Ancient and Modern (1) Particular problems in studying history of ancient economy — lack of evidence, fact that ancients themselves never studied or wrote about it — means that ‘theory’ of one sort or another, whether used explicitly or unconsciously, becomes particularly important. Until very recently, and still to a very great extent, dominated by two intersecting debates: primitivism vs. modernism, and formalism vs. substantivism. (2) ‘Modernism’ begins in mid C19 when historians like Mommsen and Meyer first examine aspects of ancient economy: assume that there’s little difference between ancient and modern worlds, differences in trade, industry etc. a matter of ‘quantity’ rather than ‘quality’. Restated in mid-C20 by Rostovtzeff, who ascribes achievements of ancient civilisation to ‘bourgeoisie’. An optimistic view of achievements of antiquity; happy to use terms like capitalism, markets, trade, entrepreneur. (3) ‘Primitivism’ begins as reaction to modernisers: Bucher, Weber, Hasebroek. Not major force in ancient history until Finley (influenced by Weber and Polanyi) in later C20. Emphasis on absolute difference between ancient and modern; antiquity is primitive, pre-modern, pre-industrial, under-developed. (4) Views clearly rest not only on different interpretations of limited ancient evidence, e.g. involvement of Roman senators in trade, but on different narratives (continuity vs. fundamental break) and different ideas of our relation to ancients (they’re just like us vs. they’re completely alien). Political overtones: assume that our form of society (i.e. capitalism) is universal and eternal, or insist that capitalism is historically limited. (5) Closely related to more abstract debate. ‘Formalists’ argue that economic theory is universally applicable, since it analyses behaviour inherent to human beings; hence no problem in applying modern economic concepts to antiquity. Mainly associated with modernisers, but not always; many modernisers know no economics but simply use vocabulary unselfconsciously, while a few primitivists make use of (carefully selected) economic theory, mainly microeconomics — arguing, for example, that we may find economically rational behaviour at the individual level, e.g. in managing one’s farm, but in absence of integrated market system macroeconomics is useless. (6) ‘Substantivists’ argue that economics was developed to study modern capitalist economy and so is useless for non-capitalist and non-western economies where economy is ‘embedded’ in social structures (political overtones again: associated with critique of ‘development economics’). Either reject use of theory altogether (Finley’s approach; mainly sticks to critique rather than attempting positive account) or turn to sociology, psychology or above all anthropology in search of alternative models of human behaviour (see e.g. von Reden, Exchange in Ancient Greece). Increasingly also turn to study of material and environmental context, limits on human action; assume that medical and ecological science is universally valid, if not economics. (7) Key issues: what’s the most appropriate comparison for antiquity — the modern world, an African tribe, medieval Europe? What is an appropriate vocabulary for the study of the ancient economy? How to choose between primitivism and modernism?