Output Quality, Skill Intensity, and Factor Contents of Trade: An Empirical Analysis Based on Micro-Data of the Census of Manufactures WIOD Conference on Industry‐Level Analyses of Globalization and its Consequences Technische Universitaet Wien, Vienna May 26-28, 2010 Kyoji Fukao (Hitotsubashi University and RIETI) Keiko Ito (Senshu University) 1 1. Introduction • Recent studies on intra-industry trade (IIT) have brought to light rapid increases in vertical IIT (VIIT) (for example, see Fukao, Ishido and Ito (2003) and Schott (2004)). • Many theoretical models assume that developed economies export physical and human capitalintensive products of high quality and import unskilled labor-intensive products of low quality from developing economies. • Through this mechanism, an increase in vertical IIT may have a large impact on factor demand and factor prices. 2 1. Introduction (Contd.) • Empirical studies use information on the unit value of commodities as a proxy for product quality. • Most of empirical studies based on the unit value data take the positive relationships between commodity prices and factor intensities as given. • Yet, to the best of our knowledge, few studies have empirically examined the relationship between unit values of commodities and their factor contents at the factory level. (Notes: Some recent studies try to take quality difference among firms (plants) into account. <Quality Heterogenous-Firms model> Baldwin & Harrigan 2007; Kugler & Verhoogen 2008; Hallak & Sivadasan 2009, etc.) 3 1. Introduction (Contd.) • The Purposes of this study is: - To develop a theoretical framework to estimate the relationship between the unit values of gross output and factor intensities - To test whether factories that produce goods with a higher unit value tend to input more skilled labor and capital stock services, using micro data of the Census of Manufactures for Japan -To calculate the factor contents of trade for Japan, based on the estimated relationship between the unit values and factor intensity. 4 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT • We assume that factories, in order to produce commodities of a high quality, engage in production processes that are intensive in both skilled labor and capital. • Suppose that N commodities are produced in an industry. For each commodity, there is a continuum of different qualities. • Each “commodity” in our model corresponds to one product item in the most detailed commodity classification of production and trade statistics and that products that differ only in quality are not recorded as different products in the statistics. 5 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) • Each commodity, (n, q), is produced by a Leontief-type constant-returns-to-scale production function. Yq , i , t LU , q , i , t L S , q , i , t K q ,i ,t M q ,i ,t min , , , e ( qi ,t ) f ( q i , t ) g ( q i , t ) h ( q i , t ) ai ,t cn ,t where LU, q, i, t, LS, q, i, t, Kq, i, t and Mq, i, t denote unskilled (blue-collar) labor, skilled (white-collar) labor, capital, and intermediate input. Yq, i, t denotes the gross output of factory i. a i, t denotes factory i’s total factor productivity (TFP) level in comparison with the industry average TFP level in year t. We express elasticity values by ηY=(qi, t de(qi, t))/(e(qi, t) dqi, t), ηS=(qi, t df(qi, t))/(f(qi, t) dqi, t), ηK=(qi, t dg(qi, t))/(g(qi, t) dqi, 6 t), ηM=(qi, t dh(qi, t))/(h(qi, t) dqi, t), respectively. 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) From our production function, we have the following factor demand relationships: L S , q ,i ,t LU , q , i , t K q ,i ,t LU , q , i , t M q ,i ,t LU , q , i , t LU , q , i , t Yq , i , t f ( q i ,t ) (3.3) g ( qi ,t ) (3.4) h ( qi ,t ) (3.5) ai ,t c n ,t e ( qi ,t ) (3.6) We assume that the price elasticity of demand for each factory’s output in this industry is constant and takes the same value for all factories producing commodity n. 7 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) From an unit production cost function and constant mark-up ratio, we have the following relationship between p and q. ln p q , i , t ln e q i , t ln wU , t f ( q i , t ) w S , t g ( q i , t ) rt h ( q i , t ) p M , t ln a i , t ln c n , t ln 1 By making a linear approximation of equation (3.3) and subtracting average values across all factories from both sides of the equation, we have LS , q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t LS ,t ln L U ,t S ln p q , i , t ln p t S ln a i , t 8 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) K q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t Kt ln K ln p q , i , t ln p t K ln a i , t L U ,t M q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t Mt ln L U ,t LU , q , i , t ln Y q ,i ,t LU , t ln Y t M ln p q , i , t ln p t M ln a i , t Y ln p q , i , t ln p t Y ln a i , t ln a i , t 9 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) where S K M Y S f ( q t *) w S , t S g ( q t *) rt K h ( q t *) p M , t M Y wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t K f ( q t *) w S , t S g ( q t *) rt K h ( q t *) p M , t M Y wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t M f ( q t *) w S , t S g ( q t *) rt K h ( q t *) p M , t M Y wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t Y f ( q t *) w S , t S g ( q t *) rt K h ( q t *) p M , t M Y wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t 10 2. Theoretical Analysis of Factor Contents in VIIT (Contd.) Since we assume constant returns to scale and a constant mark-up ratio, we have the following identity among the coefficients of the above four equations. Y f ( q t *) w S , t wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t g ( q t *) rt wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t h ( q t *) p M , t wU , t f ( q t *) w S , t g ( q t *) rt h ( q t *) p M , t S K (3.19) M 1 This constraint means that a one percent increase in the unit price of output corresponds to a one percent increase in the unit production cost. We estimate the four equations under the constraint 11 (3.19) using SUR techniques. 3. Factor Contents in Japan’s VIIT • Using equations (3.15) and (3.18), we can express the ratio of the white-collar labor input to the output quantity for a factory which produces commodity (n, q) as follows: LS , n ,t ( pt ) c n , t p t S Y Yn , t ( p t ) where c’n, t denotes a commodity- and year-specific constant term. Let φD, n, t(pt) denote the distribution function of output quantity by all the factories producing commodity n in Japan over unit value p. Then, we can derive the following equation from the above equation: 12 3. Factor Contents in Japan’s VIIT (contd.) L S , D , n , t Y D , n , t c n , t pt 0 pt S Y D , n , t ( p t ) dp t • In a similar way, we can derive L S , E , n ,t YE , n ,t L S , I , n ,t YI , n ,t L S , D , n ,t YD , n ,t L S , D , n ,t YD , n ,t pt 0 S Y E , n , t ( p t ) dp t S Y D , n , t ( p t ) dp t S Y I , n , t ( p t ) dp t S Y D , n , t ( p t ) dp t pt pt 0 pt pt 0 pt pt 0 pt 13 4. Data • Census of Manufactures for Japan - Larger Establishment Sample: all mfg. plants with 30 or more employees - 6-digit commodity level information on shipment and quantity Unit values can be calculated for 800 commodities out of 2,000 commodities - Number of blue-collar and white-collar workers available for years 1981, 1984, 1987, and 1990. • Trade Statistics for Japan - Values and quantities of exports and imports at the HS 9-digit commodity level (7,000 commodities for exports and 9,000 commodities for imports) 14 4. Data (contd.) • To estimate the relationship between the unit value of gross output and factor intensities, we select only single-product establishments, which we define as establishments where one commodity accounts for more than 60% of total shipments. • By using the unit value and factor intensity information taken form the CM and the TS, we calculate the factor contents of Japan’s trade, taking account of quality (price) difference between exported and imported goods. 15 Table 5. Summary table of the unit value analysis: The case of cotton tubular knit fabric Unit value data of the Census of Manufactures 1990 Commodity classification name in the Census of Manufactures Commodity code Number of factories whose data were used Number of white-collar workers per one million yen gross output Number of blue-collar workers per one million yen gross output Capital stock (in million yen) per one million yen gross output Average unit value (million yen per ton) Standard deviation of unit value (million yen per ton) Average of natural log of unit value Standard deviation of natural log of unit value Cotton tubular knit fa 1451-11 14 0.0066 0.0167 0.1257 1.3571 1.6016 0.0393 0.6073 Total value of exports (million yen) Total value of exports/total volume of exports (million yen) Weighted average of unit value of exports (weight: value of exports) Total value of imports (million yen) Unit value (Total value of imports/total volume of imports, million yen per ton) Weighted average of unit value of imports (weight: value of imports) 203.110 2.482 2.488 543.365 1.344 1.400 16 5. Empirical Results on the Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities • Estimate equations (3.15)-(3.18) by SUR estimations subject to the constraint expressed by equation (3.19)----using factory-level data from the Census LS , q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t L ln S , t L U ,t K q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t Kt ln L U ,t M q ,i ,t ln L U , q ,i ,t LU , q , i , t ln Y q ,i ,t Mt ln L U ,t L ln U , t Y t S ln p q ,i ,t ln p t K ln p q , i , t ln S ln a i , t p t K ln a i , t M ln p q , i , t ln p t M ln a i , t Y ln p q , i , t ln p t Y ln a i , t ln a i , t 17 5. Empirical Results on the Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities: Basic Result Table 1. Relationship between factor intensity and unit price: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations with constraint Equation number Dependent variable Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) (3.15) dvlnWBratio 0.088** (0.040) (3.16) dvlnKBratio (3.17) (3.18) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) 0.165*** 0.097*** 0.056*** 0.115*** 0.117*** -0.002 (0.022) (0.027) (0.015) (0.014) (0.020) (0.023) 0.315*** (0.058) -0.248*** 0.073*** -0.051 (0.044) (0.018) (0.048) 0.132*** 0.004 (0.029) (0.031) -0.110*** 0.048*** 0.155*** 0.051 (0.020) (0.015) (0.025) (0.034) 0.140** (0.068) dvlnMBratio -0.282*** 0.131*** -0.026 (0.035) (0.018) (0.033) -0.037* (0.020) -0.179*** 0.079*** 0.051*** 0.025 (0.015) (0.013) (0.017) (0.026) 0.067 (0.044) dvlnBYratio 1.217*** 0.897*** 1.021*** 1.007*** 1.022*** 1.134*** 0.931*** 0.946*** 0.979*** 0.928*** (0.029) (0.014) (0.028) (0.016) (0.016) (0.012) (0.010) (0.015) (0.021) (0.034) Number of observations 3006 0.119*** 0.050 (0.017) (0.033) Chemicals Ceramics Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and Metals tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery 6712 1942 4331 -0.047** (0.021) 5515 8270 2267 1736 906 1074 18 5. Empirical Results on the Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities: TFP controlled Table 2. Relationship between factor intensity and unit price: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations with constraint, TFP controlled Equation Dependent variable number Explanatory variables (3.15) dvlnWBratio dvlnUV lnTFP (3.16) dvlnKBratio dvlnUV lnTFP (3.17) dvlnMBratio dvlnUV lnTFP (3.18) dvlnBYratio dvlnUV lnTFP Number of observations Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) Chemicals Ceramics (4) (5) Metals (6) Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery (7) (8) (9) (10) 0.097** (0.041) 0.111** (0.052) 0.087*** (0.017) 0.909*** (0.049) 0.049 (0.033) 0.137* (0.081) 0.154*** (0.022) 0.109** (0.050) 0.092*** (0.027) 0.062 (0.041) 0.051*** (0.015) 0.319*** (0.038) 0.116*** (0.014) 0.210*** (0.074) 0.093*** (0.020) 0.975*** (0.090) -0.005 (0.023) 0.345*** (0.097) 0.302*** (0.058) 0.411*** (0.121) -0.268*** (0.044) 0.207*** (0.057) 0.062*** (0.018) 0.296*** (0.053) -0.045 (0.049) -0.335*** (0.120) 0.120*** (0.029) -0.119* (0.065) 0.017 (0.032) -0.163*** (0.048) -0.101*** (0.020) 0.151*** (0.049) 0.056*** (0.016) -0.181** (0.081) 0.131*** (0.025) 1.248*** (0.112) 0.057* (0.034) -0.049 (0.142) 0.150** (0.070) -0.120 (0.145) -0.298*** (0.035) 0.545*** (0.045) 0.082*** (0.017) 0.991*** (0.050) -0.025 (0.032) 0.409*** (0.080) -0.073*** (0.019) 0.297*** (0.043) -0.045** (0.022) 0.404*** (0.033) -0.189*** (0.015) 0.349*** (0.038) 0.077*** (0.013) 0.118* (0.066) 0.022 (0.016) 0.864*** (0.074) 0.023 (0.026) 0.220** (0.108) 0.040 (0.044) 0.195** (0.093) 1.229*** (0.029) -0.983*** (0.041) 2940 0.934*** (0.013) -1.438*** (0.038) 6665 1.019*** (0.027) -1.177*** (0.070) 1931 1.035*** (0.016) -0.937*** (0.038) 4292 1.020*** (0.016) -1.092*** (0.028) 5461 1.141*** (0.012) -1.093*** (0.032) 8223 0.932*** (0.010) -0.857*** (0.055) 2248 0.971*** (0.014) -1.504*** (0.063) 1716 0.980*** (0.021) -0.928*** (0.090) 893 0.949*** (0.035) -0.895*** (0.074) 1066 19 5. Empirical Results on the Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities: Estimation without the Constraint Table 3. Relationship between factor intensity and unit price: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations without constraint Equation number Dependent variable Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) Chemicals Ceramics (4) (5) Metals (6) Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery (7) (8) (9) (10) (3.15) dvlnWBratio 0.032 (0.040) 0.125*** (0.017) 0.050 (0.033) 0.168*** (0.022) 0.104*** (0.027) 0.057*** (0.015) 0.114*** (0.014) 0.120*** (0.020) -0.002 (0.023) 0.340*** (0.058) (3.16) dvlnKBratio -0.185*** 0.073*** (0.044) (0.018) -0.056 (0.049) 0.131*** (0.029) -0.013 (0.031) -0.107*** 0.047*** (0.020) (0.015) 0.166*** (0.026) 0.051 (0.034) 0.152** (0.068) (3.17) dvlnMBratio -0.169*** 0.127*** (0.036) (0.018) -0.025 (0.033) -0.047** (0.020) -0.006 (0.022) -0.178*** 0.079*** (0.015) (0.013) 0.047*** (0.017) 0.024 (0.026) 0.052 (0.044) (3.18) dvlnBYratio 0.933*** (0.035) 0.879*** (0.014) 1.001*** (0.031) 0.933*** (0.018) 0.890*** (0.021) 1.115*** (0.014) 0.920*** (0.011) 0.924*** (0.016) 0.976*** (0.023) 0.844*** (0.038) 3006 6712 1942 4331 5515 8270 2267 1736 906 1074 Number of observations 20 5. Empirical Results on the Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities: based on data of factories belonging to firms with no additional factory and whose headquarters are located in the same place Table 4. Relationship between factor intensity and unit price: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations without constraint, based on data of factories belonging to firms with no additional factory and whose headquarters are located in the same place Equation number Dependent variable Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) Chemicals Ceramics (4) (5) Metals (6) (3.15) dvlnWBratio 0.122** (0.058) 0.123*** (0.022) -0.001 (0.042) 0.224*** (0.038) 0.157*** (0.044) 0.064*** (0.022) (3.16) dvlnKBratio -0.199*** 0.078*** (0.067) (0.024) -0.039 (0.058) 0.049 (0.051) -0.140** (0.056) (3.17) dvlnMBratio -0.186*** 0.091*** (0.052) (0.023) -0.063 (0.046) -0.053 (0.036) (3.18) dvlnBYratio 1.055*** (0.050) 0.903*** (0.019) 1.051*** (0.042) 1578 3547 963 Number of observations Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery (7) 0.117*** (0.020) (8) (9) (10) 0.132*** (0.036) -0.010 (0.030) 0.209*** (0.075) -0.076*** 0.051** (0.029) (0.023) 0.079* (0.043) -0.021 (0.051) 0.219** (0.096) -0.001 (0.037) -0.167*** 0.106*** (0.023) (0.019) 0.011 (0.030) -0.044 (0.034) 0.020 (0.053) 0.964*** (0.028) 0.880*** (0.035) 1.127*** (0.020) 0.893*** (0.016) 0.962*** (0.027) 1.031*** (0.030) 0.875*** (0.046) 1448 2245 3766 1050 601 468 561 21 5. Robustness checks: Relationship between Unit Production Costs and Factor Intensities Appendix Table 2. Relationship between factor intensity and unit production cost: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations without constraint Equation number Dependent variable Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) (3.15) dvlnWBratio 0.109*** (0.038) (3.16) dvlnKBratio (3.17) (3.18) (4) (5) Metals (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) 0.091*** (0.030) 0.161*** (0.021) 0.127*** (0.024) 0.058*** (0.014) 0.111*** (0.014) 0.113*** (0.021) -0.008 (0.023) 0.277*** (0.055) -0.132*** 0.089*** (0.042) (0.018) 0.073 (0.045) 0.148*** (0.027) 0.092*** (0.028) -0.062*** 0.055*** (0.019) (0.015) 0.140*** (0.026) 0.055 (0.034) 0.155** (0.064) dvlnMBratio -0.241*** 0.132*** (0.034) (0.017) 0.013 (0.031) -0.015 (0.019) -0.024 (0.019) -0.093*** 0.088*** (0.015) (0.012) 0.062*** (0.017) 0.040 (0.025) 0.133*** (0.041) dvlnBYratio 1.164*** (0.030) 0.896*** (0.014) 0.980*** (0.028) 0.972*** (0.016) 0.946*** (0.017) 1.067*** (0.013) 0.919*** (0.011) 0.943*** (0.015) 0.978*** (0.022) 0.842*** (0.034) 3006 6712 1942 4331 5515 8270 2267 1736 906 1074 Number of observations 0.089*** (0.017) Chemicals Ceramics Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery 22 5. Robustness checks: Relationship between Output Unit Values and Factor Intensities including Multi-Product Establishments Appendix Table 3. Relationship between factor intensity and unit price: Seemingly Unrelated Regression estimations with constraint --- Including multi-product establishments --- Equation number Dependent variable Food Textiles Wood (1) (2) (3) Chemicals Ceramics (4) (5) Electrical Transpor- Miscellane General and Metals tation -ous machinery precision equipment products machinery (6) (7) (8) (9) (3.15) dvlnWBratio 0.084** (0.037) (3.16) dvlnKBratio -0.224*** 0.077*** -0.117*** 0.150*** -0.006 (0.043) (0.017) (0.038) (0.028) (0.030) -0.116*** 0.060*** 0.175*** 0.066** (0.018) (0.014) (0.024) (0.031) 0.147** (0.065) (3.17) dvlnMBratio -0.205*** 0.137*** -0.021 (0.036) (0.017) (0.027) -0.179*** 0.085*** 0.054*** 0.045* (0.014) (0.012) (0.016) (0.025) 0.073* (0.042) (3.18) dvlnBYratio 1.158*** 0.893*** 1.019*** 1.019*** 1.012*** 1.135*** 0.926*** 0.942*** 0.963*** 0.924*** (0.029) (0.013) (0.022) (0.016) (0.015) (0.011) (0.009) (0.014) (0.020) (0.033) Number of observations 3450 0.125*** 0.073*** 0.182*** 0.124*** 0.051*** 0.111*** 0.127*** -0.002 (0.016) (0.028) (0.021) (0.025) (0.014) (0.013) (0.019) (0.022) (10) 8508 3042 -0.056*** -0.034* (0.019) (0.020) 5085 6255 9475 2675 2076 1187 0.318*** (0.058) 1158 23 6. Calculated Factor Contents in VIIT (contd.) • Using unit value information taken from the CM and the trade statistics as well as data on factor intensities, we estimate the factor contents of Japan’s VIIT. • For number of white-collar workers embodied in Japan’s exports for commodity n are calculated as: Unknown L S , E , n ,t YE , n ,t L S , D , n ,t YD , n ,t pt 0 pt pt 0 pt S Y E , n , t ( p t ) dp t S Y D , n , t ( p t ) dp t Estimated 24 6. Calculated Factor Contents in VIIT (contd.) • Assuming that φE, n, t(pn, t) and φI, n, t(pt) follow a log normal distribution, L S , E , n ,t Y E , n ,t L S , D , n ,t Y D ,n ,t exp S Y E 2 2 2 D S Y E D 1 2 μE : log of unit value of Japan’s exports μD : average of the factory-level unit values in logarithm σE : standard deviation of the distribution functions of exports σD : standard deviation of the distribution functions of all shipments by single-product factories 25 6. Calculated Factor Contents in VIIT (contd.) • Due to data constraints, we use average unit value differences (μE – μD, μI – μD) at the broad industry level. • Average difference between ln(unit value for exporting factories) and ln(unit value for nonexporting factories), calculated using the CM for 2001-2004. • Average difference between ln(export unit value) and ln(import unit value), calculated using the TS • We assume that σE = σI = σD L S , E , n , t NY E , n , t LS , D ,n ,t NY D , n , t exp S Y 1 E D 26 Table 7. Difference in average unit values Estimate relative unit values for domestic shipments, exports, and imports 2001-2004 Average 1990 2000 Census of Manufactures Trade Statistics Trade Statistics Export Export Export No. of No. of No. of commodities Domestic* commodities Import** commodities Import** Industry 1 Food 32 -0.003 304 0.389 332 0.444 2 Textiles 45 -0.042 716 0.342 738 0.964 3 Wood 21 -0.111 184 0.402 209 0.985 4 Chemicals 176 0.067 915 0.238 943 0.380 5 Ceramics 28 -0.104 140 -0.045 149 0.723 6 Metals 111 0.122 504 0.149 581 0.348 7 General machinery 70 0.000 442 -0.104 448 0.444 8 Electrical & precision machinery 48 0.095 379 -0.281 434 0.277 9 Transportation equipment 32 -0.078 95 -0.367 101 0.089 10 Miscellaneous products 12 0.099 230 0.293 233 0.561 Notes: * Average value of 6-digit commodity-level "ln(unit value for exporting factories)-ln(unit value for non-exporting factories)" using the 6-digit commodity-level shipments as weights. ** Average value of HS 6-digit commodity-level "ln(export unit value)-ln(import unit value)" using the HS 6-digit commodity-level trade values as weights. 27 Tables 8 & 9. Estimated factor contents of net exports Table 8: Year 1990 Industry 1 Food 2 Textiles 3 Wood 4 Chemicals 5 Ceramics 6 Metals 7 General machinery 8 Electrical & precision machinery 9 Transportation equipment 10 Miscellaneous products Manufacturing total Taking account of VIIT Not taking account of VIIT LS(persons) LU(persons) K(mil.yen) LS(persons) LU(persons) K(mil.yen) -23,315 -118,978 -1,008,666 -26,576 -130,497 -995,626 -16,295 -119,305 -576,299 -16,466 -111,666 -565,202 -13,619 -64,136 -456,310 -14,225 -64,946 -446,925 8,298 27,373 251,845 7,299 27,284 179,786 3,243 15,527 125,142 3,307 15,580 125,724 -11,126 -20,594 -40,230 -11,791 -22,045 -47,041 75,763 154,040 2,335,483 75,851 153,777 2,334,241 144,037 363,532 5,576,039 143,900 363,839 5,568,235 45,749 153,803 4,926,502 45,545 153,253 4,949,640 -7,592 -48,526 -253,930 -8,683 -46,957 -264,206 205,144 342,736 10,879,577 198,161 337,620 10,838,626 LS +7,000 persons (1.5%) LU +5,000 persons (2%) K +41 bil. yen (0.4%) Table 9: Year 2000 Industry 1 Food 2 Textiles 3 Wood 4 Chemicals 5 Ceramics 6 Metals 7 General machinery 8 Electrical & precision machinery 9 Transportation equipment 10 Miscellaneous products Manufacturing total Taking account of VIIT Not taking account of VIIT LS(persons) LU(persons) K(mil.yen) LS(persons) LU(persons) K(mil.yen) -27,056 -153,827 -1,617,631 -31,321 -170,601 -1,594,079 -34,241 -268,381 -2,223,632 -34,984 -234,334 -2,136,546 -17,133 -83,518 -866,133 -18,752 -85,739 -829,682 13,772 33,510 999,926 11,983 33,333 822,006 4,874 18,116 287,782 4,511 17,847 282,194 -3,932 -5,167 370,522 -5,780 -9,078 345,749 97,075 201,622 4,841,347 96,627 203,057 4,851,651 106,933 246,542 7,310,621 104,482 251,522 7,073,300 57,630 173,209 7,080,518 57,554 172,994 7,093,613 -8,680 -69,130 -435,466 -11,143 -65,169 -469,619 189,242 92,975 15,747,853 173,178 113,830 15,438,58728 LS +16,000 persons (10%) LU -21,000 persons (-18%) K +310 bil. yen (2%) 7. Conclusion • As for the relationship b/w the unit value of a product and its white-collar labor intensity, the significant and positive relationship we find is important empirical evidence which supports the assumption widely employed in theoretical models. • On the other hand, we find that the widely employed assumption that commodities with higher prices are more physical capital-intensive does not always hold. • The results of the factor contents of trade estimation suggests that the implication of international trade on the domestic factor markets should be very different if we take account of VIIT. 29 8. Extensions • Incorporate headquarter-level data in our analysis in order to take account of white-collar tasks provided by headquarters. Using information from “Kigyo Katsudo Kihon Chosa (BSBSA)? • What is the definition of “skill”? We may use the wage information as a proxy of skill. • Distinguish between intra-firm trade and inter-firm trade? If we can match the trade statistics with the firm- or plant-level data, it would be possible. (c.f. France, U.S.) 30