ALASKA NATURAL GAS EXPORTS: FISCAL STABILITY VERSUS THE STATE’S CONSTITUTION Douglas B. Reynolds, University of Alaska Fairbanks, (907) 474-6531, DBReynolds@Alaska.Edu Key Words: Natural Gas, Alaska Gas Exports, Fiscal Stability Overview Alaska has long discussed exporting its vast natural gas resources on the North Slope to Pacific Rim destinations in China, Japan and Korea. However, the North Slope natural gas resources have been deemed too far away from consuming markets to be economically exploitable, although that is now changing with the high growth rates, high environmental and energy security concerns and high natural gas prices in the Pacific Rim region. Other determining issues in the past that precluded North Slope natural gas from being exported included: the loss of oil production due to reduced pressure; United States energy security concerns; the high costs of Alaska construction; and, importantly, Alaska’s fiscal stability. While many of these problems can be overcome, one issue—Alaska’s fiscal stability—is still a problem. Over the years, the Alaska tax fiscal system has been a thorn in the side of any agreement to get an Alaska natural gas export project approved, because oil and gas producers are reluctant to commit to any project unless Alaska guarentees its natural gas production tax rates wont change in the future. However, Alaska’s constitution specifies that Alaska may not bind tax rates for future legislatures using a tax contract. This issue is interesting since it is an issue that many oil and gas countries and regions around the world deal with, i.e. trying to maximize the value of a resource while simultanesouly not giving away the right for any future government revenue increases. For example on the one hand, most countries want to make binding contracts on mineral rights, including the government take on those rights, in order to develop specific oil and gas reserves and maximize the value of those reserves, but on the other hand, those governments also want the flexibility to change any contract later. Indeed countries have been known to change contracts after oil and gas development has occurred by for example nationalizing those fields when the government no longer likes the terms of their contracts and fiscal systems. Nevertheless, this paper is an analysis of the Alaska Constitutional restrictions on fiscal system contracts that exist in Alaska. The paper gives an analysis of one way to deal with this issue. First, Section 8 of the Alaska state constitution specifies that the maximization of natural resource value in Alaska shall be pursued. However, Section 9 of the same constitution specifies that there can be no tax contracts that bind future legislatures’ right to change taxes. The idea of this paper is to show a game theory analysis of how obtaining bids in the form of a fiscal tax contract and a purchasing contract could create a credible threat to lease holding producers to give their best fiscal terms to Alaska in a binding contractual form. Then because Alaska will have two government take contracts from which to choose its best option to develop its natural gas, then it will show that the contracts maximize the resource value. The result would be that Section 8—maximization—can trump Section 9—no tax contract—of the constitution. This is one way to maximize the value of Alaska’s natural gas resource without changing its constitution. Methodology This paper will show the costs and benefits of one alternative solution to Alaska’s fiscal system (taxation) dilemma. Specifically, the idea of a competitive contract bid on competing contracts for fiscal and other terms. Former governor Palin already tried a competitive contract concept to get a natural gas project started, but that contract has so far been unsuccessful. Nevertheless, that competitive bidding and contract did not include a competitive bid on fiscal tax contracts which are needed to set fiscal stability agreements in place in order to get a large export project financed. An alternative competitive bid is specified here that is different from the Palin competitive bidding in many ways. The idea is to sell the state’s royalty natural gas to the highest bidder by having two different bids that would include a fiscal contract as a part of the bid in order to nullify the no tax contract article of the State’s constitution. Considering that the other constitutional article—section 8—specifies that Alaska must maximize resource value, this might work to nullify section 9 that specifies that no tax contract can be engaged in. It would be a contract on fiscal systems that would include competition from non-resource lease owners. Results This paper will show the game theory analysis results and the need for a credible threat to the producers to obtain the best fiscal contract and other terms. It will show the costs and benefits of the idea of a competitive fiscal contract bid as well as a possible set up and a possible stick that would get the producers to give a competitive contract that would maximize the state of Alaska’s resource value. Conclusions The Alaska constitution section 9 is set up so that you cannot get a California situation where the state legislature is not allowed to increase taxes even though inflation is high and the tax caps and therefore the tax revenues have inflated away to nothing in real terms, as has happened in California under proposition 13 in 1978. The Alaska legislature cannot make a binding tax contract deal to develop a resource under the Alaska state constitution. This is so that if a contract were make and then it was found out later that the deal is a net loss to Alaska with no way to change the fiscal contract, that Alaska would have no way out of the contract. Nevertheless, the North Slope natural gas value is subject to much risk and volatility, therefore a tax contract could be the difference between making a natural gas project viable or not, and thus maximizing the value of Alaska’s resources. This paper will show how a bidding system for a contact will work. References Alaska Department of Revenue. State Financial Participation in an Alaska Natural Gas Pipeline. January 31, 2002. _________. Alaska Gas Pipeline Financing Alternatives: Use of Tax-Exempt Financing through the Alaska Railroad. February 7, 2002. Bechtel, O'Melveny & Myers LLP, Alaska Gasline Port Authority, and Taylor-DeJongh. AGPA Engineering, Procurement and Construction Study: Financial and Economic Presentation. March 1, 2002. Berman, Mathew D. Purchasing Petroleum Industry Investment with Fiscal Incentives. May 2, 1996. BP, Exxon Mobil, & Phillips. Alaska Gas Pipeline Status Report. August 1, 2001. BP, Exxon Mobil, & Phillips. Alaska Producer Pipeline Update. April 1, 2002. Cambridge Energy Research Associates (CERA). CERA Workshop on the North American Gas and World LNG Markets. June 23, 2001. CERA. Toward New Frontiers: The Future of Gas Supply in North America. Winter 2001. Canadian Energy Research Institute. A Comparison of Natural Gas Pipeline Options for the North. October 1, 2000. Chmiel, Ilona & M. C. McCracken. Cost Benefit Analysis of the Alaska Natural Gas Transmission System. January 1, 2002. Clifton, L.J. and B. J. Gallaway, (2001). “History of Trans-Alaska Pipeline System,” http://tapseis.anl.gov/documents/docs/Section_13_May2.pdf, read February 23rd, 2005, in Trans-Alaskan Pipeline System Environmental Impact Statement, Joint Pipeline Office, US department of the Interior, Alaska State Department of Natural Resources. Dismukes, David E. Alaska Natural Gas In-State Demand Study. January 23, 2002. Exxon Mobil. Point Thomson Gas Cycling Project Overview. October 1, 2001. Fischer, Victor (2012) From Russia with love, Foothills Pipelines Ltd. Executive Summary of the Alaska Natural Gas Transportation System Group's Commercial Proposal to Alaska North Slope Shippers. January 2000. Goldsmith, Scott. Northstar Oil Field: Economic Impact Analysis. February 23, 1998. Northern Economic Research Associates. The Alaskan Natural Gas Transmission System: An Economic Analysis of Various Pipeline Proposals. Report presented to the Alaska State Legislature’s Joint Committee on Natural Gas, August 19, 2002. O'Melveny & Myers LLP. LNG: Going Global. May 1, 2001. Phillips, BP, Foothills Pipelines, Marubeni Corporation. Alaska North Slope LNG Project. March 6, 2001. Phillips, Marathon Oil Company. Kenai Liquefied Natural Gas Operations. January 2000. Purvin & Gertz, Inc. Alaskan Gas Development Strategies. October 2000. Roderick, Jack (1997). Crude Dreams: A Personal History of Oil and Politics in Alaska, Epicenter Press, Seattle. Riddlehoover, Robert and Barry Pulliam. Alaska Gas and NGL: Economic Analysis of Value and Royalty. January 1, 2002. Sharp, Alan. Royalty In Kind (RIK) Sale: House Special Committee on Oil & Gas. February 13, 2002. Taylor-DeJongh and Alaska Gasline Port Authority. AGPA Financial Model Assumptions and Results. July 1, 2001. Taylor-DeJongh and Alaska Gasline Port Authority. September 1, 2001. AGPA Financial Model Assumptions and Results. United States Energy Information Administration (EIA). The Effect of the Alaska Oil and Natural Gas Provision of H. R. 4 and S. 1766 on U.S. Energy Markets. February 1, 2002. Van Meurs, A. Pedro H. Suggestions for New Terms for the Alaska North Slope LNG Projects: A Background Report. Van Meurs and Associates, Ltd. February 12, 1997. Yukon Economic Development. Northern Pipelines: Overview of Technical Issues Surrounding Northern Pipelines. November 1, 2001. Yukon Pacific Corporation. Presentation on the TAGS Small Project. February 1, 2002.