DETERMINANTS OF PERCENTAGE SHARE OF SHADOW BANKING TO TOTAL ASSETS OF SELECTED PHILIPPINE REAL ESTATE DEVELOPERS A Thesis Presented to the Faculty of the School of Economics University of Asia and the Pacific In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Science in Industrial Economics By Rosemary T. Sia May 2015 TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables List of Figures Acknowledgements Executive Summary Page iii iii iv vi CHAPTER I II III IV V INTRODUCTION A. Background of the Study B. Statement of the Problem C. Objectives of the Study D. Significance of the Study E. Scope and Limitations F. Definition of Terms REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE A. What is Shadow Banking? B. Shadow Banking Growth Factors C. Size of Shadow Banking D. Entities and Activities of Shadow Banking E. Real Estate Adequate Financing F. In – house Financing as a Quick Path to Ownership G. Factors and Theories That Affect Shadow Banking Activities in the Real Estate 1 4 4 5 5 6 8 10 12 14 18 19 21 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK AND METHODOLOGY A. Theoretical Framework B. Empirical Methodology 31 36 PRESENTATION, INTERPRETATION, AND ANALYSIS OF DATA A. Breakdown of Shadow Banking Activities B. Regression Analysis 41 45 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS, AND RECOMMENDATIONS A. Summary of Results 53 B. Conclusions 54 C. Recommendations 54 BIBLIOGRAPHY 57 i APPENDIX A. B. C. D. E. F. G. H. I. J. K. List of Observed Companies Breakdown of Supplier Financing Breakdown of In – house Financing Breakdown of Private Placement Financing Total Supplier Financing Total In-house Financing Total Private Placement Financing Total Assets Total Profit Panel Regression Data Results of Regression on %Shadow Financing With White Cross-Sectional Test 61 62 64 66 68 69 70 70 71 73 79 ii LIST OF TABLES Table Page 1 Factors that Affect Shadow Banking in the Real Estate Sector 42 2 3 Estimated Shadow Financing Function Regression Results 53 55 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 The Philippine Financial System Shadow Bank Liabilities versus Traditional Bank Liabilities Shadow Banking in Emerging Markets Total Supplier Financing Total In – house Financing Total Private Placement Financing Breakdown of Shadow banking growth Total Assets of Selected Real Estate Developers in the Philippines Total Profit of Selected Real Estate Developers in the Philippines Percentage Share of Shadow banking to Total Assets Page 9 19 20 46 iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS “Good things come to those who believe, better things come to those who are patient, and the best things come to those who don’t give up.” It’s been quite a journey. Writing this thesis would not have been possible without the people who pushed me further. There were days when frustrations and doubts settled in, and the temptation of giving up was always present. But I’m truly grateful to the people who took part in the completion of this thesis, this would have been impossible to fulfill without all of them. To my thesis adviser, Dr. Stan, your good guidance, along with your comments and insights has definitely been helpful, I would not have been able to complete this study without you, thank you for your patience and dedication. Despite the many meetings that you have within and outside the university, you still managed to read through my work and set all the consultations with me. For that I thank you. Thank you also for sharing your knowledge all throughout my thesis work. To my internal reader, Sir Greg, you also always made such effort in reading my drafts, putting comments and suggestions, and answering the many questions that I had while writing my thesis, thank you for your kindness and great effort. To my external reader, Sir Manny, thank you for your time in reading through my work and in being one of the panellists for my final defense. Your comments were certainly helpful, thank you! To my dearest friends – Keng, Keren, Thea, Althea, Tin, Julian and Teddy, you were there in happiest of times and even in those emotional moments that I’ve iv been through. Thank you for your prayers and support. Thank you for being such great friends, I know I could always count on you. To the IEP 5th years - Althea, Keren, Keng, Chela, Joe, Apple, Sarmie, Ivy, Lyndon, German, Mon, Francis, Jose, Rey, Mar, Rige, Raf, and Rap, my journey in taking the Masters would never be complete without you. For all the trials and challenges that we’ve been through together as a batch, I must say it was definitely worth spending it with all of you, and I wouldn’t have it any other way. To my mentors and professors, I will never forget your teachings and words of wisdom, you always inspire me to strive for excellence, thank you! To my parents, Richard and Norma, I’m blessed to have you both as my Dad and Mom. You have raised your daughter well. Thank you for all the encouraging words and motivation, I deeply appreciate all the love and support. To my older brothers, Paul, Stephen and Michael, I’m blessed to have such amazing “ahias”, thank you for the love! Above all, I offer up this achievement to the One true, loving and faithful God, Who continued to sustain me all throughout the many battles that I have faced. Thank you, LORD for despite the many trials and painful experiences, it was in those moments that you have molded me into what I have become today - a stronger, more disciplined and mature person. v EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This study aims to examine the growth of shadow banking activities of listed real estate developers in the Philippines, as well as the main factors behind shadow banking growth. The observation covers a period of ten years from 2004 to 2013, and includes selected real estate developers in the country. The type of shadow banking activities that were explored are: supplier financing, in – house financing and private placement financing. By gathering annual data from consolidated financial statements of each company, as stated in the liabilities section, it is confirmed that there has been a tremendous rise of shadow banking activities within the sector. The panel regression results reveal the main determinants of shadow banking growth in this sector. Company variables such as the lagged percentage share of shadow banking over total assets and profitability had a positive correlation with the proportion of shadow banking over total assets. While informal interest rates and company size based on assets had a negative correlation with the proportion of shadow banking over total assets. Moreover, external factors such as land values have a negative impact on shadow banking, while bank loans have a positive effect. Other observed macro variables such as OFW remittances, exchange rates and gross domestic savings were also considered and tested, but were dropped as they were proven to be statistically insignificant. The model only determines the statistical significance of these variables in relation to the dependent variable that is the percentage share of shadow banking to total assets of selected real estate companies. vi vii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION A. Background of the Study Shadow banking has been broadly defined as credit intermediation outside the conventional banking system, and constitutes around one-fourth or 25% of the total financial intermediation worldwide (IMF, 2014). The term “shadow bank” was first coined by economist Paul McCulley in a 2007 speech at the annual financial symposium hosted by the Kansas City Federal Reserve Bank in Jackson Hole, Wyoming (Kodres, 2013). As mentioned in his talk, shadow banks were centered in the US and mainly referred to non-bank financial institutions that engaged in maturity transformation. Commercial banks engage in maturity transformation when deposits, which are normally short term, are used to fund loans that are long term. Shadow banks do relatively the same – that is to borrow short term funds in the money markets and use these funds to buy assets with long term maturities. However, since shadow banks are not subject to traditional banking regulations, they cannot borrow from the Federal Reserve and do not have traditional depositors whose funds are covered by insurance; they mainly lie in the “shadows”. Shadow credit intermediation can be beneficial in its capacity to provide alternative financing to the real economy, however such activities can also become a source of systemic risk. During the 2008 global financial crisis, shadow banking contributed to significant levels of risks in the financial system due to the lack of adequate regulation. While regulated banks played an important role in the 1 securitization of assets, a large share of the ultimate financing of securitized assets were provided by the shadow banking system. In advanced economies, shadow intermediaries such as money market mutual funds (MMFs) and securitization vehicles were highly leveraged and were vulnerable to runs when investors withdrew large amounts of funds at short notice. This led to the fire sales of assets, which further intensified financial risks by reducing asset values and spread the stress to traditional banks. This eventually led global regulatory reforms to initiate greater disclosure of asset valuations, improved governance and stricter oversight and regulation of shadow banks. In the Philippines, shadow banking activities are not as high compared to advanced economies. The Philippine Financial system is broadly monitored by different regulatory agencies in the country (Figure 1). The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) generally regulates the country’s banking institutions through the effective use of monetary policy instruments. Banking institutions consist of commercial banks, thrift banks, rural banks, cooperative rural banks and specialized government banks. The banking system accounts for around 80% of total assets in the entire financial system – all supervised by the BSP. On the contrary, non-bank institutions such as investment houses, financing companies, SEC dealers, fund managers, lending investors, pawnshops, government non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs) and venture capital corporations are institutions that the BSP has no direct control but are still under its supervision. With the growth of the economy in the 1960s, the system became complicated as more entities registered with specific government agencies participated in the credit markets 2 without access to BSP regulation. The completely unregulated sector is considered as the shadow banking segment or the informal credit markets. Figure 1. The Philippine Financial System Universal and Commercial Banks (90%) Banking Institutions Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas Insurance Commission Non-Banking Financial Intermediaries Thrift Banks (7.5%) Rural and Cooperative Banks (2.5%) Private Philippine Financial System Govt Completely Unregulated Financial Sector Bureau of Cooperative Development Cooperative Credit Unions Source: Philippine Institute for Development Studies; Philippines Country Monitor Estimating the size of shadow banking has always been difficult because many its entities do not report to government regulators. Of all the Southeast Asian Nations, Malaysia has the most information regarding NBFI’s, however, it still remains spotty. In Malaysia, NBFIs accounted for 20% of total credit provided to households and grew much faster than the banks. Furthermore, based on a World Bank study, NBFIs accounted for 37% of financial assets in the Philippines, 35% in Thailand, and 20% in Indonesia (FSB, 2014). The shadow banking system in emerging markets, such as the Philippines, is simpler than those in advanced economies. They are usually composed of financing, leasing and factoring companies, investment and equity funds, insurance companies, pawnshops, and underground entities. Such activities are also existent and 3 relatively growing in the real estate sector, particularly in its in – house financing operations. B. Statement of the Problem The main problem to be researched in this study is the factors that determine the growth of shadow banking or in-house financing activities in the Philippine real estate market. This is due to recent observations that shadow banking has been evidently growing in the Philippines, particularly in the real estate sector, and can be subject to certain financial risks. Despite the advantages of shadow banking in providing credit, non-bank financial intermediation may pose even greater systemic risks than traditional banks since they are not subject to BSP regulation and oversight. Thus, this study aims to answer the question: What are the main factors that contribute to the growth of shadow banking activities in the Philippine real estate sector? C. Research Objectives This study aims: 1. To explain how shadow banking activities occur in the real estate sector 2. To estimate the share of shadow banking activities of listed real estate developers in the Philippines 3. To identify the main drivers that contribute to the growth of shadow banking activities in the real estate sector 4 D. Significance of the Study This study will be useful in determining the size of shadow financing in the real estate sector. This will help the real estate sector in monitoring and assessing the risk levels of their credit intermediation activities. This will also benefit lenders and investors in the real estate sector as they reassess how much is being used to finance housing loans. Furthermore, this would also help BSP and other financial regulators implement strict measures in targeting large credit exposures from the real estate sector, so as to prevent diversion of systemic risk. E. Scope and Limitations This study will only focus on the shadow banking activities of listed and top real estate developers in the Philippines as indicated in Business World – Top 1000 Corporations in the Philippines. The top real estate developers in the country which are also publicly listed are: SM Prime Holdings, Inc., Megaworld Corp., Ayala Land, Inc., Robinsons Land Corp., Filinvest Land, Inc., Rockwell Land Corp., Vista Land and Lifescapes, Inc., Sta. Lucia Land, Inc.and Shang Properties. These companies were selected because it holds 46% market share of the total real estate industry as of 2013. The period of observation will cover ten years from 2004 to 2013. However, since Vista Land and Lifescapes, Inc. has only existed in 2006 and lacks more periods of observation, this company will be disregarded. In this study, shadow banking activities include supplier financing through construction loans which consist of accounts payable, liabilities for land and property development and other payables that are related to construction. Although, it should be noted that the accounts payable to suppliers may just be 5 working capital financing extended by suppliers. This study will also measure in – house financing through instalment payables and deposits, as well as public and private financing through bonds and notes. This study mainly estimates the size of shadow banking and determines the main drivers that affect the growth of shadow financing activities held by the major property developers in the country. In determining the factors, a panel regression model is used. However, due to limitations in this regression model, it should not be used for forecasting the future trend of shadow banking. F. Definition of Terms The following terms are some important concepts used in the study: 1. Shadow banking system: the system of credit intermediation that involves entities and activities fully or partially outside the regular banking system, or nonbank credit intermediation in short (Financial Stability Board, 2014). 2. In house – financing: This is defined as a type of seller financing offered by real estate developers to their buyers who want to purchase a property in a series of installment payments without resorting to third-party financial institutions (Lamudi, 2014). 3. Supplier financing: This is where suppliers facilitate trade in meeting the credit needs of affiliated companies. This is usually made up of construction loans and liabilities related to property development. 4. Private Placements: This refers to the sale of securities to a relatively small number of investors as a way of raising capital. The placement is not required to register with the Securities of Exchange and Commission since it only caters to 6 few investors. Also, since the placements are private, the average investor is only made aware of the placement after it has already occurred. 5. Non-Bank Financial Institutions (NBFIs): entities that are registered in any government regulated body as a non-bank financial intermediary, but holds similar functions where financial intermediation is implied. In general, NBFIs are not allowed to borrow from the public. However, NBFIs may obtain a license to have “quasi – banking” functions, in which case they are allowed to borrow from the public provided that deposits are not among the debt instruments issued. 6. Debt Ratio: A financial ratio that measures the extent of a company’s or consumer’s leverage. The debt ratio is defined as the ratio of total debt to total assets, expressed in percentage, and can be interpreted as the proportion of a company’s assets that are financed by debt. The higher this ratio, the more leveraged the company and the greater its financial risk. 7 CHAPTER II REVIEW OF RELATED LITERATURE A. What is Shadow Banking? In most studies, shadow banking is mainly defined by the nature of the entity – that it is usually less regulated than traditional banks and lacks a formal safety net. In other studies, it is thoroughly defined as activities that “consist of credit, maturity and liquidity transformation that take place without direct and explicit access to public sources of liquidity or credit backstops, and are conducted by specialized financial intermediaries called shadow banks, which are bounded together in an intermediation chain known as the shadow banking system (Pozsar, 2013). Based on the Financial Stability Board, there are two proposed definitions of Shadow banking– broad and narrow. The broad definition of shadow banking is a system of credit intermediation involving entities and activities outside the regular banking system. The four key aspects of intermediation as stated by Kodres (2014) are: 1. Maturity Transformation: obtaining short term funds to invest in long term assets 2. Liquidity Transformation: similar to maturity transformation that consists of using cash-like liabilities to buy harder – to – sell assets such as loans 3. Leverage: employing techniques such as borrowing money to buy fixed assets to magnify potential gains or losses in an investment. 8 4. Credit Risk Transfer: taking the risk of a borrower’s default and transferring it from the originator of the loan to another party. The narrow definition further breaks down the broad definition into parts: (1) the systemic concerns, in particular by maturity/liquidity transformation, leverage and flawed credit risk transfer, and/or (2) regulatory arbitrage concerns (Jeffers & Pilhon, 2014). In addition, Tobias (2013) explains that shadow credit intermediation happens in an environment where “prudential regulatory standards are either not applied or are applied to a materially lesser or different degree” compared to regular banks. Credit intermediation per se is a subset of financial intermediation that involves borrowing and lending through credit instruments that consists of credit, maturity and liquidity transformation. These are usually enhanced through the use of third-party liquidity and credit guarantees, in the form of liquidity or credit put options (Jeffers & Pilhon, 2014). A liquidity put option by the private sector is provided in the form of wraps, guarantees or credit default swaps (CDs) that is offered by insurance companies or banks. Tobias (2013) also mentions that financial intermediation activities associated with public sector guarantees are called to be “officially enhanced”. Official enhancements to credit intermediation are classified into four categories. 1. A liability with direct official enhancement must be on a financial institution’s balance sheet, while off-balance sheet liabilities of financial institutions are indirectly enhanced by the public sector. Direct and explicit official 9 enhancement activities include on-balance sheet funding of depository institutions, insurance policies and annuity contracts, liabilities of most pension funds and debt guaranteed through public sector lending programs. 2. Direct and implicit official enhancement activities include debt issued or guaranteed by the government –sponsored enterprises (GSEs), which benefit from an implicit credit put to the taxpayer. 3. Liabilities with indirect official enhancement generally include the off balance sheet activities of depository institutions, such as unfunded credit card loan commitments and lines of credit to conduits. 4. Indirect and implicit official enhancement include asset management activities, such as bank – affiliated hedge funds and money market mutual funds (MMFFs) as well as the securities lending of custodian banks. Activities that do not benefit from any form of official enhancement are said to be “unenhanced”, such as guarantees made by monoline insurance companies or companies operating in one specific financial area. Shadow credit intermediation includes all credit intermediation activities that are implicitly enhanced, indirectly enhanced, or unenhanced by official guarantees. B. Shadow Banking Growth Factors Shadow banking growth can be attributed to various factors. First, when government bond yields are low and investors are looking for higher – yielding assets, it is the shadow banking system that often supplies those assets – the search for yield effect. Second, tighter bank regulation encourages institutions to 10 circumvent it through non-bank intermediation. Third, growth of shadow banking can be complementary to the rest of the financial system. In emerging markets, the growth of pension funds and insurance companies has often come along with the growth of investment funds and other nonbank intermediaries. In the United States, shadow banking grew from the demands of so called institutional cash pools for alternatives to insured deposits and safe assets (Valckx, 2014). Econometric analysis also supports the role of these factors in determining the growth of shadow banking. Main findings show that higher growth of shadow banking is associated with various complementing factors. One is bank regulation in terms of more stringent capital requirements. Banks have an incentive to shift activities to the nonbank sector in response to certain regulatory changes. Another is liquidity conditions, the negative correlation of shadow banking growth with term spreads and interest rates becomes stronger after 2008. Moreover, there is the institutional cash pools and financial development. Stronger growth of institutional investors is associated with shadow banking, consistent with complementarities and demand side effects (Valckx, 2014). Lastly, there is the growing banking sector. Higher banking sector growth rates indicate higher growth of shadow banking, which also suggest complementarities. Data from flow of funds and sectoral accounts provide a quantitative approximation of various sources of shadow banking risk. Specifically, in addition to size, rough approximations of maturity risk (based on whether assets are of long or short duration, liquidity risk (based on whether assets are liquid and easy to trade), credit risk (share of loan assets that carry substantial credit risk), 11 leverage (total assets to equity), and interconnectedness (how these entities are exposed to banks through asset holdings or liabilities) can be inferred from the flow of funds and sectoral balance sheet breakdowns (Valckx, 2014). However, the type of risk analysis based on this data has certain limitations. Aggregation at the sectoral level can cover up important vulnerabilities at the entity level. Risk scores of individual sectors may underestimate both interdependence among shadow banking entities and exposure to common factors. Nevertheless, this level of analysis may still be useful as a starting point for assessing the magnitude of risks posed by shadow banking entities and tracking their growth through time. C. Size of Shadow banking During the U.S. financial crisis, the gross measure of shadow bank liabilities grew by $22 trillion as of 2007, according to a study conducted by Pozsar et al.(2013). This was even higher than the total liabilities in the banking sector, which was around $14 trillion. The size of shadow banking made a significant decline after the peak of 2007, whereas total liabilities in the banking sector continued to increase throughout the crisis. According to IMF (2014), in its 2014 Global Financial Stability Report, shadow banking amounts between 15 and 25 trillion dollars in the United States, between 13.5 and 22.5 trillion in the euro area, between 2.5 and 6 trillion in Japan, and around 7 trillion in emerging markets. In emerging markets, shadow banking is seen to grow at a faster pace than the tradition banking system. 12 Figure 2. Shadow Bank Liabilities versus Traditional Bank Liabilities Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Flow of Funds accounts of the United States”(as of 2011:Q3); Federal Reserve Bank of New York In the Philippines, although non-bank institutions are supervised by the BSP, they provide alternative source of funding and have a certain degree of flexibility compared to banks in terms of policies imposed by the central bank. Based on the BSP’s first Consumer Finance Survey, 8 out 0f 10 Filipinos (78.5%) of the total respondents do not have deposit accounts. Thus, instead of people depositing money in a bank, they keep their money in alternative entities such as “paluwagan”, savings and loans association and other informal lending activities under shadow banking, which are completely unregulated.1 As financial markets continue to show progress, shadow banking also develops wherein various forms of credit instruments are formed that are no longer regulated by the central bank. The figure below shows the World Bank estimates on the size of shadow banking in the Philippines along with other 1 The survey was conducted between November 2009 and January 2010 using 2008 expenditure data. Sample size consists of 10,520 households with 3,872 households within NCR and 6,648 households outside NCR. 13 emerging markets in 2010. It also shows that the estimated size of shadow banking in the Philippines is more than one-third of the whole financial system’s total assets, and has been gradually increasing similar with other neighboring countries. Figure 3. Shadow Banking in Emerging Markets Source: Ghosh et.al. (2012) D. Entities and Activities of Shadow Banking As mentioned previously, the bank-like functions that shadow banks execute are credit, maturity and liquidity transformation and credit risk transfer. Activities that contribute to the emergence of shadow banks are securitization and funding of financial entities and collateral intermediation. Securitization in banks transforms the risk on a single balance sheet, while securitization in shadow banks involves a chain of balance sheets with different sources of funding. This activity is prone to excessive maturity and liquidity transformation, leverage, and evasion of bank regulations. 14 In the shadow banking system of advanced economies, entities that are usually involved in the borrowing side are Special Purpose Vehicles (SPV) and Structured Investment Vehicle (SIV), and on the funding side are Repurchase Agreement (repo) markets and Money Market Funds (MMF). Aside from these, other entities that are prone to “runs” and systemic risk are broker-dealers, investment funds (i.e. hedge funds, equity funds, bond funds, mixed funds), securities lenders, cash funds and investment banks. Furthermore, European Economic and Social Committee (EESC, 2012) highlights that some commercial banks perform shadow banking activities as well (Jeffers and Pilhon, 2014). The Financial Stability Board’s (FSB, 2014) recent report on Asia’s Shadow Banking identified the following criteria that exclude financial activities from shadow banking: ๏ท The non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs) that are subject to a proper regulatory body. ๏ท The exposure in risks are not considered systemic ๏ท The NBFIs that do not carry out credit intermediation activities. Credit unions or Cooperatives (CUCs) are classified as shadow banks in the country, which have the second largest number of 22,555 institutions with 6,395 total assets. The FSB (2014) reported that CUCs are basically involved in offering financial services that provide convenient access to savings and lending services. Moreover, its activities hint systemic risks indicated by maturity transformation, liquidity transformation and leverage. CUCs are also involved in 15 loan provisions that rely on short-term financing and are generally not under a regulation body. Another type of informal credit intermediation is the “paluwagan”. A “paluwagan” is a form of mutual self-help group wherein a group of persons turn in the same amount of money towards a common fund and then take turns in using the amount of funds collected. As it is usually managed by one person, deposits in a “paluwagan” do not earn interest, but each member of the group is provided with larger funds when it is the person’s turn to collect the “sahod” (income)(Agabin, 1989). Pawnshops are also financial institutions that fall under shadow banking due to minimal leverage, and given that they are involved in loan provision carried out outside the banking system. Also, loan provision is dependent on short-term funding and outside the regulation of the banking system. Furthermore, based from the FSB report, only India and the Philippines identified Microfinance Institutions (MFIs) as shadow banking because of its many systemic risk indicators and minimal regulatory arbitrage out of the seven Asian jurisdictions. Lastly, finance companies are categorized as shadow banking as well because of their exposure to liquidity and maturity mismatch and its engagement in shortterm loan provision subsidy. Most finance companies are also not strictly monitored by prudential regulatory policies unlike the banks under the BSP. Shadow banking activities in the Philippines also take place in the real estate sector particularly in in-house financing activities of developers. In-house financing is a common practice among property developers wherein it provides 16 high-interest credit with less rigid requirements for buyers, which serves as an option to the more conventional mortgage loan through banks and other lending companies (Kritz, 2015). Winston Conrad B. Padojinog, an economist from University of Asia and the Pacific supported the claim that the drastic growth of shadow banks is in the particular sector. He added that most real estate developers who avail in-house financing do not qualify under the bank standards (Ang, 2013). The BSP enacted a 20% limit on a bank’s exposure to real estate that further tightens the availability of credit for real estate. Due to this, real estate developers are looking for alternative sources of credit to finance their operations especially since bank lending on real estate tightened recently. Majority of activities in the shadow banks are from real estate, and the regulators are in the shadows on how much credit these real estate developers lend. Based on a staff report by the IMF, Bank lending has accelerated since end-2013, reaching almost 21% in April 2014. Estimated to be around 35% of GDP, credit penetration of the private sector through banks is low from a regional perspective, however nonbank financing is seen to grow significantly. Large companies have been issuing debt securities, which allows them to lock in fixed rate funding, lengthen maturities and bypass bank exposure limits on individual borrowers. While domestic bank loans still dominate, other sources of formal credit (bonds, external loans) are gaining in importance, and total debt of the nonbank private sector has risen steadily to around 55 percent of GDP. The vast majority of this debt is extended to corporates. On average, leverage of listed companies is low at 100 percent in 2012. However, debt is unevenly distributed 17 across firms, and companies with leverage ratios above 200 percent account for about one-third of total corporate debt. Banks exposure to real estate amounted 21.8 percent of total loan portfolios at end 2013, and has been growing faster than other segments. Sixty percent of real estate loans are to commercial entities (developers and construction companies) with the rest to households. Real estate developers and their affiliated conglomerates are also active in debt and equity markets, and developers— as well as several public agencies—provide credit directly to home buyers (estimated to total around 7.5 percent of GDP, including mortgage lending by banks) (IMF, 2014). E. Real Estate Adequate Financing Real estate developers and investors usually rely on leverage funds to finance their projects. This refers to the minimum amount of equity funds and a maximum amount of borrowed funds to control large investment. The funds needed for land acquisition can come from various sources. The seller can back a purchase money deed of trust, the developer can form a syndicate and raise the needed capital by selling ownership shares, or the funds can be borrowed from financial institutions or other private parties. After land acquisition, funds for construction can come from traditional lenders, such as banks, thrifts institutions, insurance companies, and mortgage companies. In addition, construction funds can also come from pension funds, real estate investment trusts, and endowment funds (Mckenzie, 2011). 18 Generally, the loan used for funds to construct buildings and other site improvements is referred to as a construction loan, or interim, loan. It is mainly used to fund all the hard costs of construction such as materials and labor for site improvements. It may also cover some soft costs, such as leasing costs, planning costs, and management. It may also include finishing the interior space for tenants through the lease-up stage. Lenders prefer to make loans only for the cost of site improvements, but competition among many lenders may result in more flexible lending policies. F. In-house financing as a quick path to ownership Most developers target first time buyers among the OFWs and the middle income segments who do not qualify for more stringently regulated conventional bank loans or who choose not to undergo a more time – consuming approval process. Though there are buyers who meet the qualifications for Bank loans, Social Security System (SSS) or Pag-Ibig financing, the process of availing for these loans is still very time consuming. In the in-house financing scheme, developers offer payment schemes that suit the financial capacity of their buyers. This would also mean that buyers directly pay their monthly amortization to the developers. This type of financing require less paperwork, background check and is processed faster compared to bank loans, but has a higher interest rate. The interest rate is stated to range from 14% to 18% (Rappler, 2014). Developers only require buyers to pay 10% if the project is preselling or 20%, the higher the down payment, the lower the balance and monthly amortization. 19 Despite the ease in choosing the in-house financing scheme, this may also pose as a problem. BSP supervision is limited only to banks. The largest but hidden part of home loan finance is made of credit receivables extended by developers to the buyers through contract to sell (CTS) agreements. CTS is common in emerging economies where there is a shortage of accessible mortgage market. Developers use deferred sale contracts, which in practice is a credit facility granted to a purchasing household. The title to the property is transferred only upon full payment and in case of default, the CTS is cancelled and the unit can be resold to another client. This lending activity is neither regulated nor measured by BSP. Although the idea of CTS is positive in terms of expanding home finance to low and middle income sector, it is possible that these developers or real estate companies may have been applying less stringent lending standards and more generous loan terms than required of banks (e.g. zero interest rates, zero downpayment) which opens up the financial system to trouble (Ballesteros, n.d). CTS are channeled to the financial system through a refinancing scheme by banks and government housing finance corporation (e.g. HDMF) but the amount of CTS retained by developers could still be large. Based on the assets of the largest developers it is possible that about 15% of assets are made of CTS considering preselling activities. Other developers could have more since banks are more reluctant to finance them. 20 G. Factors and Theories that Affect Shadow Financing Activities in the Real Estate Interest Rates based on Austrian Business Cycle Theory Austrian business cycle theory (ABCT) emerges from Austrian school of thought, which assumes that money is not neutral and financial flows serve as a mirror of what is happening in the real economy (Zelmanovitz, 2011). The main proponents of the Austrian business cycle theory historically were Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek followed by Murray Rothbard, James Keeler and Roger Garrison to name a few. Hayek won a Nobel Prize in economics in 1974 (shared with Gunnar Myrdal) in part for his work on this theory. Austrian business cycle theory, or preferably called credit cycle by Austrian economists, can be divided into four stages, namely, expansion, crisis, recession and recovery. Expansion stage starts when low interest rates or expansionary monetary policy tend to stimulate borrowing or credit expansion from the banking system to businesses and individual borrowers, which causes an expansion of the money supply through the money creation process in a fractional reserve banking system. In this stage production and prices increase. This then leads to unsustainable credit-sourced boom during, which the artificially stimulated borrowing seeks out diminishing investment opportunities, and results in widespread mal-investments causing capital resources to be misallocated into areas that would not attract investment if the money supply remained stable. Crisis stage starts with a correction (or credit crunch or recession or bust) that occurs when exponential credit creation cannot be sustained. The money supply suddenly and sharply 21 contracts. In this stage stock exchanges crash and multiple bankruptcies occur. Recession stage follows after the crisis when output and prices drop and interest rates increase. Recovery stage start when markets finally “clear” and causing resources to be reallocated back towards more efficient uses. In this stage stocks recover due to the fall in prices and incomes. Recovery and prosperity are associated with increases in productivity, consumer confidence, aggregate demand and prices. Thus, in this case, interest Rates have a major impact on real estate markets. When interest rates fall, the cost to obtain a mortgage to buy a home decreases, which creates higher demand for real estate, and eventually pushes property prices up. Conversely, as interest rates rise, the cost to obtain a mortgage increases, thereby lowering the demand and prices of real estate (Nguyen, n.d). However, to determine fully how government-influenced interest rates, capital flows and financing rates affect property values, the income approach is used. The income approach focuses on what the potential income for rental property yields relative to initial investment. The income approach is used frequently for commercial real estate investing. The income approach relies on determining the annual capitalization rate for an investment. This rate is simply the projected annual income from the gross rent multiplier divided by the original cost or current value of the property (Abraham, n.d). Interest rates can significantly affect financing costs and mortgage rates, and can also influence capital flows of investments. In the real estate, the changes 22 in lending rates either add or reduce the amount of capital available for investment. The amount of capital and the cost of capital affect demand but also supply, capital available for real estate purchases and development. For example, when capital availability is tight due to high interest rates, capital providers tend to lend less as a percentage of intrinsic value, or not as far up the "capital stack." This means that loans are made at lower loan to value ratios, thus reducing leveraged cash flows and property values. These changes in capital flows can also have a direct effect on the supply and demand for property. The cost of capital and capital availability would determine supply by providing additional capital for property development (Stammers, n.d). Land values based on Relative Mobility and Financial Accelerator Theory Land values also serves as an important factor to consider in financing for real estate activities. Land values tend to appreciate in varying central locations. In the Philippines, land values are higher in central business districts (CBDs) found in Makati, Ortigas Center and Bonifacio Global City. This is due to the increasing population residing in the area, where the effect of a so called” relative mobility” takes place (Manganelli, 2015). This then further leads to an increase in demand of offices and condominiums, and consequently an increase in real estate financing activities. Moreover, based on the “financial accelerator” framework, represented by Kiyotaki and Moore (1997), Bernanke et al (1994) and Aoki et al (2002), borrowing conditions are determined by the total value of real estate assets (as collateral). Increase in land prices lower external finance premiums and 23 improve credit availability for borrowers, thus causing an increase in demand for real estate assets and driving property prices even higher (Davis and Zhu, 2004). Real Estate Loans from Banks based on Credit Rationing The supply of real estate loans from banks may also affect shadow financing activities. According to the theory of credit rationing that has been modelled by Bell (1990) based on the study by Haugen (2005), there is a form of interaction between formal and informal credit institutions. His model shows that when formal credit is rationed or tightened, and the informal lender is able to offer contract loans that are preferred by the borrowers, then there would be a spilled over demand in the market. This means that when formal banking institutions do not give as much credit as the borrowers desire, the borrowers would turn to informal credit intermediaries. Based on Circular No. 600 that was implemented in 2012, BSP set a limit on bank real estate loans (RELs) of twenty percent (20%) of total loan portfolio. However, latest central bank data show that banks’ real estate exposure went up 23 percent to P1.159 trillion as of September 2014. This exposure was made up of P977.085 billion in loans and P181.882 billion in investments to the sector (Martin,2015), which is above the minimum requirement. This further allowed banks to implement stricter measures in handing out loans. The tightening of the supply of loans from banks consequently leads to more demand for loans from non-financial institutions, as the theory suggests that the excess demand is catered by the informal sector. Thus, a decreasing supply of real estate loans from banks 24 result to more financing activities among real estate companies and its partner institutions. Based on a study on “Factors Affecting Leveraging for Quoted Real Estate Development in China” by Simiyu and Huo (2013), there are also other significant variables that greatly determines the financing growth in the real estate. These are company size and profitability. Company size (Assets) Company size determines financial leverage for virtually all sectors. All theories explaining capital structures have dwelled much on the existing connection between financial leverage and company size (Schoubben and van Hulle, 2004, p. 595). Company size is calculated by transforming total assets to natural logarithm. Measuring size of company as log of sales or use of absolute value of assets was supported by Huang and Song (2002). The reason for use of absolute value of total assets or natural log of sales as a preferred computation of firm size is because the two are highly correlated with a coefficient of 0.79. However, in a recent study of Pandey (2004), it applies natural log of total assets to compute for firm size. Low risks brought about by the finance distress are demystified by the fact that large firms have more developed portfolio, great monitoring system and transparency. (Ang et al. 1982; Myers 1984; Myers & Majluf, 1984 and Bevan and Danbolt, 1999). Large companies are advantaged in comparison with small ventures because their credit rating structure is favored by the size of its assets. 25 Profitability based on Minsky’s Theory and Pecking Order Theory According to Minsky’s Theory, as the economy perform better and businesses grow, expected profits increase and firms tend to raise their level of debt beyond their ability to repay. However, companies believe that profits will rise and the debt will eventually be repaid without much trouble. The rising profit attracts other firms or entrepreneurs to join in and encourages them to raise their level of debt. More debt leads to more investment, borrowers’ financial health show visible improvement, the economy grows further, and this makes lenders more eager to lend to firms even without full guarantees of success. Through time, the pace of debt accumulation starts to rise much faster than borrowers' ability to repay and serve the debt (Ascarya, 2013). This is referred to as Ponzi financing. In this way, the economy has taken on much risky credit. At this stage, the foundation for an economic bust is set in motion, started with the default of some big firms, which make lenders realize the actual risks in the economy and stop giving credit. Refinancing becomes impossible for many, and more firms default. If no new money comes into the economy to allow the refinancing process, a real economic crisis begins. During the recession, firms start to hedge again, and the cycle is closed. Many economists, such as Wray (2009a and 2009b) and Prychitko (2010), argue that current global financial crisis could be called the ‘Minsky Moment’ or ‘Minsky Crisis’. Profitability determines income shield and velocity of cash flow. According to Brealey & Allen (2008) in their works, it states that the commonly 26 applied determinant of company profits is return on assets (ROA).Highly profitable firms have high income shield with high velocity of cash flow. As postulated by Pecking Order Theory, firms with higher profits (high internally generated funds) prefer to borrow less because it is easier and more cost effective to finance from internal fund sources. So, as per this theory, there will be an expected negative relation between profitability and leverage. On the contrary, Trade-off theory suggests that this relationship would be positive. Since profitable firms are less likely to go bankrupt, and hence can avail more debt at cheaper rates of interest. Based on the results of the study, both company size and profitability greatly influence the behavior of supply of funds (leverage) for real estate developers. Macroeconomic factors Other macroeconomic factors are also considered to affect the financing activities in the real estate sector. With higher interest rates, it is said to attract more remittances and a further appreciation of the exchange rate (Bayangos, 2012). Philippines is considered to be one of the world’s largest remittance recipients, with over 10.5 million Overseas Filipino Workers (OFWs) living and working in 210 countries and territories worldwide. In 2013, OFW remittances grew 7.4% to US$22.9 billion, or around 8.4% of GDP. It has been estimated that 60% of these remittances go directly or indirectly to the real estate sector, according to World Bank (Global Property Guide, 2014). These OFW remittances generate the low-end to mid-range residential property market, housing projects 27 and mid – scale subdivisions in regions near Metro Manila, such as the provinces like Cavite, Batangas and Laguna. Remittances based on the Dutch Disease Effect According to BSP, based on the “Dutch Disease Effect”, higher flows in remittances will increase liquidity in financial markets which may allow the interest rate to decrease and lead to an expansion of credit. The lower interest rate may invite an increase in expenditure. Increased investment of remittances in real estate or the stock market can push up asset prices which may exert a wealth effect. The total demand impact of an increase in remittances is the sum of these various effects: the direct expenditure effect, the multiplier effect and the interest rate effect will have a positive impact while the exchange rate appreciation could have a negative impact. Exchange Rates based on the Exchange Rate Effect Foreign exchange rate movements play a significant role on OFW demand for housing. Against the dollar, the peso has appreciated from around PHP55 (2003-2005), to an average of PhP51 in 2006 and PHP46 in 2007 (Global Property Guide, 2008). Because of this, Overseas Filipinos’ foreign earnings buy less and less in the Philippines during this period. An appreciation of exchange rates can then lead to a decrease in demand in real estate investments covered by most OFWs. Based on the exchange rate effect, an increase in the nominal pesoโdollar rate corresponds to depreciation rather an appreciation of the peso. The BSP maintains a freely floating peso, whose value is determined greatly by supply and 28 demand factors. The nominal exchange rate is sensitive to the level of the current account balance and to the interest rate differential. The direct effect of an increase in remittances on the current account is positive leading to an appreciation, but there are also indirect effects on exports (through the impact of remittances on competitiveness) and on imports (through the increase in domestic demand that remittances generate) and the overall impact of an increase in remittances could be a deterioration of the current account balance which would lead to a depreciation of the nominal exchange rate (Bayangos, 2012). The large flow of remittances in the country further promotes economic growth in the consequently leading to more credit intermediation in the real estate sector. An increase in income allows more households to increase spending and borrowings. The macroeconomic condition of the country is better measured by its gross domestic savings, as also mentioned by Dr. Victor Abola. Based on the World Bank, gross domestic savings is calculated as GDP less final consumption expenditure (total consumption). This is also supported in Mankiw’s Loanable funds theory, where the sum of private and government savings are the “flows into the financial markets” and investments the “flow out of the financial markets” (Mankiw, 1997). In this manner, he interprets the national accounting identity between saving and investment as a budget constraint that is no flows of loanable funds would be available without prior saving. In short, the higher saving is, the more credit will be supplied which given all things constant, lowers interest rates. 29 However, in a study conducted by the Macroeconomic Policy Institute of of Germany, a critique was made to argue the loanable funds theory. It explained three cases regarding the households saving behaviour and the consequences for the firm sector. First, if households save financially, the revenues of the firm during the period will be lower than its expenditures, such that its total financial assets decrease and the household’s net financial assets to increase. In this case, it is clear that household savings reduced the investing firm’s financial means. The firm would have to borrow in order to maintain its liquidity position. Second, if households did not save financially, the same amount of revenues would flow into the firm that it had previously left in the form of expenditures (given the assumption that revenues and expenditures are equal to receipts and payments), the firm would not have to borrow. Third, if the household spent more than it received in revenues from the firm, the firm would be able to increase its revenues and would have more financial means than it initially started. In all three cases, it would then conclude that the households financial saving extracts financial means from the firm and does not add to it - as claimed by loanable funds theorists (Lindner, 2013). The author also tries to assert that the amount of debts and financial assets do not necessarily depend on savings, but on the frequency of money or funds that is transferred. Thus, in principle, the amount of money in the economy could approach zero while the amount of debts and financial assets could reach with no limits. 30 CHAPTER III THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY Theoretical Diagram A. Theoretical Framework In using the IS-LM model with both an informal credit market and regulated banking sector (Carpenter 1999), the economy has only three assets: money, bank loans and informal market credit. The agents and firms only have two options for credit access, which are formal credit market through the banking sector and informal credit market. In this economy, it is assumed that there are no alternative sources of funds. Loans from banks are from both deposits and credit extended by the central bank. It has a fixed interest rate, which is usually below market cost that results into an excess demand for credit. This results to an excess demand for credit, which is captured by the informal markets. The demand for deposits is represented by the money demand function, which is expressed as: 31 ๐ท(๐, ๐ฆ) Demand for bank deposits have a negative relationship with interest rate ๐ in the informal sector and have a positive relationship with income ๐ฆ because of transactions demand. On the other hand, supply is determined by the reserve requirement ๐ and reserves in the banking sector R. By setting money demand equal to money supply, the expression will be as follows: ๐ท(๐, ๐ฆ) = ๐ −1 ๐ The reserve requirement set by the central bank and the amount of reserves in banks are the determinants of the quantity of loans ๐, which is given by: ๐ = ๐ท(๐, ๐ฆ)(1 − ๐) + ๐ถ The loans are deposits not in the reserves plus the credit extended by the central bank, which is captured by C. The residuals represent the demand for informal credit. The excess demand for credit is catered by the informal market and is represented by the difference between the aggregate demand for credit and quantity of loans supplied. In theory, formal interest rate is always less than the informal interest rate. Thus, interest rates charged by banks do not affect the demand for credit in the informal market. It is the quantity of loans supplied, which is represented by ๐ that affects the informal market. On the contrary, the demand function for informal markets is a function of interest rate ๐, income ๐ฆ and quantity of bank loans ๐. Informal money demand negatively depends on interest rate ๐ and quantity of bank loans ๐ , while it 32 positively depends on income ๐ฆ . The informal money demand function is expressed as: ๐ฟ(๐, ๐ฆ, ๐) If the effect of informal credit demand on interest rate ๐๐ณ ๐๐ is small, the market is its only source of credit, which makes it a necessity for the firm or agent. ๐๐ณ The response of informal market demand on output is represented by ๐๐, which represents the substitutability between the formal and informal markets. If the two markets are highly segregated, an increase in bank credit has an insignificant effect on the demand for informal credit. Lastly, ๐๐ณ ๐๐ is the measure of interconnectedness of the two markets. The supply of informal markets is a portfolio decision, and is represented by ๐(๐, ๐). A higher return stimulates more lending, with ๐๐ ๐๐ > 0. Similarly, an increase in income ๐ฆ will also encourage more lending. Informal interest rate is determined by equating the informal money demand and informal money supply, which is called the IM curve. ๐ฟ(๐, ๐ฆ, ๐) = ๐(๐, ๐) ๐ = ๐ผ(๐ฆ, ๐ถ, ๐ ) In comparison with the IS-LM model, the monetary policy shift both IS and IM curves. In this model, IM curve is upward sloping, and the steepness ๐๐ณ ๐๐ depends on the derivatives of informal credit, which are ๐๐and ๐๐. A high demand for credit due to an increase in output results into a steeper IM curve. A shift in the IM curve is intuitive because for a given output, higher credit or reserves 33 lowers the interest rate, which shifts the IM curve downward. On the contrary, lower credit or reserves increases the interest rate, which shifts the IM curve upward. This is because bank loans and informal loans are considered substitutes. Shifts in the IS curve represents the formal credit channel in the economy. When IS curve shifts to the right, more credit is allocated in the economy, which reduces the interest rate in the informal market. This results into a downward shift in the IM curve. 34 Table 1. Factors that Affect Shadow Banking in the Real Estate Sector Theory Variable Expected Sign Informal Interest Rates (%) IR (-) LV (-) COSIZE (+) PROF (+)/(-) REL (-) REM (+) EX (-) GDS (+) “Austrian Business Cycle Theory” or “Credit Cycle Theory” Land Values “Relative Mobility” and “Financial Accelerator Framework” Company Size (log of assets) “Pandey’s Theory” Profitability “Minsky’s Theory” or “Peking Order Theory” Real Estate Loans “Credit Rationing” OFW Remittances “Dutch Disease effect in the Philippines” Exchange Rates “Exchange Rate Effect” Gross Domestic Savings “loanable Funds Theory” by Mankiw 35 As based on the literature, the above framework is used as determinants that drive shadow financing growth in the real estate sector. B. Empirical Methodology Data Collection This study aims to examine the growth of shadow banking or shadow financing activities in the real estate sector and to identify whether it has been growing significantly than the traditional banking system. In estimating the size of shadow financing among real estate developers, data of financial assets will be gathered from the consolidated financial statements (2003-2013) of selected real estate developers in the Philippines (Annex 1). These listed companies, which serve as the backbone on the real estate industry, reflect the development of the industry as a whole. Specifically, this study will look into the debt ratio or the percentage of loans lended by real estate companies from their overall assets. Real estate financing activities can be financially examined in the liabilities section in the balance sheet. Shadow banking can be examined in terms of supplier financing through construction loans which consist of accounts payable, liabilities for land and property development and other payables that are related to construction. This study will also measure in – house financing through instalment payables and deposits, and private placement financing through bonds and notes. To get the proportion of the companies’ assets that are financed by debt, total value of shadow financing activities is divided by the total assets of the real 36 estate companies. The higher the ratio, the more leveraged the companies and the greater its financial risk. Shadow financing Total Assets % Shadow Financing After getting the total values of % Shadow Financing, a panel regression analysis is done to evaluate how the significant factors affect the growth of shadow financing in the real estate. A similar method was also done by a previous study done by Simiyu and Huo (2013). Panel Regression The analysis is conducted by using the panel regression model to examine empirically the main determinants that affect shadow financing. The dependent variable is the debt ratio or the percentage share of shadow financing activities during the time period from 2003 to 2013. The general regression equation is of the form: yit๏ฝ๏ ๏ ๏ก๏ ๏ซ๏ Σxit ๏ซ๏ ๏ฅit, i ๏ฝ๏ ๏ฑ๏ฌ๏ฒ๏ฌ๏ฎ๏ฎ๏ฎ๏ t ๏ฝ๏ฑ๏ฌ๏ฎ๏ฎ๏ฎ๏ฑ๏ฐ๏ In this model, yit represents the leverage of real estate firm i in year t; ๏ก๏ is the constant term; Σxit is a vector of independent variables which serve as explanatory indicators; ๏ฅit, is the unobserved error term or disturbance term. Based on the literature review, the regression model will be constructed in the following expression: %SF = f (IR,LV, COSIZE, PROF, REL, REM, EX, GDS) 37 %SF serves as the dependent variable that represents the short term debt ratio with the size of total assets. The independent variables are: IR - interest rates, LV -land values, COSIZE - company size, PROF – profitability, REL - real estate loans from banks, REM - OFW remittances, EX - exchange rates, and GDS gross domestic savings. The table below serves as a summary of independent variables to be tested with the corresponding signs. Hausman Test In determining whether to use fixed effects or random effect in running the model, the Hausman test is performed. The Hausman test serves as a statistical hypothesis test that evaluates the consistency of an estimator when compared to an alternative estimator. Under the null hypothesis, random effects is appropriate, while under the alternative hypothesis, fixed effects is appropriate. Structural Vector Autoregression Model In this section, the structured vector autoregression model (SVAR) is also used to analyze the factors that affect shadow financing. VAR serves as an nequation with n-endogenous variables, where each variable is explained by its own lag, as well as current and past values of other endogenous variables in the model. Therefore, in the context of modern econometrics, VAR is considered as multivariate time series that treats all variables endogenous, since there is no confidence that a variable is actually exogenous, and VAR allows the data to tell what actually happen. SVAR is said to be useful for two following reasons. First, relative to a quantitative model, SVARs allow more flexible specifications, and 38 the integration of a larger number of shocks. Second, relative to a panel regression, the SVARs explicitly assume that all variables are endogenous and interact between them. SVARs are immune to arguments of reverse causality, and to incorrectly assuming that a variable is exogenous when it is not. This same methodology was applied in a study conducted on analyzing the drivers of housing markets in China by Yang Bian and Gete (2015) and also in a working paper entitled “What drives Shadow Banking System in the Short Run and Long Run?” conducted by Duca (2014) in the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. Based on the study, short run changes of shadow banking was modelled that includes a function of an error-correction term (EC = actual minus equilibrium log-levels of shadow banking). The error-correction coefficients were seen to be highly significant, with an expected negative sign. For this study, the model is mainly used to test whether past shadow financing activities affect present values of shadow financing. The model is constructed as follows: %๐๐น๐ก = ๏ข0 + ๏ข1 %๐๐น๐ก−2 + ๏ข2 ๐๐ ๐ ๐๐ก๐ ๐ก−2 + ๏ข3 ๐๐๐๐๐๐ก๐ก−2 + ๏ข4REL + ๏ข5 ๐๐๐๐๐๐ก−2+ ๏ข6 ๐ผ๐ ๐ก−1 ๐๐ก The model includes a lagged dependent variable to control for residuals autocorrelation and account for the adjustment delay of the observed %SF. White Cross-sectional Method The White cross-sectional method is used get a more accurate and unbiased results from regressions, in this case, there cannot be any correlations between error terms. Thus, to remove possible correlations and reducing standard 39 error estimates, this method must be applied. The white cross-sectional method assumes that the errors are contemporaneously correlated. If there are fixed effects in the periods this method is used to correct for correlations such as heteroscedasticity. 40 CHAPTER IV PRESENTATION, INTERPRETATION, AND ANALYSIS OF DATA This section presents the results on the data gathered from the consolidated financial statements of the observed real estate companies. It also presents significant results from the regression model that determines the factors that could affect the growth of shadow banking for listed real estate companies. A. Breakdown of Shadow Banking Activities Total supplier financing (figure 4) portrays an upward trend with an estimated value of Php 17 billion in 2004 to Php 111 billion in 2013. A steady growth is seen from 2004 to 2010, while a rapid increase began in 2011 to 2013. This explains that there has been an increasing amount of construction loans or loans related to land and property development incurred by the listed companies. (See Appendix 2) Figure 4. Total Supplier Financing Supplier Financing (in thousand Php) 120,000,000 100,000,000 80,000,000 Supplier Financing 60,000,000 40,000,000 20,000,000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 41 Total in – house financing (figure 5) also reveals an upward growth, although not as high and as rapid as supplier financing. But similar to supplier financing, there has also been a great rise of in – house financing activities that occurred in 2012 to 2013. Still, it shows that financing coming from instalment contracts and customer deposits post a significant portion of shadow banking. For full details of Supplier financing activities see Appendix 2. Figure 5. Total In-house Financing In - house Financing (in thousand Php) 60,000,000 50,000,000 40,000,000 In - house Financing 30,000,000 20,000,000 10,000,000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Financing made through private placements (figure 6) show a more stunted growth from 2004 to 2011 with an average amount of Php 13 billion. However, there has also been a sudden increase in private placement financing that occurred from 2011 to 2013. This means that there has been an increase in financing through bonds and notes payables. (See Appendix 3) 42 Figure 6. Total Private Placement Financing Private Placements (in thousand Php) 120,000,000 100,000,000 80,000,000 Private Placements 60,000,000 40,000,000 20,000,000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 The combined data (figure 7) reveals that shadow banking activities as a whole have been continuously increasing from an estimated value of Php 43 billion in 2004 to Php 268 billion in 2013. The largest contributor to shadow banking throughout the years mainly comes from supplier financing. This is followed by in – house financing which contributed a larger growth from 2004 to 2010, with a value of Php 16 billion to Php 29 billion. However, during 2011 to 2013, private placements had a more significant increase compared to in – house financing, which grew from Php 32 billion to Php101 billion. 43 Figure 7. Breakdown of Shadow banking growth Breakdown of Shadow Banking Activiites (in thousand Php) 300,000,000 250,000,000 Private Placements 200,000,000 In-House Financing 150,000,000 Supplier Financing 100,000,000 50,000,000 2004200520062007200820092010201120122013 Total assets of listed real estate developers similarly portray an increasing trend from a total amount of Php 2.8 billion in 2004 to Php 1.1 trillion in 2013 (Figure 8). This shows the increasing flow of investments made among the developers through the years. The significant portion of this is derived from the net operating income that the developers get from tenants. (See Appendix 8). Figure 8. Total Assets of Selected Real Estate Developers in the Philippines Total Assets (in thousand Php) 1,200,000,000 1,000,000,000 800,000,000 600,000,000 Total Assets 400,000,000 200,000,000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 44 The net income of listed real estate developers also shows an increasing trend from 2004 to 2013 (figure 9), indicating a strong and healthy performance in the sector. Net profit reached an average amount of Php 50 billion in 2013 from a value of Php 10 billion in 2004 (See Appendix 9). The increase in profit implies an increasing return on investments from real estate operations. With increasing profits, this would allow the companies to engage in more debt financing activities, or the companies could make use of profit generated resources for the funding of their projects. Figure 9. Total Profit of Selected Real Estate Developers in the Philippines Total Profit (in thousand Php) 60,000,000 50,000,000 40,000,000 30,000,000 Total Profit 20,000,000 10,000,000 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 In terms of determining the proportion of shadow banking to total assets (figure 10), the shadow banking ratio portrayed a steady growth with an average of 15% from 2004 to 2011. However, as of 2012 – 2013, the percentage share of shadow banking over total assets greatly rose to an average of 24%. In this case, the rapid growth of shadow banking could contribute to greater risks if certain measures are not taken keep debt levels at minimum. 45 Figure 10. Percentage Share of Shadow banking to Total Assets % Share of Shadow banking to Total Assets 30.00% 9.38% 25.00% Private Placements 20.00% 15.00% 2.90% 5.12% 10.00% 5.93% 5.00% 6.28% In-house Supplier 10.31% 0.00% 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 B. Regression Analysis In applying the Hausman test, results show that the p-value is greater than 0.05, which indicates that random effects is more appropriate in running the model. This also means that the statistical model corresponds to the data presented. In running the panel regression under random effects, various combinations of lags and leads were used to get the most fitted model. Other explanatory variables were dropped in the model, since they were estimated to be insignificant, and did not exactly match a more fitted model. The variables that were dropped were: OFW remittances, exchange rates and Gross domestic savings. As seen in Table 2, the most fitted model that came out was in lagging the dependent variable, %SF, to two years, along with a combination of 2 leads for assets, profit and price (land values) and a 1 year lag for interest rates. Certain 46 adjustments were also applied by using the White test in consideration for the existence of autocorrelation. Table 2. Estimated Shadow Financing Function Source: Author’s computation The above empirical results show that shadow financing as a lagged variable is statistically significant at 0.2% level, which confirms the theory that past shadow financing activities have a positive correlation with the present condition of shadow financing operations. The coefficient of lagged shadow financing displayed values of 0.56, which means that if past values of shadow financing increased by 1%, the current share of shadow financing are likely to increase by 0.55%. The company size, which is determined by the total assets of the companies, is seen significant at 13% degree of error. The variable displayed a coefficient value of -3.26, which means that if total assets increase by 1 unit, the 47 percentage share of shadow financing would decrease by 3.26%. In comparison with the study on factors affecting leveraging for quoted real estate development companies in China, the results were different, where company size had a positive correlation with leverage and significant at 5% level. The negative correlation in this model goes against Pandey’s theory that there is a positive correlation between company size based on assets and shadow banking. This may be due to the reason that the total assets of selected real estate developers grew at a much faster rate compared to shadow banking, which explains the negative sign. In the study conducted in China, total assets had a positive correlation wit the debt financing activitites of real estate developers, this may be because their debt financing activities are larger compared to their net assets. Profitability was positive and statistically significant at 0.8%, as claimed by trade off theory that this should have a positive relationship with debt financing. It had a coefficient value of 1.51, which means that if annual profit increased by 1 unit, the percentage share of shadow financing would increase by 1.51%. The positive correlation follows Minsky’s theory which explains that profitable firms are less likely to go bankrupt, and can avail for more debt at cheaper rates of interest. Based on the trend of net profit among the companies (figure 9), it shows that company profits have been continually increasing. Thus, the higher the profit the companies make the more likely that the companies would go into shadow banking activities, as it gains more confidence that these firms would be able to pay back. 48 Moreover, the interest rates variable with a lag of two years was negative and statistically significant at 2%. The variable had a coefficient value of – 2, this implies that a 1% decrease in interest rates would cause a rise of shadow financing by 2%. The negative relationship follows the credit cycle theory that low interest rates stimulate an increase in borrowings from the shadow banking system. The general increase in shadow banking among the real estate developers may be due to the observation that the average informal interest rates of real estate companies across the period have been declining over the years. Macroeconomic variables were also considered in the regression and posted significant results. Real estate loans from banks was positive and statistically significant at 0.1%. It had a coefficient value of 0.21, which means that if loans from banks increase by 1 unit, the percentage share of shadow financing would increase by 0.21%. The negative correlation goes against the theory that shadow financing activities are less likely to occur as more loans are allowed to be lended out by banks at cheaper interest rates. In the case of the Philippines, there is still an increasing growth of shadow financing activities despite the increasing trend of real estate loans from banks. This may be due to the actual observation that shadow banks are not subject to bank limits on loans (Elliott, Kroeber and Qiao, 2015). Lastly, land values had a negative relationship with shadow financing, which goes against the theory that an appreciation of land values would indicate high financing costs, thus causing companies to borrow more from other nonfinancial institutions. The negative correlation between land prices and shadow 49 financing in the real estate could mean that the developers mostly finance for mid – income projects, instead of high-end segments where land prices are high. As stated by KMC MAG Group Managing Director Michael McCulllogh (2014), it is the middle income and low cost demand in Metro Manila that has kept the market demand buoyant and occupancy rates high, while slower growth is observed in the high – end segments. He also added that there is a growing middle – class that is fueling the retail market, encouraging retail developers to pursue aggressive expansion plans. As of 2014, the SM Group planned to invest Php 38.8 billion, concentrating on areas outside of Metro Manila. The group aimed at expanding its mall portfolio to 7.5 million square meters, which is nearly half of the total retail space in the country. Ayala Land Inc. planned at operating 500 convenience stores within the next five years and has also entered a joint venture with Rustan's to open the first Wellworth department store in Fairview Terraces (PR Newswire, 2014). Projects that cater to mid – income groups usually have lower land prices. In this case, land values had a coefficient value of -0.002, which means that a 1 unit decrease in the price of land would lead to an increase of shadow financing by only 0.002%. 50 Table 3. Regression Results In analyzing the factors that affect shadow banking in the real estate sector, the panel regression reveals significant results (Appendix 10). The R – squared serves as a statistical measure of how close the data are to the fitted regression model. It can range between the value of 0 and 1, where a value closer to 1 indicates that a greater proportion of variance is accounted for by the model. In this case, the regression analysis displayed an R-squared value of 0.618, thereby explaining that about 61.8% of the total variations of shadow financing can be explained by the independent variables. The remaining 38.2% may be explained by the error terms. In this case, since the r-squared value is small, it should be noted that this model cannot be used for forecasting future trends of shadow banking. Thus, it mainly serves its purpose of determining the factors that affect the percentage share of shadow banking to total assets. The F – Stat tests the overall significance of the regression model. It tries to evaluate the null hypothesis that all regression coefficients are equal to zero against the alternative that at least one coefficient is not. The F-value is the ratio of the mean regression sum of squares divided by the mean sum of squares. A 51 significant F – test indicates that the observed R – squared is reliable, and does not contain any spurious results from the data set. Thus, the F – test determines whether the proposed relationship between the dependent variable and the explanatory variables is statistically significant. The Prob(F) is the probability that the null hypothesis for the entire model is true ( that all regression coefficients are zero). In this model, the F – stat having a value of 11 is greater than Prob (F) with a value of zero. This would mean that the regression equation is valid enough in fitting the data. The Durbin – Watson statistic serves as a test for autocorrelation of residuals (error terms) in a regression model. A DW value near 0 indicates that there is a strong positive autocorrelation that exists, a DW value near 2 indicates that there is minimal amount of autocorrelation, and a DW value near 4 indicates that there is strong negative autocorrelation. Based on the result of the model, the DW value is 1.93 which proves that the white test has minimized the presence of autocorrelation in the model. 52 CHAPTER V SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS This thesis aimed to answer the questions: (1) How do shadow banking activities occur in the real estate sector? (2) What is the estimated the share of shadow banking activities among listed real estate developers in the Philippines? (3) What are the main drivers that contribute to the growth of shadow banking activities in the real estate sector? This study revolved around these three questions which are rooted from the notion that there is an emerging growth of unmonitored debt financing or shadow banking particularly in the real estate sector. There have been various studies as discussed in Chapter II explaining how shadow banking have occurred in other countries and how its continuing growth led to certain systemic risks. There has also been a similar study done in another country that tries to examine the factors that affect the capital structure of their real estate developments. The variables that were seen greatly significant were company size, as measured by the total assets of each company and profitability. Other economists suggest that certain macroeconomic conditions may also impact the shadow financing in the real estate industry such as OFW remittances and gross domestic savings (GDS). In determining the growth trend of shadow banking of listed developers in the Philippines, the consolidated financial statements of the observed companies were gathered to examine the values behind their debt financing activities from 2004 to 2013. In analyzing the factors that could affect the growth of the 53 companies’ shadow banking activities, a panel regression random effects model was used, along with structural vector autoregression (SVAR) which showed significant results. A. Summary of Results Increasing Growth of Shadow Banking Activities Based on the data collected, shadow banking activities which are associated with supplier financing, in – house financing and private placement financing have been generally increasing throughout the years. However, a more striking growth occurred from periods 2011 to 2013. This may be due to the surge of demand on residential properties that occurred during this period. This then confirms the notion that there is indeed an increasing trend of shadow banking activities in the real estate sector. In generating the model that determines the factors behind shadow banking growth, the variables (assets, profit, real estate loans from banks, land values and interest rates) were seen statistically significant. The model also has an r – squared value of 0.618, which means that 61.8% of the variance of shadow financing can be explained by these variables. Other macro variables such as remittances, exchange rates and gross domestic savings were dropped as they were statistically insignificant, which means that these variables may not have an impact or have lesser effect on the shadow financing activities of real estate developers. 54 B. Conclusion This study has proven that there is indeed a rising trend of shadow banking activities in the real estate sector, particularly visible among listed real estate developers in the country. This study has also empirically proven that industry factors such as profit and interest rates post significant effects toward the growth of shadow banking. Past values of shadow banking can also influence the present shadow banking activities in the sector. Other factors such as land values and loans from banks are also seen significant. Whereas in the Philippine setting, most developers associate their financing activities to mid – income segments where the value of land is low, thus having low property prices. Moreover, the supply of loans from banks can also affect shadow banking, although it has also been observed that shadow banking activities are not subject to bank limits on loans. Other macroeconomic factors such as OFW remittances, exchange rates and gross domestic savings were seen to be insignificant, which means that these variables may not have that much impact on shadow banking in the real estate. C. Recommendation The research that has been done for this thesis has revealed significant findings on which future studies could find it beneficial. Further studies on shadow banking, particularly in the real estate sector, may include a larger sample size, or longer periods of observation to fully capture the shadow banking conditions in the sector. Future studies may also try using only shadow banking (not as a portion of total assets) as a dependent variable in running a regression to 55 accurately determine the factors behind its growth. Future researchers can also try other methods in determining the factors that drive shadow banking. Real estate firms around the country could also make use of this study in analyzing the risk factors that affect the real estate market. Given the increasing trend of shadow banking in the real estate industry, the firms could re-evaluate their debt financing schemes and take precautionary measures in facilitating credit intermediation. Furthermore, the BSP could implement more stringent policy measures that would contain the build up of shadow banking activities particularly in the real estate market, so as to prevent certain systemic risks. 56 BIBLIOGRAPHY Abraham, Stephen. “4 Ways to Value A Real Estate Rental Property”. Accessed January 10, 2015. http://www.investopedia.com/articles/mortgages-realestate/11/how-to-value-real-estate-rental.asp. Agabin, Meliza, and Lamberte, Mario. Integrative report On the Informal Credit Markets in the Philippines. Philippine Institute for development Studies, 1989. Ang, Karen. The Pros and cons of Shadow Banking, 2013. Accessed December 20, 2014. http://research.bworldonline.com/populareconomics/story.php?id=91&title=The-pros-and-cons-of-shadow-banking. Ascarya (2013). Analysis of Financial Crisis and How to Prevent Itin Islamic Perspective using Vector Error Correction Model. Central Banking Education and Studies Department, Bank Indonesia. Ballesteros, Marife. Housing and Real Estate Development and the Potential Risk of a Housing Bubble. Accessed January 10, 2015. http://www.pids.gov.ph/files/outreach/Ballesteros-Housing.pdf. Bayangos, Veronica. Going with Remittances: the Case of the Philippines. (July 2012). Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas. BSP Working Paper Series. Accessed March 25, 2014. http://www.bsp.gov.ph/downloads/publications/2012/wps201201.pdf. Brealey, R. A., Myers, S. C., & Allen, F. (2008). Principles of Corporate Finance (9th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. Carpenter, Seth. Informal Credit Markets and the Transmission of Monetary Policy: Evidence from Korea. Review of Development Economics, 1999. Davis, E Philip and Zhu, Haibin. (2004)Bank Lending and Commercial Property cycles: some cross – country evidence. Access April 30, 2015 from http://www.bis.org/publ/work150.pdf Duca, John (2014). What Drives the Shadow Banking System in the Short Run and Long Run?. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas. “Easy Financing Schemes for Homebuyers.” Rappler,2014. Accessed January 10, 2015. http://www.rappler.com/brandrap/58370-easy-financing-schemesfor-home-buyers. Elliott, Douglas, Kroeber, Arthur and Yu, Qiao. Shadow Banking in China: A primer. (March 2015) Accessed April 29, 2015. http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/papers/2015/04/01shadow-banking-chinaprimer/shadow_banking_china_elliott_kroeber_yu.pdf. 57 Financial Stability Board. (2014). Global Shadow Banking Monitoring Report 2014. Ghosh, Swati, Gonzalez del Mazo, Ines and Otker-Robe, Inci. “Chasing the Shadows: How Significant is Shadow Banking in Emerging Markets?” (September 2012). Accessed January 10, 2015. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTPREMNET/Resources/EP88.pdf. Global Property Guide. Philippines’ real estate boom is weaking. Accessed February 17, 2015. http://www.globalpropertyguide.com/Asia/Philippines/Price-HistoryArchive/Philippines-real-estate-boom-is-weakening-1. Global Property Guide. Slowdown in residential property price rises in Manila. (2014) Accessed February 17, 2015. http://www.globalpropertyguide.com/Asia/Philippines/Price-History. Haugen, Norunn (2005). The Informal credit market: A study of default and informal lending in Nepal. Accessed April 30, 2015 from http://www.cmi.no/publications/file/1937-the-informal-credit-market.pdf. International Monetary Fund. Chapter II: Household Credit Growth in Emerging Market Countries. (2006). Accessed January 10, 2015. https://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/GFSR/2006/02/pdf/chap2.pdf. International Monetary Fund (IMF). Global Financial Stability Report: Risk Taking, Liquidity and Shadow Banking – Curbing Excess While Promoting Growth. (October 2014). Accessed February 15, 2015. http://www.ledevoir.com/documents/pdf/FMI_stabilit%C3%A9.pdf. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2014 Article IV Consultation – Staff Report; Press Release. Accessed February 3, 2015. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2014/cr14245.pdf. Jeffers, Esther and Pilhon, Dominique. Universal Banking and Shadow Banking in Europe. (2014). Accessed April 20, 2015. https://fernandonogueiracosta.files.wordpress.com/2014/10/jeffers-plihoneuropean-shadow-banking4.pdf. KMC MAG Gropu. Midyear Report. Accessed April 28, 2015. http://c.kmcmaggroup.com/pdfs/2014/metro-manila-mid-year-report2014-v2.pdf. Kodres, Laura. What is Shadow Banking? (2013). Accessed January 25, 2015. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2013/06/basics.htm. Kritz, Ben. “Special Report: In-house financing raises alarm over unregulated growth”. Manila Times. September 14, 2014. Accessed January 25, 2015. http://www.manilatimes.net/in-house-financing-raises-alarm-overunregulated-growth/126681/. 58 Lamudi. Your Options: Bank vs. in – house financing. (2014). Accessed January 13, 2015. http://www.lamudi.com.ph/journal/options-bank-vs-housefinancing/. Lim, Thian Cheng, Zhao, Dan & Chai, Ruiyang. “Capital Structure of Real Estate Firms in Chinese Stock Market”. International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Research. (2012). Accessed March 17, 2015. http://www.ijmsbr.com/volume%201,issue%209%20paper%20(8).doc.pdf. Lindner, Fabian. “Does Saving Increase the Supply of Credit? A Critique of Loanable Funds Theory”. Macroeconomic Policy Institute, Dusseldorf, Germany. (September 2013). Accessed April 15, 2015. http://www.boeckler.de/pdf/p_imk_wp_120_2013. Manganelli, Benedetto. Real Estate Investing Market Analysis, Valuation Techniques and Risk Management. Martin, Kathleen. “Local Banks pass stress tests – BSP”. Philstar, February 25, 2015. Accessed March 8, 2015. http://www.philstar.com/business/2015/02/25/1427243/local-banks-passstress-tests-bsp. Mckenzie, Dennis. Essentials of Real Estate Economics. (2011). Pp. 395 – 396. Nguyen, Joseph. “4 Key Factors That Drive the Real Estate Market”. Investopedia Accessed March 8, 2015. http://www.investopedia.com/articles/mortagesreal-estate/11/factors-affecting-real-estate-market.asp. Philippines’ real estate boom is weaking. Accessed February 17, 2015. http://www.globalpropertyguide.com/Asia/Philippines/Price-HistoryArchive/Philippines-real-estate-boom-is-weakening-1. PR Newswire. “Foreign Investments, Focus on Middle – income Housing to Power Growth in Philippine Real Estate Market”. Accessed April 28, 2014. http://en.prnasia.com/story/104027-0.shtml. Mankiw, Gregory N., Macroeconomics, Third Edition, New York: Worth Publishers, 1997. Rappler. “Easy Financing Schemes for Homebuyers”. (2014). Accessed January 10, 2015. http://www.rappler.com/brandrap/58370-easy-financingschemes-for-home-buyers. Stammers, Robert. “How Interest Rates Affect Property Values”. Investopedia. http://www.investopedia.com/articles/mortgages-real-estate/08/interestrates-affect-property-values.asp. 59 Valckx, Nico. “Shadow Banking Around the Globe: How Large and How Risky?” International Monetary Fund (IMF). (2014). Accessed January 24, 2015. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfsr/2014/02/pdf/c2.pdf. Pozsar, Zoltan. “Shadow Banking” (2013). PR Newswire. “Foreign Investments, Focus on Middle – income Housing to Power Growth in Philippine Real Estate Market”. (2014). Accessed April 28, 2014 from: http://en.prnasia.com/story/104027-0.shtml. Simiyu, Lunami Abiud & Huo, Xuexi. “Factors Affecting Leveraging for Quoted Real Estate Development in China” International Journal of Economics and Finance; Vol. 5, No. 7; 2013. Canadian Center of Science and Education. Yang Bian, Timothy and Gete, Pedro . “What Drives Housing Dynamics in China? (2015). A Sign Restrictions VAR Approach”. Accessed April 21, 2015 from http://faculty.georgetown.edu/pg252/Bian-Gete_China_SVAR.pdf. Zelmanovitz, L. “The Austrian Business Cycle Theory and The Recent Financial Crisis.” Criterio Libre 9, no. 15 (2011): 25-58. 60 APPENDIX Appendix 1: List of Observed Companies SM Prime Holdings, Inc., (SMPH) Megaworld Corp., (MEG) Ayala Land, Inc., (ALI) Robinsons Land Corp., Filinvest Land, Inc., (FLI) Rockwell Land Corp., (RLC) Vista Land and Lifescapes, Inc., (VLLI) Sta. Lucia Land, Inc. Shang Properties 61 Appendix 2: Breakdown of Supplier Financing 62 63 Appendix 3: Breakdown of In-house Financing 64 65 Appendix 4: Breakdown of Private Placement Financing 66 67 Appendix 5: Total Supplier Financing 68 Appendix 6: Total In-house Financing 69 Appendix 7: Total Private Placement Financing 70 Appendix 8: Total Assets 71 Appendix 9: Total Profit 72 Appendix 10: Panel Regression Data 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 Appendix 11: Results of Regression on %Shadow Financing with White Cross-Sectional Test 80