Surplus, Efficiency, and Deadweight Loss (“Economics” – Chapter 5) We just finished a detailed examination of the interaction of buyers and sellers in a market. As a result of this interaction, who benefits and to what degree? That is: How much does a buyer gain from making a purchase? How much does a seller gain from making a sale? In total, how much do buyers collectively and sellers collectively gain from trade in a particular market? In total, how much does society as a whole gain from trade in a particular market? Recall the… “Vertical Interpretation” of curves – start by focusing on a particular quantity demanded (or supplied), and then go up to the curve vertically to determine the corresponding price at which this particular quantity would be demanded (or supplied) price price Supply 5.25 4.50 2.75 Demand quantity 0 0 1,250 1.50 0 quantity 2,400 3,500 4,750 0 1 Also recall… Buyer’s Reservation Price – maximum dollar amount a buyer is willing to give up in order to acquire an item At any particular quantity demanded, the height of the demand curve illustrates the “reservation price” of the buyer of that unit. Seller’s Reservation Price – minimum dollar amount a seller is willing to accept in order to part with an item At any particular quantity supplied, the height of the supply curve illustrates the “reservation price” of the seller of that unit. Our measures of “benefits (or surplus) from trade” will be based upon these reservation prices… 2 Consumer’s Surplus and Producer’s Surplus: Consumer’s Surplus: When a buyer purchases an item for less than his reservation price he obtains a “gain” or “surplus” from doing so. Example: rb (22) and p (15) => buyer realizes a surplus of CS rb p 22 15 7 for this purchase Producer’s Surplus: When a producer sells an item for more than her reservation price she obtains a “gain” or “surplus” from doing so. Example: rs (12) and p (15) => seller realizes a surplus of PS p rs 15 12 3 from this sale Social Surplus: The Social Surplus of a trade is equal to the sum of gains over every person in society. For many goods, people other than buyer/seller have a surplus of (0) => Social Surplus is simply the sum of Consumer’s Surplus and Producer’s Surplus: SS CS PS (rb p) ( p rs ) rb rs In the example above: SS rb rs 22 12 10 “Price” complete drops out of the expression for Social Surplus. “Price at which trade takes place” is critical for determining how the “gains from trade” are “split” between the trading partners, but does not influence the magnitude of Social Surplus whatsoever. 3 Recall the market equilibrium outcome… Only “stable price” is at the intersection of the demand curve and the supply curve. price Supply p*=30 Demand 0 quantity 0 q*=D(30)=S(30)=55 Noted that the equilibrium in the model of Supply and Demand is: “stable” (if we are there we will stay there, unless outside forces change; but this had to be true by the definition of equilibrium) “unique” (there is one and only one equilibrium, a property which follows from the “Law of Demand” and “Law of Supply”) “self enforcing” (at higher prices there is downward pressure on price; at lower prices there is upward pressure on price – therefore if we start at any other price, we will be pushed toward the equilibrium price) 4 But is it a “desirable outcome”? What is the “best level of trade” for society? One way to begin to address this question is by comparing the “Total Social Surplus” at the market equilibrium to the “Total Social Surplus” at other levels of trade… Total Social Surplus – a measure of the total gains from trade, defined as the sum of Total Consumers’ Surplus and Total Producers’ Surplus in the market. Total Consumers’ Surplus – a measure of the total gains from trade realized by consumers, defined as the difference between buyer’s reservation price and actual price paid added over all units purchased. Total Producers’ Surplus – a measure of the total gains from trade realized by sellers, defined as the difference between actual price received and seller’s reservation price added over all units sold. Recall, Social Surplus realized from trading one particular unit: SS CS PS (rb p) ( p rs ) rb rs . In order to maximize “Total Social Surplus,” which units should be traded and which units should not be traded? Do trade all units for which (rb rs ) 0 (or equivalently rb rs ) Do not trade any units for which (rb rs ) 0 (or equivalently rb rs ) Total Social Surplus is maximized by trading all units and only those units for which buyer’s reservation price exceeds seller’s reservation price 5 price Supply Maximum possible Social Surplus Demand 0 quantity 0 qe qe “Social Surplus Maximizing” or “Efficient” Level of Trade q* ? How does compare to That is, how does the equilibrium level of trade compare to the efficient level? The “Equilibrium Quantity of Trade” is “Efficient” in the sense that it maximizes Total Social Surplus (i.e., total gains from trade). Any other level of trade is “Inefficient” in the sense that Total Social Surplus is not as large as possible. Any other level of trade (either higher or lower) leads to a smaller realized value of Total Social Surplus. Note: to say that “free markets” are “efficient” is a bit of a simplification. In practice, several conditions must be met for this to be true, including: there must be many buyers and sellers in the market; information must be available at low cost; there cannot be any “external effects” associated with production/consumption of the good. 6 Deadweight Loss (DWL) – the difference between the “maximum possible level of Total Social Surplus” and the “realized level of Total Social Surplus.” DWL is zero at the efficient level of trade; DWL is positive at all other levels of trade. Inefficiency from “too little trade”: price Realized Social Surplus equal to “orange area” DWL Supply Demand quantity 0 0 Level of Trade below “Efficient Level” Inefficiency from “too little trade” – there are some units that we do not trade for which buyer’s reservation price is greater than seller’s reservation price (i.e., we do not trade all of the units we should trade). 7 Inefficiency from “too much trade”: price Realized Social Surplus equal to “orange area minus black area” DWL Supply Demand 0 quantity 0 Level of Trade above “Efficient Level” Inefficiency from “too much trade” – we trade some units for which seller’s reservation price is greater than buyer’s reservation price (i.e., we trade some units that we should not trade). Open-ended fallacy – the logical error whereby someone incorrectly concludes that simply because there are benefits (to some people) from higher levels of an activity, that more of the activity is always better Important to recognize that the socially best level of trade of any good is finite direct result of scarcity of resources => tradeoffs exist in regards to levels of production of different goods to maximize Total Social Surplus, appropriately compare and balance marginal benefits for society against marginal costs for society (exactly as suggested by CostBenefit Principle) 8 Finally, notice that the discussion of “deadweight loss” and the “efficient level of trade” made no mention of “price.” While price does not play any role in determining the “total gains from trade,” it is of critical importance in specifying how the “total gains” are “split” between buyers and sellers. “Equilibrium Price” serves to define the “split” of “total gains from trade” between buyers and sellers under the market equilibrium outcome: price Equilibrium Price Total Consumers’ Surplus (“green area”) Supply Total Social Surplus (“green area” plus “purple area”) Total Producers’ Surplus (“purple area”) Demand 0 quantity 0 “Efficient” Level of Trade, as well as “Equilibrium” Level of Trade 9