International Trade Classical Trade Theory and Comparative Advantage References Textbooks Appleyard, D., Field, A. and Cobb, S. (2005) International Economics, McGrawHill Ch. 3 Husted, S. and Melvin, M. (2007), International Economics, Addison-Wesley Ch. 3 Krugman, P. and Obstfeld, M. (2009) International Economics: Theory and Policy Addison-Wesley Ch. 2 & 3 Articles Balassa, B. (1963) "An Empirical Demonstration of Classical Comparative Cost Theory“, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 45(3), pp. 231-38. Helpman, E. (1999), “The Structure of Foreign Trade”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(2), pp.121-144. Krugman, P. (1997), “Ricardo’s difficult idea”, http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/ricardo.htm Importance of International Trade World GDP is over 7 times what it was in 1950 but volume of world exports is now over 27 times what is was in 19501 MASSIVE INCREASE IN WORLD TRADE But why? Reduction in trade barriers is certainly an important factor 1Husted and Melvin, 2007 EU trade In 2007 the EU was the top exporter and importer of both goods and services in the world (International Trade Statistics, WTO) So who does the EU trade with? EU(27) exports by destination in 2007 United States Switzerland Russian Federation China Turkey Source: International Trade Statistics, WTO EU(27) imports by origin in 2007 China United States Russian Federation Switzerland Japan Source: International Trade Statistics, WTO What do we trade? In 2007 83% of the EU exports were manufactures and 61% of imports were manufactures (International Trade Statistics, WTO) World trade is similarly dominated by manufactures (Krugman and Obstfeld, 2009) Developing countries are also increasingly export manufactures and less agricultural products (Krugman and Obstfeld, 2009) It is very important to understand patterns of trade, the terms of trade as well as the gains from trade. This will then allow us to assess the impact of various trade policies. Rationale for International Trade Self sufficiency means no specialisation therefore low productivity Exchange allows specialisation in what we are good at producing This applies to both internal and external trade Opportunity cost of self sufficiency is the loss of foregone output in high efficiency areas Specialisation with trade allows overall production to increase Absolute Advantage If Britain can produce cloth more efficiently than America and… America can produce food more efficiently than Britain…. Both countries can gain from trade if they specialise in what they do best On this basis Adam Smith advocated free trade (allows division of labour) Absolute Advantage Potential Output per Unit of Labour No Trade Cloth Food With Trade Cloth Food Britain 30 45 60 0 America 15 60 0 120 World 45 105 60 120 Britain will export cloth and America will export food Absolute Advantage If Britain exchanges 30 units of cloth for 60 units of food….. Both countries could have 30 units of cloth and 60 units of food Britain gains 15 units of food and America gains 15 units of cloth But what if America is more efficient than Britain at producing both food and cloth? Ricardian Model David Ricardo was an English political economist in the early 1800s who introduced the concept of comparative advantage. Ricardo demonstrated that trade can be beneficial with only comparative advantage A country will export a good in which their productivity is relatively high. Assumptions of the Ricardian Model One factor of production – labour Two goods Two countries Labour is immobile internationally but mobile nationally (=> wages are equalised nationally but not internationally) Zero transport costs Free trade Comparative Advantage Potential Output per Unit of Labour Britain No Trade Cloth Food 30 45 With Trade Cloth Food 60 0 America 40 80 15 130 World 70 125 75 130 Comparative Advantage America’s superiority in cloth is 40/30 = 33% whereas superiority in food is 80/45 = 78% => America will still export food Notice if the ratios were the same there would be no basis for trade Hence Britain has a comparative advantage in cloth production => Britain will still export cloth There are also still gains from trade since a country’s consumption possibilities are greater But do both countries always gain from trade? It depends on: – – what your production would have been with no trade taking place the units labour requirements for each of the goods. What is the impact on trade on prices (terms of trade)? Pre-trade relative prices are equal to relative unit labour requirements If both countries completely specialise their production the traded price of each good ends up somewhere between the two countries pre-trade prices. As long as prices rise when countries begin trading then there are gains from trade, since the real wage rises and everybody in a country gets the same wage. Ricardian Model The Ricardian model is simple but nevertheless very useful in explaining trade flows. This model allows us to reject a whole series of common claims… ‘A country will only benefit from free trade if strong enough to stand up to foreign competition’ ‘Competition from foreign countries with low wages is damaging’ But there are some serious limitations of the Ricardian model… Assumes a high degree of specialisation Assumes constant return to scale Does not discuss the effects of trade on income distribution within countries Does not take into account the different resources held by different countries Supportive Empirical Evidence Source: Balassa (1963) Summary We have examined the simple Ricardian model that shows countries export goods in which their productivity is relatively high, in other words in which they have a comparative advantage. This model implies gains from trade There are gains no matter whether the trade is ‘competitive’ or ‘fair’ Studies such as that by Balassa (1963) have confirmed the predictions of the Ricardian model empirically.