AAE 637 Midterm Answer Key 1. (a) 2 Q 2 PEL 2571.74 PEL EL Q PEL 0.541 2571.74 1.0945 PEL Q 1271.2 Given that only β2 is only used in the calculation of the above elasticity, we only need to use its variance in the calculation of the variance of this elasticity. As such, we have: Std.Err. ηEL 1 PEL Q Std.Err. β 2 1 164.87 0.2397 (0.541)(1271.2) With the null hypothesis that the own price elasticity is -1.0, we have t 1.0945 1 0.3942 0.2397 (b) There is no question that there is heteroscedasticity associated with the use of annual town electricity consumption as the dependent variable. The reason for this is that by definition, for the ith town we have we have Qi = 1 Ni qij . Hence even if the Ni j=1 electricity consumption of individual households in all towns has a common variance V(qij)=σ2, the variance for Qi is nevertheless: 1 Ni 1 Ni 1 σ2 2 given that there is zero V Qi V qij 2 V qij 2 Nσ Ni Ni Ni j=1 Ni j=1 covariance of the error terms by assumption. Note that the variance is different across town given that the number of households per town is expected to be different. This results implies that our CRM parameter estimates are unbiased but the standard errors are incorrectly calculated. This also carries over to the estimates of the variance of the standard error of the above elasticity estimate (c) Given the above error structure we need to use a GLS estimator to obtain parameter estimates. The weighted least squares regression would look like this: -1 Qi Ni 0 Ni 1 Ni INCi 2 Ni PElec,i 3 Ni PNG,i 4 Ni E_EQPi + That is we would have N1 0 N2 0 P 0 1 0 N 1 1 0 N2 0 i* Ni εi ~ 0,σ2 N1 0 0 -1 where P P= 0 N 42 1 0 0 N 1 1 0 2 0 N2 and σ 1 0 N 42 0 0 0 or N 42 0 0 1 N 42 2. (a) We know that by definition that: R 2 =1 TSS 0 N2 σ 2 T-1 σ 2u TSS= u 2 TSS T-1 1-R 11.799(99) 3583.132 . 0.326 Using the above definition of the TSS, we have for Model II σ 2u 0.202(3583.132) 7.311 . For model III we have: 99 R2 1 6.043 0.8330 3583.132 99 Note, for each model we have: SSEI = 11.799*98 = 1156.302 SSEII = 7.311*97 = 709.167 SSEIII = 6.043*97 = 586.171 SSEIV = 6.095*96 = 585.12 (b) H0: Model I H1: Model IV F SSE I -SSE IV σ2u,IV (2) 46.857 Ni εi (c) H0: Model I H1: Model II F SSE I -SSE II F SSE II -SSEIV F SSE I -SSE III F TSS-SSEIV σ2u,II (1) 61.59 (or use T-ratio in Model II) (d) H0: Model II H1: Model IV σ2u,IV (1) 20.352 (or use T-ratio in Model IV) (e) H0: Model I H1: Model III σ 2u,III (1) 94.35 (or use T-ratio in Model III) (f) H0: Model 0 H1: Model IV σ2u,IV (3) 163.960 3. (a) The sample likelihood function can be represented as: T 1 l t 1 1e yt y t 1 T T K T e e Tt 1 yt T y 1 t 1 t Tt 1 yt T y 1 t 1 t The total sample log-likelihood function can be represented as: T yt L ln K T ln t 1 T 1 ln yt t 1 The 1st and 2nd derivatives are: T yt L T t 1 2 T y 2 L T t 1 t 2 2 4 2 Equating the FOC to 0 and solving yields the following solution: T yt y * t 1 T Second-order conditions are satisfied at the above value for the unknown parameter. (b) Taking expectations of the above optimal parameter value: E * T yt T E t 1 unbiased T T Var * (c) T yt 1 T Var t 1 Var yt 2 T T t 1 1 T T 2 2 2 T The above implies the estimator is consistent since the estimator is unbiased and the variances goes to zero as T →∞ 4. (a) The easiest way to proceed is to substitute the true, unknown relationship for each observation: y1=β0+β1X1+e1, yn=β0+β1Xn+en 1 0 1 X n en 0 1 X1 e1 X n X1 1 1 X n X1 en e1 X n X1 en e1 X n X1 We then can take the expected value of both sides of the above: E en E e1 e e e e E E 1 n 1 1 E n 1 1 1 X n X1 X n X1 X n X1 because E(ei)=0. Therefore this estimator is unbiased. e e Var en Var e1 (b) Var 1 Var 1 n 1 given that the errors are the X n X1 X n X1 2 only random variables, the denominator is a constant, and we have homoescedastic non-autocorrelated errors. This implies that Var 1 2 2 X n X1 2 (c) Given the above expression for the variance, the only way the above parameter estimator generates a consistent parameter estimate is if the (Xn-X1)2 approaches infinity as the sample size gets larger. In general, this estimator will not be consistent since we are usually not able to find arbitrarily large or small values of X. 5. I was looking for the fact that the FOC for minimization of the SSE with respect to the intercept terms generates the results in the non-stochastic component of the equation shown in this question. Refer to equation (5.3.7) and (5.3.8) of JHGLL on page 165. Sure, if you plug in the means you get an estimate of the intercept but the question is whether this is the CRM estimate.