16.g. The Economics of Discrimination Earnings often differ between workers because some are more productive than others, or because some workers have invested in more education than others or have had more on the job training. Some workers have had the fortune of being employed by expanding firms, whereas others have had the misfortune of the opposite. There still remains though the problem of discrimination in the job market. Labor-market discrimination by gender, race, color, religion, and national origin has been made illegal in the United States since the Civil Rights Act of 1964, though still prevails. Such discrimination occurs when individual’s job opportunities are not solely based on the individual’s productivity but also are dependent on such differences listed above. As a result of the difficulty that arises when measuring discrimination, as well as differences in the method to which it should actually be estimated, there remains an obvious problem. Many economists though have come up with ways to measure such discrimination and theories of the repercussions of such actions. One theory is presented by Gary Becker who claims that the white male has a “taste for discrimination” Claiming that white men have a preference for associating with other white men, rather than with people of a different race or gender. He claims that theses men are willing to pay a higher price for their own comfort or self assurance. This theory does not explain why these tastes arise or persist but rather asserts that they are determined by purely non-economical considerations. Becker then proceeds to show how these tastes for discrimination affect economic decisions. If there is no discrimination present, and all workers are equally productive in a competitive market than the employer will hire a worker only if the workers marginal revenue product (MRP) is equal to or greater than the worker’s wage. This said, the employer will hire until MRP=W. If there is no discrimination against men, MRPm = Wm. If this employer then discriminates against women, he will only hire a woman if the firm can make an extra profit to compensate for the employer’s discriminatory tastes. Following this, the employer will hire when MRP f = Wf + df (which includes df that the employer adds to compensate for his tastes). Since MRPf = MRPm we see that Wm – Wf = df. This means that if the employer hires a female woman it will have to be at a lower wage than the man’s. The employer’s premium for hiring women is df (the difference in wage rates by sex). In this case the employer will attempt to maximize his profits and either choose not to hire any women at all, or pay them a lower wage. There arises a problem in this theory when one considers that not all markets are discriminatory and also all employers are not white men. Though one might find Becker’s theory comprehensible, it is also useful to examine other explanations and theories. An alternate theory of discrimination assumes that there are both discriminators and nondiscriminators in the market. The final result of this assumption is that the wage rates of men and women are equal. An example can be seen in the following graphs: Market A - Discriminators S' S"=S 12= W 10=W D Labor (total) Market B - Nondiscriminators Wage S"=S 10=W S' 8=W D" Labor (total) In Market A when employers begin to discriminate against women, the initial effect shifts the supply curve to the left (S’) (in the Market A graph). After this occurs a simultaneous rightward shift occurs in the supply of the Market B graph (as the women who were discharged in market A migrate to Market B without discrimination). This also creates incentives for the men in market B to shift into market A (which then reverses the initial leftward shift in the supply of the Market A graph. Again, this theory asserts that the wage for both women and men should be equal in the presence of both discriminatory markets and nondiscriminatory. This theory then would imply that the reasons for the differences in the wages of men and women are due to other factors. One possible explanation is that married women more often tend to have the responsibility of household chores and duty, hence they have less time to work (this is supported by studies that show married women make less on average than single women. This is just one possible explanation though there are many that exist. So, when trying to explain the differences in wage rates one must attempt to compare groups who are equally capable, motivated and experienced. Factors such as education, region and hours of work also have an obvious effect on wages and make it equally as difficult to assert when and if discrimination is a factor in the job market. The topic itself is controversial and many theories and applications apply.