The Wealth Effect and Nominal Interest Rates Avner Bar-Ilan* December 2000 Abstract This short paper derives the IS curve with a wealth effect. The existence of nominal bonds allows the central bank to use the nominal interest rate in order to affect wealth, consumption and aggregate demand. This might provide an explanation to the unresolved issue of interest rate smoothing. * Department of economics, University of Haifa, 31905 Haifa, Israel. E-mail: bar-ilan@econ.haifa.ac.il. 1. Introduction and Summary The goal of this short paper is to use an explicit optimization in order to derive the consumption function and the IS relationship with a wealth effect. This derivation is then used as a possible explanation of the puzzle of interest rate smoothing. Another natural application is a simplification of macroeconomic models suggested recently as models appropriate to be used in classrooms. We start by extending next section the setup of McCallum and Nelson (1999) by introducing nominal bonds and overlapping generations. By changing the nominal interest rate, the central bank changes bond prices. The valuation of bonds affects public’s wealth and therefore its consumption. The resulting IS curve demonstrates that, in addition to the standard depressing effect that real interest rate has on output, output is negatively related to the nominal interest rate as well. Its ability to affect wealth allows the central bank to use another channel of monetary policy. This additional leverage implies that the movements in interest rates required to achieve output and inflation targets are lower than without the wealth effect. This might explain why interest rate movements are typically smaller than theory predicts, the oftendiscussed issue of interest rate smoothing. We demonstrate this point in section 3 by using the widely used model of Clarida et al. (1999); the variance of nominal interest rate is negatively related to the coefficient of this interest rate in the IS equation. We suggest in section 4 that macroeconomic models presented in principles and intermediate macro courses might include nominal instead of real interest rates. Basic features of the models of Romer (2000) and Taylor (2000) are preserved with this change. However, this frees the model from the assumption that the central bank is able to control the real interest rate, an assumption that makes the model Keynesian. The ability of the monetary policy to manipulate consumption in the short run using the nominal interest rate, plus the use of the nominal rate as the instrument of monetary policy, is all what is needed to present the aggregate demand. The model presented here captures, in a very straightforward fashion, some main features of the so-called stock market channel of monetary policy. That is, how the impact that central banks have on valuation of financial assets could change aggregate 1 demand. For simplicity we use just bonds and ignore equities.1 Another simplifying assumption used here is that all bonds are consols, perpetual bonds. It is true that central banks control short-term interest rates much better than long rates. However, enriching the range of financial assets will not change the qualitative results.2 2. Derivation of the IS Equation We start by deriving the IS equation with a wealth effect. The derivation is based on explicit optimization by economic agents, as in Fane (1985) and McCallum and Nelson (1999). The model is an overlapping generations model where the economy consists of many individuals who live for two periods. Each individual works, consumes, and saves in the first period and consumes her saving in the second period. Unlike the citizens, the government lives forever while spending, taxing, and borrowing using perpetual bonds (consols). Each bond pays $1 at the start of every period, indefinitely. Allowing the government to issue additional financial assets like short-term bonds and money will not make any substantial difference. The timing is as follows. During period t the young inelastically supplies one unit of labor, consumes, and makes contingent consumption plan for period t+1. To finance future consumption she purchases bonds and physical capital. Consumption of the old is thus financed out of selling bonds and physical capital to the young and out of profit. The government might then intervene in the financial market and change the nominal interest rate and bond prices. This could potentially make actual consumption while old different from planned consumption. The individual maximizes lifetime utility u (cty ) u (cto1 ) where (0,1) is the discount factor, ct is period-t consumption, and the superscript y (o) denotes young (old). The budget constraint is Poterba (2000) surveys recent estimates of the response of consumption to wealth changes. He quotes studies that show that consumption, especially in the long run, responds much stronger to innovations in nonequity wealth than to equity wealth. He also shows that as of December 1999 U.S. financial assets excluding equities are 60% higher than the market value of equities. 2 Romer and Romer (2000) note that long-term interest rates typically rise in response to tighter monetary policy. They attribute this to information advantage of the Fed. See also Campbell (1995) on this point. 1 2 (1) cty cto1 B B 1 k t 1 t wt nt (1 rt ) 1 f (nt 1 , k t 1 ) txt 1 wt 1nt 1 (1 )k t 1 t (1 ). 1 rt Pt I t Pt 1 I t 1 In equation (1) rt denotes the one-period real interest rate between period t and period t+1 while I t is the long-term nominal interest rate at period t. Bt is period-t quantity of bonds whose nominal price at that period, right after the coupon payment, is 1/ I t . Nominal value of the bond one period later is 1+1/ I t 1 . Pt is the price level at t. We denote as k t the capital stock at the start of period t. The depreciation rate is per period, and the real price of capital is assumed to be constant equal to one. The period-t real wage and employment are wt and nt , respectively. The production function is f (,) and txt denotes period-t lump sum tax on the old. Imposing the lump sum tax on the young will not make any difference. All quantities are expressed in per-capita terms. The population growth, for simplicity, is fixed at level zero. Taking derivatives of the Lagrangean with respect to ct , ct 1 , nt 1 , Bt , and k t 1 yields, after some simplification, the following first-order conditions, (2) u ' (cty ) (1 rt )u ' (cto1 ), (3) f1 (nt 1 , k t 1 ) wt 1 , (4) (1 rt )(1 t ) (5) It It , I t 1 f 2 (nt 1 , k t 1 ) rt . In equations (2)-(5) f i denotes partial derivative with respect to the ith argument while t is the inflation rate between periods t and t+1. Equations (2), (3), and (5) are 3 standard. Equation (4) determines the short-term real interest rate in response to paths of long-term nominal rates and inflation.3 The terminal condition of no-bankruptcy is (6) cto1 f (nt 1 , k t 1 ) txt 1 wt 1 nt 1 (1 )k t 1 Bt 1 (1 ) prt 1 as t 1 . Pt 1 I t 1 The last term of the middle equation in (6) defines the value of financial assets and is denoted by as. The sum of the other terms in (6) represents return on capital and denoted by pr for ‘profit’. Equations (1)-(6) determine cty , cto1 , Bt , k t 1 , nt 1 , and rt in response to paths for I t , txt , wt , t , and Pt . The last three variables are determined by the following equations, B Bt 1 Bt 1 , txt t Pt I P t t (7) g t (8) nt 1, (9) t Pt 1 Pt . Pt In equation (7), the government budget constraint, g t , is (per capita) government spending and the term Bt 1 / Pt denotes real coupon payment in period t. The system (1)(9) determines cty , cto1 , Bt , k t 1 , nt 1 , rt , wt , t , and Pt in response to monetary and fiscal paths for I t , g t , and txt . 3 Since 1 rt (1 it ) /(1 t ) , the one-period nominal rate, it , is it I t I t I t 1 . It 4 We follow McCallum and Nelson (1999) in converting a system similar to (1)-(9) into an IS equation. The first step is observing that combining equations (1), (6), and (7) yields the following equation (10) y t cto cty k t 1 (1 )k t g t cto cty in t g t . Equation (10) is the national income identity. Output is yt f (nt , k t ) and in t is period-t investment. Log-linearization of equation (10) gives, (11) log y t d1 log cty d 2 log cto d 3 log in t d 4 log g t , where the coefficients d i , 0 d i 1 , are the steady-state output shares of the corresponding components of output. Assume next, still as in McCallum and Nelson (1999), that the utility function is of isoelastic form, u (c) (1 / )c , ( 1) / , 0 . Substitute this functional form in equation (2) yields, (12) log cty log cto1 log( 1 rt ) log . Interpreting equation (13) as a choice of period-t consumption in response to rt and expectations of future consumption and approximating log( 1 rt ) by rt gives, (13) log cty b0' b1' rr Et log cto1 , b1' 0 . We denote expectations as of time t by Et. Log-linearization of equation (6) gives, (14) log cto d 5 log prt d 6 log ast . In (12) d 5 and d 6 are steady-state ratios of profit and assets to consumption of the old, 0 d 5 , d 6 1 . Denoting the steady-state ratio of profit to output by we obtain 5 (15) log cto d 5 log y t d 6 log( 1 1 ) d 6 log Pt d 7 . It The parameter d7 is defined as a function of constant and predetermined variables as d 7 log d 6 log Bt 1 . We next assume Cobb-Douglas production function where we denote by ,0 1 , the power of the capital stock. Equation (5) yields now (16) log k t d 8 d 9 log( rt ) , where d 9 1 /(1 ) 0 . In order to simplify, and without loss of generality, we assume full depreciation within a period. Inserting 1 in (16) gives (17) log int d 8d 9 rt . Substitution of equations (13), (15), and (17) into (11) gives (18) log y t b0 b1 rt b2 log( 1 1 1 ) b3 log Pt b4 log g t b5 Et log y t 1 b6 Et log( 1 ) b7 Et log Pt 1 It I t 1 This is our IS curve. The coefficients bi are functions of the various d i and bi' and satisfy bi >0, i 1,...,7. The negative effect of the real interest rate rt comes from intertemporal substitution in consumption and from investment. Government expenditures have the usual expansionary effect. The negative coefficient of the price level Pt and its expected level is the real balances effect coming here from nominal bonds instead of money, the standard source of this effect. The positive relationship between expected future output and current output is the focus of McCallum and Nelson (1999). Our focus here is the negative impact of nominal interest rates on output. This is the wealth effect. Higher nominal rates devalue nominal bonds and depress consumption. This is obvious in equation (6) where consumption of the old is financed 6 in part by bonds purchased one period earlier and whose price fluctuates with the nominal rate.4 Future rates have similar effect via expected capital losses. 3. Interest Rate Smoothing Clarida et al. (1999) write on p. 1688 that “understanding why central banks choose a smooth path of interest rates than theory would predict is an important unresolved issue.” A few possible explanations have been offered to this observation, referred to as “interest rate smoothing.” Goodfriend (1991) and Campbell (1995) suggest that volatility of interest rates might disrupt financial markets and risk financial institutions. Clarida et al. (1999) discuss the role of model uncertainty in introducing some interest rate smoothing. Williams (1997) and Rudebusch and Svensson (1999) constrain the volatility of interest rates while estimating optimal monetary rules. Rotemberg and Woodford (1997) discuss the related issue of lagged dependence in the interest rate. We suggest here a simple mechanism that reduces interest rate volatility. The ability of central bank to affect aggregate demand using the nominal interest rate, via the wealth effect, implies that the interest rate change needed to achieve a certain goal is smaller than the standard change when only real interest rate can affect real variables. It is easy to demonstrate this point. Consider a straightforward extension of the model of Clarida et al. (1999), the model used in many recent monetary policy studies (Taylor 1999, 2000). The economy is described by an IS-type equation and a Phillips curve. The former takes the following form, (19) xt b1rt b2 I t Et xt 1 g t . The variable xt is the deviation of (log) output yt from the (log of) natural output level. Equation (19), a simplified version of equation (18), is identical to the IS equation in Clarida et al. (1999), except for the additional term b2 I t here that captures the wealth effect. The real rate rt is rt I t Et t 1 , where t 1 is the inflation rate. The fiscal policy term is taken as random, satisfying an AR(1) process, 4 Introducing a bequest motive will weaken this effect. 7 (20) g t g t 1 g t* . The disturbance term g t* is i.i.d. with zero mean and variance g2 and is weakly bounded between 0 and 1. The Phillips curve that relates inflation to output gap is given by (21) t xt Et t 1 ut . The random term u t satisfies (22) u t u t 1 u t* , when u t* is i.i.d. with zero mean and variance u2 and the AR(1) term satisfies 0 1. The model is closed with the objective function of the central bank. The bank chooses a path for nominal interest rates in order to minimize a loss function given by 1 (23) Min Et i [xt2i t2i ] . 2 i 0 The parameter denotes the weight on output variability relative to price variability, and is the discount factor. When the central bank cannot commit to certain future actions we obtain the socalled discretionary solution. As Clarida et al. (1999) demonstrate, the optimal output and inflation levels are given by (23) xt (1 ) 2 ut , 8 (24) t ut . (1 ) 2 Plugging the values of xt and t from (23) and (24) into the IS equation (19) yields the solution for the nominal interest rate, b1 (1 ) 1 Et t 1 (25) I t gt , b1 b2 b1 b2 (b1 b2 ) where the expected inflation is (26) Et t 1 ut . (1 ) 2 The variance of I t ,Var ( I t ) , is given by b1 (1 ) (27) Var ( I t ) b1 b2 (b1 b2 ) 2 g2 u2 1 2 . 2 (1 ) 1 (b1 b2 ) 1 2 The essence of the wealth effect on interest rate smoothing is dVar ( I t ) / db2 0 . The extra leverage that the central bank has on the economy allows it to adjust the nominal interest rate less in face of external shocks and still achieve the same output and inflation levels. Another way of observing this point is by noting that the coefficient of Et t 1 in equation (25) is not necessarily larger than 1 when b2 0 . Result 3 of Clarida et al. (1999) states that this coefficient is larger than 1; that is, the real interest rate must optimally rise in response to an increase in expected inflation in order to contract demand and stabilize the economy. But this is not necessarily true unless b2 0 . The presence of the wealth effect allows some contraction to come from hike of the nominal rate such that the real rate does not necessarily rise as well. The issue of whether it is optimal to adjust real rates up or down when inflation accelerates is thus an empirical issue, depending on the characteristics of the economy; in particular, on the ratio b2 / b1 that measures the effectiveness of the wealth effect relative to the standard channel of real interest rate on aggregate demand. 9 4. A Classroom Model Romer (2000) and Taylor (2000) have recently suggested to adjust the way macroeconomics is taught at the principles and intermediate levels to recent developments. Their model is a simple version of the model of Clarida et al. (1999) presented in the previous section. It is a system of three equations in three unknowns: output, inflation and the real interest rate. The first equation is an IS curve that negatively relates output to the real rate. A second equation is a positive relationship between the real interest rate and inflation. It aims at capturing the way monetary policy is conducted, and replaces the LM equation in simple models. These two equations are combined to give an inverse relationship between output and inflation that is termed aggregate demand. This aggregate demand is combined with a Phillips curve equation that relates inflation to output in order to solve for these two variables. Determination of the interest rate completes the solution. I suggest replacing the real interest rate by the nominal one in the basic model suggested above for teaching macroeconomics at the principles or even intermediate levels. This has most of the advantages discussed by Romer (2000), and more. As Romer notes, replacing the LM equation, with its dependence on the nominal interest rate, with the assumption that the central bank directly controls the real rate, makes the model more coherent; both the IS and the monetary policy equation include the same type of interest rate. Using my suggestion this coherence is achieved via the wealth effect of the nominal rate on consumption and the IS curve. As Romer (2000) emphasizes, the assumption that the central bank is able to follow a real interest rate rule is based on price rigidity and therefore makes the model Keynesian. It is also hard to explain this assumption to students; Romer suggests to explain it in stages, starting with complete price rigidity and proceeding by relaxing this assumption. The ability of the central bank to affect the nominal interest rate, on the other hand, is not constrained by any assumption. There is a unanimous agreement on the ability of central banks to control short-term nominal interest rates. Moreover, as discussed in the previous section, assuming that the real rate is controlled requires that the central bank adjust the nominal rate more than one-for-one with inflation. This is a 10 strong quantitative assumption that does not always hold in reality5 and not easily understood by beginners. All this complication is avoided by assuming that the nominal interest rate is the monetary policy instrument. A more advanced model should include both the nominal and the real interest rates affecting aggregate demand. Simplifying by omitting the real rate is not a big loss, at least at the principles level, in terms of economic intuition and dynamics of the model. The aggregate demand relationship of output and inflation is qualitatively identical whether the model includes nominal or real interest rates. On the other hand, the mechanism by which higher nominal interest rates act to reduce consumption is easily grasped even by beginners. Generally speaking, the wealth channel of monetary policy transmission mechanism is widely discussed in the popular press. The students are aware of the ability of the central bank to determine nominal interest rates and the prompt effect that interest rate changes have on both the debt and equities markets. The last link, that between wealth and consumption, is also easy to understand. References Campbell, John Y., “Some Lessons from the Yield Curve,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, Summer 1995, 129-152. Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler, “The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspectives,” Journal of Economic Literature 37, December 1999, 1661-1707. ___, “Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, February 2000, 147-180. Fane, George, “A Derivation of the IS-LM Model from Explicit Optimizing Behavior,” Journal of Macroeconomics 7, Fall 1985, 493-508. Goodfriend, Marvin S., “Interest Rates and the Conduct of Monetary Policy,” CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy 34, 1991, 7-37. 5 See Goodfriend (1993) and Clarida et al. (2000). 11 ___, “Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem: 1979-1992,” Federal Reserve of Richmond Economic Quarterly 79, Winter 1993, 1-24. McCallum, Bennett T. and Edward Nelson, “An Optimizing IS-LM Specification for Monetary Policy and Business Cycle Analysis,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 31, August 1999, 296-316. Poterba, James M., “Stock Market wealth and Consumption,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, Spring 2000, 99-118. Romer, Christina D. and David H. Romer, “Federal Reserve Information and the Behavior of Interest Rates,” American Economic Review 90, June 2000, 429-457. Romer, David, “Keynesian Macroeconomics without the LM Curve,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, Spring 2000, 149-169. Rotemberg, Julio and Michael Woodford, “An Optimization-Based Econometric Framework for the Evaluation of Monetary Policy,” NBER Macroecomics Annual, 1997, Ben Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg, eds. Rudedusch, Glenn D., and Lars Svensson, “Monetary Policy Rules and Inflation Targeting,” in Monetary Policy Rules, John Taylor, ed., 1999. Taylor, John B., ed., Monetary Policy Rules, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1999. ___, “Teaching Modern Macroeconomics at the Principles Level,” American Economic Review 90, May 2000, 90-94. Williams, John C., “Simple Rules for Monetary Policy,” mimeo, Federal Reserve Board, 1997. 12 13