5 Network value 5.1 Introduction Enabling the network value of distributed generation to be captured by distributed generators is an important driver of efficient investment and installation of distributed generation technologies of all sizes. If network vale can be identified, captured and paid to those parties providing distributed generation, positive net network values can provide incentives to connect distributed generation in areas where it has the biggest benefits in reducing the cost of the network. Network costs are a major driver of retail electricity prices (ACIL Tasman 2012c). Positive network values signal areas where the existing network is close to, or at capacity, and investment in distributed generation would allow additional investment in the network to be deferred or avoided. Those able to connect distributed generation in these congested areas of the network would receive a greater financial incentive to do so than those proposing to connect in areas where the network value may be zero or negative because of the investment required to reinforce the network to accommodate distributed generation. Identifying and realising the network value of distributed generation is more difficult than identifying the output value of exported electricity because network value is location and time specific. In addition, it relies on distributed generation being able to guarantee production when it is needed by the network. Furthermore, network value is a capital value rather than a value based on per unit of output. If there were an effective market for identifying and realising network value the Commission expects that distribution businesses would plan measures, including for distributed generation, to alleviate identified localised system constraints where such investment would have a net benefit. The distribution businesses and the proponents of distributed generation would also be able to access sufficient information to assess the costs and benefits of the proposed distributed generation to the network and the proponent. The rules on how any necessary network reinforcement costs should be shared, and who pays, would be clear, efficient and equitable. Areas where network investment could be avoided by distributed generation (or demand side responses more generally) would be identified and payments made available to proponents of such investments. If distributed generation projects arise outside this planning and require investment to be brought forward the rules on how such projects would be charged would also be clear and predetermined. In these circumstances each party would be in a position to make an informed decision about the value of proposed investment in distributed generation. Such a system would allow distributed generation to be planned into the network and charges and payments to be defined up front as part of the Australian Energy Regulator’s (AER’s) five yearly price reset when regulated distribution charges are determined. This system would avoid the problem of one distributed generation project bearing the full cost of any necessary network reinforcement. However, the current market is unlikely to deliver this sort of outcome because distribution businesses are regional monopolies and therefore do not face competition, and the way they are regulated reinforces the traditional approach of meeting future demand by investing in the capability of the existing network. The Commission NETWORK VALUE 73 considers these issues and possible recommendations to address them in the remainder of the chapter. 5.2 How material is network value? The value of deferring additional investment in the network is both time and location specific, and where the network is constrained the value may be significant. Based on a range of estimates on the network value of distributed generation ACIL Tasman reported that: In a recent report to the AEMC, Ernst and Young noted that the network value of reducing growth in peak demand is complex and recommended “exercising extreme caution in using any (general) measure of value”. Ernst and Young considered that there was sufficient precedent for using “rules of thumb” of between $90 and $300 per kVA per year for deferred network expenditure. (ACIL Tasman 2012c, p.87) Another estimate found similar values: Similarly, in the context of the Victorian Advanced Metering Infrastructure program, Oakley Greenwood calculated the value of reduced growth in peak demand at $200 per kW, although this included the value of deferred investment in generation, so is greater than the network value. (ACIL Tasman 2012c, p.87) In very constrained networks the value of deferring can be very high. For example, in the very constrained parts of the Sydney network: … there are potential avoidable network costs of up to and beyond $1000 per kVA of peak demand reduction per year. If such a peak lasted, say 10 hours per year, this represents a potential avoidable cost of $1000/10 hours or about $100 per kWh. (Dunstan et al. 2011, p.11) In terms of what this means for a distributed generation in Victoria, ACIL Tasman noted that: If it is assumed that the network value is in the order of $150 per kW, and a 2.5 kW solar PV system defers a planned network augmentation by three years, the network value is $375 per year for the three years for which the augmentation is deferred. (ACIL Tasman 2012c, p.83) Currently there is little information about the nature, location and value of network constraints. This situation clearly limits the capacity of market participants to identify and value opportunities to relax these constraints and/or defer investments in the network. That said, the ACIL Tasman findings suggest that network value, if it could be realised and made available to the proponents of distributed generation, is likely to provide a material financial incentive for those in constrained parts of the network to invest in distributed generation. 5.3 Market power concerns Local distribution businesses have monopoly power, and access to information on where the network is constrained or is reaching capacity (hence where network value is greatest) and on the need for, and cost of, any network reinforcement necessary to support the connection of distributed generation. This is a significant information asymmetry. 74 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION Market power concerns can be reduced by putting distributed generation proponents in a better negotiating position. Increasing their negotiating position through the use of aggregators (being considered in the AEMO Small Generator Aggregator Framework rule change) would help by providing distributed generation proponents a degree of countervailing power (AEMO 2011). However, issues remain, the two key ones for this inquiry are: provision of better information increased clarity on the size and sharing of reinforcement costs. 5.3.1 Better information Many inquiry participants argued that information on network capacity by location could help reveal areas where network values are likely to be higher and inform better siting of investment in distributed generation. Such information would assist with negotiation thereby improving the functioning of the market and reduce connection costs. Distributed generators can benefit from information on where their projects are needed or can be tolerated in the network and where there are network constraints to their further addition. The lack of such information could be a significant barrier to efficient distributed generation investment and active demand management, and makes it more difficult for distributed generators to negotiate with monopoly distribution businesses. Many participants, for example Ironbark Sustainability, sub. 50 and the Clean Energy Council, sub. DR200 suggested that regulators should require the publication of better information about network constraints and other issues that may render certain locations unsuitable for new connections. The Energy Efficiency Council recommended the publication of: Annual maps of the costs and benefits of connecting cogeneration at different points on the grid, including potential payments for offsetting infrastructure investment. The pre-emptive analysis of the costs and benefits of connecting to the grid at different points would provide greater information transparency, opening up competition in the market. (sub. DR200, p. 11) In the UK, distribution network service providers (DNSPs) submit information strategies for regulatory approval (ACIL Tasman 2011b, p.30). Ironbark Sustainability suggested maps of network constraints could reduce barriers to distributed generation (sub. 50, p. 14). The Institute for Sustainable Futures prepared maps that identify network constraints that can help inform where distributed generation could result in savings from deferred network investment (SV 2012). However, these maps are not available on the Sustainability Victoria website. In addition, the ISF report does not contain information on fault levels, the main driver of distributed generation connection costs in Melbourne. Exigency’s submission argued that: Publication of network performance data (capacity constraints, quality of supply) would simultaneously support regulatory oversight of prudent network expenditure and enable the market to proactively devise non-network solutions. The process of consideration of non-network solutions by DNSPs could be made more transparent, for the benefit of energy market efficiency overall. (sub. 4, p. 3) NETWORK VALUE 75 The Clean Energy Council proposed that transparency could be improved by compelling the DNSPs to provide information in sufficient detail to inform negotiation (sub. DR197). The CEC suggested that any new arrangements should take account of the fact that DNSPs are monopoly businesses (CEC, sub. 76, p. 6). CitiPower and Powercor (sub. DR 184) and United Energy (sub. DR 199) claimed that such information is already available (discussed in the following section). The AEMC is currently considering a rule change request from the Ministerial Council on Energy on the Distribution Network Planning and Expansion Framework (AEMC 2011a). The proposed rule change includes a requirement for DNSPs to publish a Distribution Annual Planning Report (DAPR) that would detail peak demand, forecast augmentation of the network and, of particular relevance to distributed generation: … forecasts of any factors that may have a material impact on the network, including factors affecting: (A) fault levels; (B) voltage levels; (C) other power system security requirements; and (D) ageing and potentially unreliable assets. (AEMC 2011a S5.8(2)(v)) In June 2012, the AEMC published a draft rule determination and is seeking submissions on it by 9 August 2012. The AEMC states that: The Commission considers that the draft rule will contribute to the achievement of the National Electricity Objective by establishing a clearly defined and efficient planning process for distribution network investment. This will support the efficient development of distribution networks. The draft rule will also provide transparency to, and information on, distribution business planning activities and decision making processes. This will assist market participants in making efficient investment decisions and enable non-network providers to put forward credible non-network options as alternatives to network investment. (AEMC 2012d, p.1) The submission process for the draft rule determination will provide an opportunity for affected interested parties to comment on the value of the draft change from the perspective of removing barriers to the connection of distributed generation. The Commission’s view The Commission considers improved spatial information on network constraints and fault levels would improve contestability through fairer negotiation which would help reveal the network value of distributed generation, and better siting of investment leading to reduced connection costs. The information would allow distributed generator proponents to make judgements about likely connection costs and manage the risks of pursuing projects that are less likely to proceed. Information can support proponents to make informed decisions and to negotiate more effectively with DNSPs. The MCE’s proposed Distribution Network Planning and Expansion Framework rule change request is expected to improve transparency and lead to better long-term planning to accommodate distributed generators (box 5.1). It would also require DNSPs to more actively engage with distributed generators. 76 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION The AEMC noted ‘that the proposed content of the DAPR would maintain the core of existing jurisdictional requirements’ (AEMC 2012d, p.30) and the aim is to reduce inconsistency across jurisdictions. In response to the AEMC’s consultation paper, Seed Advisory asserted: Guidance should be provided to ensure that DAPRs appropriately reflect existing and well-based anticipations about future projects in the five years covered by each DAPR. This guidance could include: Requiring the DNSP to provide information on the basis for projections of estimated embedded generating units and outputs… Requiring the DNSP to discuss the methodology on which estimates of capacity in sections of the network have been based… Requiring the DNSP to discuss the methodology on which estimates of system security issues, design fault levels and the requirement for voltage regulation have been based … (Seed Advisory 2011, p.2) Other participants considered that sufficient information already exists and that additional information requirements would impose unnecessary burdens on electricity companies. For example, CitiPower and Powercor claimed: In relation to information and planning, Victorian DNSPs have for more than ten years produced annual planning reports for their distribution assets and transmission connection assets. The Essential Service Commission of Victoria (ESCV) ensured through various amendments to the Electricity Distribution Code over time that the detail provided in these reports is the most detailed in Australia and publicly available from DNSP websites. The current annual planning reports already place a significant work load on the Businesses taking many months of preparation, review and co-ordination with other parties. The Australian Energy Market Commission’s (AEMC) proposed Distribution Network Planning and Expansion Framework further increases the detail required in each report. The Businesses question how much further information can practically and cost effectively be included in these reports. Further, the Businesses would note the Distribution Network Planning and Expansion Framework Rule changes have been subject to detailed consultation over many years and the Businesses would expect the AEMC has reviewed and considered the same issues identified by stakeholders in the current review. (sub. DR 184, p. 6) Similarly, United Energy stated that information provision is required by Victorian regulation: … distributors have, for the past 10 years, published distribution system planning reports which must set out, among other information: (a) the historical and forecast demand from, and capacity of, each zone substation; (b) a description of feasible options for meeting forecast demand including opportunities for embedded generation and demand management; (c) where a preferred option for meeting forecast demand has been identified, a reasonably detailed description of that option, including estimated costs; and (d) the availability of financial contributions from the distributor to embedded generators or customers to reduce forecast demand and defer or avoid augmentation of the distributor’s distribution system. (sub. DR 199, p. 3) NETWORK VALUE 77 Distributed generation of all scales is likely to grow (chapter 2) and pressure to reduce the growth of network costs will increase. This will make it increasingly important that distribution businesses and regulators have good information on the constraints in the network and where network investment is needed and where it could be avoided. Distributed generation projects that address network needs are more likely to be identified and brought forward if regular information is produced in sufficient detail and made available to the market. The red tape risk is that DNSPs are required to produce information they would not otherwise need for their own planning for areas that are not of interest to the proponents of distributed generation. Patricia Boyce from Seed Advisory questioned the value of information currently provided through the distribution code: The information required by the Distribution Code is answering the wrong question from the perspective of embedded generators not primarily interested in demand side management. The requirements of the Victorian and other state Annual Planning Reviews have been strongly influenced over time by Demand Side Management proponents and, as a result, the information focuses on the requirement for network augmentation, the planned timing and costs of that augmentation and the potential for a DSM proponent to receive payments from the network from identifying an alternative solution. The material is focussed on the network’s own requirements, but the underlying customer facing information is not provided and, I would judge, would be difficult to derive without an intimate knowledge of the network. As a customer, you’d want to know: How to map your project’s location to a zone sub-station, so as to identify whether or not, at first glance, there appear to be capacity issues at the zone sub-station that would serve your project; Whether the underlying projections for energy demand at the zone substation already allow for your project proceeding; Whether there’s any fault level headroom in the location you’re planning to build and, if so, how much; For what areas of the network there is effectively a choice of zone substation, giving the project proponent the opportunity to consider alternative connection routes. (Boyce 2012) Additional information will be available to the proponents of distributed generation as a result of the rule change (box 5.1). 78 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION Box 5.1 AEMC’s draft determination: reporting requirements The AEMC’s Draft Determination on the Distribution Network Planning and Expansion Framework proposes the publication of the following information: forecasts for the forward planning period, including at least: – a description of the forecasting methodology used, sources of input information and the assumptions applied; – load forecasts for: - transmission-distribution connection points; - sub-transmission lines; - zone substations, - total capacity; - firm delivery capacity for summer periods and winter periods; - peak load (summer or winter and the number of hours per year that 95 per cent of peak is expected to be reached); - power factor at time of peak load; - load transfer capacities; and - generation capacity of embedded generating units; forecasts of future sub-transmission lines, transmission-distribution connection points and zone substations, including for the latter two asset categories: – location; – future loading level; and – proposed commissioning time (estimate of month and year); forecasts of any factors that may have a material impact on its network, including factors affecting: – fault levels; – voltage levels; – other power system security requirements; and – ageing and potentially unreliable assets. Source: AEMC 2012. There was a strong consensus among the participants that were investing in distributed generation projects that information is important and current levels of information are inadequate. But there was disagreement and differing emphasis on where in the process that information should be provided. Information can be provided up front through distribution system planning reports. Location specific information tailored to specific projects seems best provided during connection negotiations. The need for information can be reduced by setting predetermined standards that allow for automatic connection.1 The AEMC is considering a rule change request which, among other things, would set connection standards. These avenues for information provision are not mutually exclusive. They form a continuum and if more information is available at one stage the need for information at other stages can be reduced. Information provided during connection negotiations and through predetermined standards is discussed in chapter 6. 1 NETWORK VALUE 79 If the framework and other process do not deliver the level of specificity needed the Victorian Government could: Undertake and release specific work on network constraints and augmentation needs Seek a further rule change Require distribution businesses to provide information through state requirements. The Commission therefore considers it prudent to wait until the rule changes are finalised and then assess the extent to which gaps remain in the information provided. While the Commission considers that access to information is a significant barrier to distributed generation it is not in a position, at this stage of the process, to recommend the approach Victoria should take if the results of the rule changes are inadequate. 5.4 Network reinforcement costs A network may need to be reinforced to accommodate the connection of distributed generation. However, given the monopoly position of the network providers, four questions arise: are the quoted costs of reinforcement and augmentation appropriate? how does the proponent know this? who benefits from the reinforcement? how are the costs shared among distributed generation proponents? 5.4.1 Information and transparency A lack of transparency makes it difficult for distributed generators to evaluate the appropriateness or competitiveness of the cost estimates and distributed generators’ share of the costs of network augmentation. Bauknecht and Brunekreeft (2008, p.489) argued that in theory the form of regulation used for distributed generation, 100 per cent cost pass through, gives DNSPs incentives to shift costs of system augmentation, which would happen regardless, onto distributed generation customers. The MCE in 2006 and the AEMC in 2012 identified that this is a problem in practice. Augmentation of existing network assets may provide benefits to other network users, creating difficulties in assigning these costs. Furthermore, DG may provide other benefits to network users, for example, through improved system security. Quantifying and assigning these benefits is difficult. (Ministerial Council on Energy Standing Committee of Officials 2006, p.26) … in relation to augmentations, it is difficult to distinguish the causes of the increased need of augmentation in a meshed network. (AEMC 2012f, p.173) Distributed generators claimed that the information provided by the DNSPs is often insufficient to do due diligence on estimated network costs (Synergy 2010, p. 22). The Energy Efficiency Council argued there are ‘uncertain and often unjustifiable costs for connecting to the grid’ (sub. DR200, p. 11). Additional concerns raised by participants are discussed in chapter 6. 80 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION 5.4.2 Sharing costs Determining how to share reinforcement costs among distributed generation proponents is also problematic. Where a network is constrained, a distributed generator may have to pay the full cost of network reinforcement that would accommodate several distributed generation projects and other demand growth: Requiring non-registered DG [distributed generator] proponents to possibly pay for costs of augmenting the shared network will affect the incentives for DG projects, especially in Victoria. Currently DG projects in that state are only liable for shallow connection costs (i.e., direct connection assets and extensions)… The incremental DG project application that leads to the available fault level headroom/capacity being breached will be asked to meet the full costs of the required shared network augmentation. (AEMC 2012f, p.270) The DNSPs consider this problem is complex: There are no easy ways to remove the fault level barrier problem although long term planning should aim to reduce fault levels to make allowance for future distribution generation. (UE sub 77, p. 5) Where network reinforcement does occur, there is no mechanism to charge subsequent distributed generation projects for their share of the reinforcement. For example, the Energy Efficiency Council argued there are: Inequitable rules about who pays for network upgrades to facilitate cogeneration. Currently, the last cogeneration unit that wants to connect to the grid before an upgrade is required to pay the full cost of the upgrade, despite the fact that other units may connect before or after the upgrade. In contrast, the cost of upgrades to the grid to address rising energy demand are generally smeared across all energy users. (sub. DR200, p. 11) 5.4.3 Who benefits from reinforcement Another aspect of the incremental network reinforcement cost is identifying who benefits and which activities have produced the need for that investment. Growth in demand, for example, also naturally leads to the need for increased fault level capacity. As electricity demand increases due to population growth, more energyintensive appliances and changing land use (such as higher density housing), new substations are required to accommodate increased energy from the transmission network and this requirement increases the fault levels on the distribution network. The AER considers that, in general, the beneficiary of network augmentation to accommodate a distributed generation project is the distributed generator and that these increased costs should not be recovered from customers through network charges (AER 2011c, p.64). The AEMC considers treatment of this issue will have a significant impact on distributed generation: … the effectiveness of [the AER’s proposed connection] arrangements will depend upon how they are applied in practice, including the net benefit test and whether DNSPs offer constraint reduction services, and the transparency of connection cost estimates. (AEMC 2012f, p.174) There is also an issue that if a distributed generator does pay for investment required to connect to the network this may open the way for other distributed generators to connect without incurring any of the costs. NETWORK VALUE 81 However, while distributed generation can impose costs on the network there are potential network benefits including increased reliability, smaller incremental cost and deferred network investment. These benefits depend on highly localised characteristics and timing of distribution network investment. While the AER does recognise where there are ‘demonstrable benefits’ to other users and the negotiation process offers an opportunity to share these benefits, the onus of proof is on the distributed generator proponent (AER 2011c, p.64). In terms of regulatory incentives for distributed generation specifically, even if the overall benefits of a project are positive, additional network costs can represent a disincentive for network operators to connect the distributed generator. Consistent with this view, the AEMC concluded that the incentives for DNSPs to engage in demand side participation, which includes distributed generation, may not be optimal: ‘the current arrangements may fail to provide the right incentives even if it is efficient to do so’ (AEMC 2012f, p.135). The AEMC also concluded DNSPs have strong incentives to concentrate on security concerns, and weak incentives to connect distributed generation (AEMC 2009b, p.28). 5.4.4 The Commission’s view The Commission considers that the lack of guidance and clarity around regulatory mechanisms to recover network reinforcement costs presents a significant barrier to connecting distributed generation to the electricity network in Victoria. There have been attempts to clarify how reinforcement costs will be shared but they have been unsuccessful. For example, CitiPower proposed a levy on distributed generators for the 2011-15 price determination. The cost was to be recovered partly through a charge on embedded generators and partly from all customers (standard control service). In rejecting the proposal the AER argued the service should fully recover fees from distributed generators (alternative control service) and requested CitiPower to provide further information to support the fee (ACIL Tasman 2011b, p.20). AER was of the view that this service should be an alternative control service rather than a standard control service on the basis that the works to maintain fault levels were attributed to specific connections rather than recognising that an efficient solution requires works to be undertaken in the shared network. (ACIL Tasman 2011b, p.20) This process illustrates that there is no agreed framework on how these costs should be allocated and shared. A lack of clarity also means DNSPs are less likely to plan distribution networks to accommodate distributed generation. The sharing of costs could be improved by developing guidance on the conditions and circumstances for allocating the network reinforcement costs across new distributed generation projects and across customers when they result in system wide benefits. These guidelines could inform future price determinations and connection charges. Addressing these barriers through improved guidance and cost recovery mechanisms is a longer term issue and could potentially benefit network efficiency more broadly, not just for distributed generation. Options to address sharing network reinforcement costs include guidance, a distributed generation cost recovery scheme for DNSPs or more efficient incentives for DNSPs to invest overall. There is currently a proposal to amend the National Electricity Rules for connecting embedded generators before the AEMC. The proposed rule change could set broad principles for sharing reinforcement costs and the AER could then develop the necessary guidance material. While this is a national issue the Victorian 82 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION Government could engage with the AER, AEMC, DNSPs and distributed generator proponents to develop a solution for incorporation into Victoria’s next round of DNSP pricing determinations. The pricing determinations are expected in October 2015 providing sufficient time to work on a possible solution or solutions. The AEMC’s consideration of the Proposal to amend the NERs for connecting embedded generators provides an avenue for the Victorian Government to engage the relevant stakeholders. Recommendation 5.1 That to clarify the circumstances and conditions in which network reinforcement costs can be spread across new distributed generators and other users, the Victorian Government: make a submission seeking the development of principles for cost sharing to the Australian Energy Market Commission’s consideration of the Proposal to amend the National Electricity Rules for connecting embedded generators. This submission be prepared by the Department of Primary Industries in consultation with the Australian Energy Regulator (AER), distribution network service providers and distributed generator proponents advocate to the AER for appropriate guidance on cost sharing arrangements for the connection of distributed generators before the next round of network distribution pricing determinations expected in 2015. 5.5 Regulatory incentives Addressing market power concerns and improving information is a necessary but not sufficient step to removing barriers to connection of distributed generation. Distributed generators need to negotiate connection with a monopolist whose incentives for efficient augmentation through distributed generation are further dampened by the regulatory environment. In particular, it is argued that the current regulatory structure favours investment in traditional ‘poles and wires’ delivery systems. Participants raised concerns about the extent to which there are sufficient incentives for distribution businesses to reveal network value and encourage investment in distributed generation even where there are network benefits. For example, the Grattan Institute suggested that: … the current regulatory environment does not always recognise the economic value of such distributed generation… Many of the current regulations do not create the incentives for network operators to recognise the value of distributed generation. Indeed, because many of them earn a guaranteed rate of return on “necessary” augmentation, they have an incentive to discourage distributed generation that would reduce peak demand. (sub. 86, p. 2) ACIL Tasman suggested distribution businesses have limited incentive to innovate except when the payback is short because there is no incentive across revenue periods. … where capital expenditure deferral benefits accrue across regulatory periods … the building blocks approach reduces the benefits to the distributors as the benefits may be returned to customers at the subsequent price review. This could reduce the viability of demand management initiatives to the distributors. (ACIL Tasman 2011b, p.6) NETWORK VALUE 83 ACIL Tasman also noted that ‘a DNSP’s revenue is based on a return on its regulatory asset base so there is an incentive for the DNSPs to invest in network solutions to increase the regulatory asset base’ (ACIL Tasman 2012c, p.48) These views are shared by participants in this inquiry who, based on their experiences, argued that regulatory incentives are making it harder for the proponents of distributed generation. Mike Reeves argued that: The business model for the monopoly distributers is that they are paid for investing in their network rather than ‘deferring network augmentation by encouraging distributed generation’. They also have no incentive to pass on any network value to the DG. (sub. DR130, p. 3) Similarly, Anne-Marie Gibson stated that: … power distributors receive significant incentives to upgrade network infrastructure. The introduction of distributed energy generation, particularly in regional and remote areas of substantial size, will in fact delay or significantly decrease the requirement for some of the infrastructure projects being undertaken. (sub. DR155, p. 1) Currently there is an incentive scheme, the Demand Management Embedded Generation Connection Incentive Scheme (DMEGCIS) (previously DMIS), designed to encourage DNSPs to investigate demand management options, including distributed generation. The scheme, as it applies to distributed generation, has a number of shortcomings: the amount provided to distribution businesses is too small to be effective uncertainty associated with the ex-post assessment of the DMIS payment because DNSPs have no certainty of recouping their costs narrow focus of expenditure (ACIL Tasman 2011b, pp.17, 39). The AER identified that the ‘DMIS is not intended to be the sole or even primary source of cost recovery’ and included $221 million for Demand Side Participation (DSP) in the Queensland DNSPs’ price determinations (AER 2010c). While DSP includes distributed generation, most of the $221m in Queensland was allocated to funding DSP technologies such as air-conditioning and pool filtration direct load control and some pilots of pricing options. This suggests that exploring options for distributed generation is not the primary focus of DNSPs even when financial incentives are offered. The AEMC’s Power of Choice Review’s directions paper noted that current regulatory arrangements could create: … a bias towards capital expenditure in favour of operating expenditure, both in terms of the potential to make profit and certainty about cost recovery. Therefore, other factors being equal, operating expenditure on DSP [demand side participation] may be at a disadvantage compared to capital expenditure. (AEMC 2012f, p.138) The Power of Choice Review is considering a number of these issues in a broader context. Two specific issues highlighted in this review were: 84 How to recover the costs of the existing network — there are different views on how these costs interact with distributed generation. Some proponents of distributed generation argue that they do not use the network and therefore should not pay. Distribution businesses argue that costs are not avoided by distributed generators POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION as the network is still required as a form of insurance. Distributed generators can access electricity if their systems are unavailable and the system still has sufficient capacity if distributed generation is not available at a time of peak demand. In addition, the way network charges are currently levied means that as the amount of distributed generation increases, the network costs are shared across a deceasing volume of electricity sales. Finding mechanisms that will allow distributed generators to be paid for network savings. In relation to the first point, the increasing burden of network costs being shared across less electricity will need to be addressed in the longer run but the problem is not unique to distributed generation as it can also result from falling demand for other reasons such as energy saving (chapter 4). These issues should be considered in more general regulatory and price reforms. The Commission’s views on recovering network value is discussed in the following section. 5.6 Recovering network value The Commission considers that recovering the network value and paying it to the proponents of distributed generation is important to ensure there are incentives for the efficient incorporation of distributed generation into Victoria’s electricity system. However, recovering this value is not easy. Ceramic Fuel Cells noted that they accept that it is hard to produce a single specific figure for the network value’ (sub. DR135, p. 5). Advice provided to the Commission by ACIL Tasman suggested that the network value of distributed generation is in the nature of a local specific capital value that is unrelated to the quantity of energy generated, and is not easily incorporated into the FiT payment (ACIL Tasman 2012). The Commission’s view is that the network value is appropriately dealt with outside of the FiT payment. Possible options for addressing this network value, include: Recognising that there is a value but do nothing because of the difficulty and possible transactions costs involved in trying to calculate it. These costs arise because the network value will vary by location, time of day, type of generator and the extent to which the DNSP can rely on the generator producing electricity when it is needed. Improving regulatory structures to provide incentives to reveal the network value — proposed changes to the regulations governing incentive structures for distribution businesses, simpler (and less costly) connection processes, and better information about local bottlenecks may make the value more accessible to distributed generators. The value could be estimated and spread across all distributed generators and reflected in FiT payments, but as noted earlier this is not the Commission’s preferred approach because the network value is not based on output. However, none of these options is particularly effective in identifying the network value and ensuring it is paid to the distributed generation proponent. The Commission considers that another option is to use the AER’s price reset process to consider the value of any network benefits from distributed generation and to then require distribution companies to make payments based on this value. NETWORK VALUE 85 The payments could be made available to large distributed generators, retailers (to pass on to relevant distributed generators), or aggregators who may be responsible for aggregating a number of distributed generators to have an appreciable effect on the network. Distribution businesses are already required to provide the AER with estimates of the need for and cost of network investment as part of the price reset process. Those requirements could be modified to include providing estimates of the network costs and benefits of distributed generation (or demand side responses more broadly). This information would be the basis for identifying the areas of the network where the network benefits of distributed generation would be positive and setting up how payments would be made to proponents bringing forward proposals that would realise those benefits. Recommendation 5.2 That the Victorian Government, through the Department of Primary Industries investigate whether, and how, the Australian Energy Regulator’s price reset process can be used to: Identify the network value of distributed generation Require distribution businesses to make available payments based on that value. Subject to the investigation producing a practical solution, and in the absence of any other relevant developments, the Victorian Government prepare and submit a rule change proposal so it could be considered by the AEMC prior to the next price reset process in 2015. 86 POWER FROM THE PEOPLE: INQUIRY INTO DISTRIBUTED GENERATION