Chapter 3 Comparative Advantage and Factor Proportions Link to syllabus Adam Smith: The Wealth of Nations 1776 In a free market society, individuals, acting out of their own self interest, will be guided, as if by an invisible hand, to make socially beneficial economic decisions. Chapter 3. Comparative advantage –why countries can gain from trade, and who will trade which product. Questionable example page 36. Book’s example. My example. PPcurve. Opportunity cost. Demonstration of who has comp. adv. Demonstration of gains from trade. Adam Smith: Individuals acting out of their own self interest, will be guided, as if by an invisible hand, to make socially beneficial economic decisions. Also: benefits of free trade, criticism of mercantilism. David Ricardo. 1772-1823 Born in London; father was a stockbroker. In addition to major contributions in Economics, he was a member of the British Parliament, a businessman and financier. Said to have become interested in economics at the age of 27, after reading Adam Smith, while on vacation. Was friends with James Mill, Bentham, Malthus, and other classical economists. Also, benefits of free trade, and criticism of mercantilism. David Ricardo. 1772-1823 Born in London; father was a strockbroker. In addition to major contributions in Economics, was a member of the British Parliament, a businessman and financier. Said to have become interested in econ at the age of 27, after reading Adam Smith, while on vacation. Was friends with James Mill, Bentham, Malthus, and other classical economists. Smith talked about benefits of trade, using argument of absolute advantage. Argued against mercantilism. Mercantilism: trade is source of growth (through exports). Imports were to be minimized. Emphasis on generating employment. Accumulate gold (balance of payments surplus). Book states that mercantilists viewed trade is a zero sum game. Ricardo: labor theory of value. Comp. advantage. Book’s example of Ricardian model (p. 37): 2 Labor hours to make one unit of Cloth Wheat U.S. R.o.W. 4.0 1.0 2.0 1.5 Labor Productivity (units of cloth per hour): [inverse of labor hours US R.o.w. Cloth/labor .25 1.0 Wheat/labor 0.5 0.66 Ricardian example of comparative advantage. Page 37 Pre- trade Prices, in Ricardo’s Example p. 38 Ricardian model of comparative advantage. Data on Page 36. Typos for R.o.W. Also, question of notation on p. 38 R.o.W. has absolute advantage in both goods. Maybe US would fear trade in either good. Let’s look at comparative advantage. Where are goods relatively cheaper? Calculation of opportunity costs: In U.S., one unit of cloth requires 4 units of labor, which could have produced 2 units of wheat. So the opportunity cost of cloth in terms of wheat in the US is 2. In R.o.W., one unit of cloth requires 1 unit of labor which could have produced 2/3 unit of wheat. So cloth’s opportunity cost in terms of wheat in R.o.W. is 2/3. It is cheaper there. Pre-trade Relative prices: U.S. R.o.W. Pcl/Pwh 2bu/yard 0.67 bu/yard 3 Other relative prices are the inverses: Pwh/Pcl .5 1.5 Benefits from trade. Have to construct the PPcurve. Figure 3.1 page 39 Gains from trade: constant cost case My example. Labor Input: Figure 3.1 page 41. PPC drawn with 100 units of labor in each country. Labor hours to make one unit of: U.S. R.o.W. Cloth 4.0 1.0 Wheat 2.0 1.5 Country A B gr 0.5 0.33 ma 1 0.25 Opportunity cost of grain in terms of machines In A: 1 unit of grain needs 0.5 units of labor, which could have produced 0.5 units of machines In B: 1 unit of grain needs 0.33 units of labor, which could have produced 0.33/0.25 =1.33 units of ma. So grain is cheaper in A. Absolute Advantage Does Matter p. 43 Absolute Advantage Does Matter p. 41 Handouts Description of argument of comparative advantage Numerical example of comparative advantage Handouts on comparative advantage What determines comparative advantage? Demand or supply If supply, wages, productivity (technology), existence of raw materials. 4 Let awh be the amount of labor used for a unit of wheat in the US, and acl the amount of labor for a unit of cloth. Let Pwh and Pcl be the prices of the two goods, and their levels of output or consumption be Wh and Cl. First, what is the slope of the PPC in the US? The PPC is also the budget line for the US, and the formula for the budget line is Pwh · Wh + Pcl · Cl = Budget (some level). With prices fixed, a movement along the PPC or the budget line involves a change in Wh (ΔWh) counterbalanced by a change in Cl (ΔCl). So we have: Pwh · ΔWh + Pcl · ΔCl = ΔBudget = 0. The PPC as drawn in our text has wheat on the vertical axis, so its slope is ΔWh / ΔCl , which from this formula is - Pcl / Pwh . Note that if labor is the only cost (Ricardian world), we can express the prices in terms of the labor inputs. If labor is paid ‘wage’, and it takes awh of labor to produce one unit of wheat, then Pwh = awh· wage. Similarly Pcl = acl ·wage. So the ratio Pcl / Pwh = acl / awh . In other words, the ratio of prices is the direct ratio of labor inputs. To determine which country has the lower pre-trade prices, just look at the ratio of the labor inputs. The common sense interpretation of this is that the (relative) price of a good will be lower if that good uses (relatively) less labor. The above derivation hints of calculus. A simpler story is simply the following. For a given level of the labor force L, the vertical height of the PPC is L/ awh , and the horizontal distance is L/ acl . So the ratio of height to length is (L/ awh )/ (L/ acl), or acl / awh . Chapter 3 p. 45. Question #8