International Economics: Trade Theory and Policy WS 2013/14 Christen/Leiter/Pfaffermayr Lecture: Mo. 8:30-11:00, HS3 Proseminar: see Syllabus International Economics Page 1 Literature van Marrewijk, Ch. (2012), International Economics, Oxford University Press, 2nd ed. Chapters from Parts I, II and III Additional material will be covered in the Proseminar International Economics Page 2 Exam and Grading Includes all the material covered in the course (lecture plus proseminar). A positive grade in the PS is a necessity. Course grade is an ECTS-weighted average of exam and PS. An example of an exam plus some examples of exam questions are provided in OLAT. Three final exams per semester. Lecture: 70.0% Two short essays. You can choose from three topics. Proseminar: 30.0% Three short questions. International Economics Page 3 Questions addressed in trade theory and policy I • Determinants of trade and industry structure of an open economy in the long run. • The welfare effects and distributional consequences (factor incomes) of worldwide globalization and trade liberalization. • Labor market effects of trade and foreign direct investment. • Trade Policy: Instruments and their welfare effects The impact and the welfare effects of regional trade agreements International Economics Page 4 Questions addressed in trade theory and policy II • Structural change and trade liberalization: Should European countries protect e.g. their textile industries? • ‘Are our wages set in Beijing?’: The impact of trade with low wage countries on low skilled workers’ wages in Europe. • Why do trade volumes grow faster than GDP? • What can we expect from the multilateral trade liberalization efforts of WTO? • The impact of a bilateral Trade Agreements, e.g., between EU and US? International Economics Page 5 Literature and Resources I • Study Guide: Stephan Schueller and Daniel Ottens Oxford University Press • Krugman, Paul R., Maurice Obstfeld and Marc J. Melitz: International Economics, Theory and Policy, Pearson, 9th ed., 2012. • Feenstra Robert C. and Alan M. Taylor, International Economics: International Edition, Worth Publishers, 2nd ed., 2011 • Further literature cited in these two books, especially papers in the academic journals International Economics Page 6 Literature and Resources II FIW: http://www.fiw.ac.at/ WIFO: http://www.wifo.ac.at/ WIIW: http://www.wiiw.ac.at/ WTO: http://www.wto.org/ EU: http://ec.europa.eu/trade/ WITS: http://wits.worldbank.org/wits/ CEPII: http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/bdd_modele/bdd.asp UNCTAD: http://unctad.org/en/Pages/Statistics.aspx GTAP: https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/ Feeenstra: http://cid.econ.ucdavis.edu/data.html International Economics Page 7 Chapter 1: The World Economy – Some Stylized Facts p. 4: „International economics is what international economists do,…, you will only know about international economics, once you have studied it yourself“. „…I think that an important distinguishing characteristic is the general equilibrium nature of this approach.“ This forces us to be precise and complete in our explanations. International Economics Page 8 * The portrait was painted by Carla Rodenburg in 2001. I am grateful to Angus Maddison for his permission to use this painting. Angus Maddison Figure 1.1 Angus Maddison (1926 -2010) International Economics Page 9 Chap. 1.2 and 1.3: The economic size (power?) of a nation is best measured in terms of the total value of goods and services produced in a certain time period. Other measures of size such as land area and population are weakly correlated with economic size – look at Russia, China, India, Brazil on the one hand, and on the European Countries on the other hand. International Economics Page 10 A size comparison across open countries needs three steps: 1. Accurate data from the statistical offices in national currency (Maddison in our case). 2. Decide to look at GNP or GDP GDP + net receipts of factor income = GNP GDP…market value of goods and services produced by labor and property located in a country. GNP… market value of goods and services produced by labor and property of the nationals of a country. 3. Use the same currency ($): current US $ or PPP. International Economics Page 11 Fig 1.2: GDP and GNP, 2008 ($ billion) The dotted line is a 45º line, the axes use a logarithmic scale, and the circles are proportional to the size of GDP. GDP and GNI, 2008 (billion current $) 100,000 USA Gross National Income, GNI Japan 10,000 Germany China 1,000 100 10 10 100 1,000 Gross Domestic Product, GDP International Economics Page 12 10,000 100,000 Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) Comparing income in current $ tends to overestimate the differences between high and low income countries (i) Tradable goods are subject to international competition so that the prices of such tradable goods tend to be equal when measured in the same currency. (ii) Within a country producers of tradable and non-tradable goods compete for same resources (labor) so that the wage rate in each country reflects labor productivity. (iii) Across countries differences in productivity in the non-tradable sectors tend to be smaller than in the tradable sectors. In current $, the value of output tends to be underestimated in low-income countries. International Economics Page 13 Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)-continued Example: based on the current exchange rate Cost of hair cut in the US: 10$ Cost of hair cut in Tansania: 1$ So the same service is priced differently: the value of production in US is overestimated by a factor 10! United Nation income comparison project (ICP) collects price data on goods and services in all countries of the world and calculates PPP comparing prices in local currencies. P$=PTZS E$/TZS International Economics P US 10 => implied PPP: E TZS/E P TZS 1 Page 14 Figure 1.3: Gross domestic product, 2008; top 15, ranked according to PPP International Economics Page 15 1.5 International Trade Trade flows can readily compared using exchange rates. We distinguish merchandise trade and trade in commercial services. Stylized facts 2008 (see http://www.fiw.ac.at/ for more recent evidence): China has been the largest merchandize trade exporter, followed by Germany and US. US share in world exports is just 8.5%. Many countries have a larger share in world exports than in world production (country size matters!). International Economics Page 16 Exports Relative to Imports The difference between exports and imports (trade balance) is more pronounced than the difference between GDP and GNP, but relative to the size of imports and exports the difference is small. In 2008 China had the largest trade surplus in goods and services (349 bn $) followed by Germany (228 bn $). US has the largest trade deficit (696 bn $). In relative terms Brunei is the largest net exporter and Ethiopia the largest net-importer. Trade openness is defined as the ratio of exports +imports to production. For Singapore this ratio is more than 234%. International Economics Page 17 Figure 1.4: Exports and imports of goods and services, 2008 ($ billion) The dotted line is a 45º line, the axes use a logarithmic scale, and the circles are proportional to the size of exports. Exports and imports of goods and services, 2008 ($ bn) 10,000 USA China import value 1,000 Germany Russia 100 Saudi Arabia Ethiopia 10 Brunei 1 1 10 100 export value International Economics Page 18 1,000 10,000 Figure 1.5: Relative exports of goods and services, 2008 (% of GDP) Relative exports of goods and services, 2008 (% of GDP) 234 Singapore 212 Hong Kong 179 Luxembourg 131 Seychelles 110 Malaysia 97 Bahrain Belgium 92 United Arab Emirates 91 Macao 90 88 Malta 0 International Economics 50 100 Page 19 150 200 250 Figure 1.6: Taxes on international trade Taxes on international trade, 2008 (% of revenue) 57 Lesotho 52 Bahamas, The 44 Namibia 35 Cote d'Ivoire 35 Madagascar Maldives 32 St. Kitts and Nevis 32 27 Bangladesh 26 Niger 25 Russian Federation 0 International Economics 10 20 30 Page 20 40 50 60 1.6 Globalization Globalization defined by Neary (2002): The increased interdependence of national economies; trend towards greater integration of goods, labor and capital markets. Globalization and Income: Income statistics based on Maddison’s work (in 1990 international Dollars (corrected for PPP, ensure transitivity, base country invariance and additivity). Logarithmic scale (level and growth). Big increase in GDP per capita in 1820 (industrial revolution). Two waves of globalization: second half of 19th century and after WW2. New institutional setting after WW2: income per capita +3% p.a., world income +5% p.a., world trade flows +8% .p.a. International Economics Page 21 Figure 1.7: Development of world per capita income over the last 2000 years World GDP per capita (1990 international $), logarithmic scale 10,000 5,709 1,000 667 435 444 100 0 International Economics 500 1000 Page 22 1500 1820 2000 Figure 1.8: Two waves of globalization in trade Merchandise exports, % of GDP in 1990 prices 17.2 15 13.4 10.1 10 5 4.6 2.5 0.2 0 1870 1900 1930 world International Economics 1960 USA Page 23 Japan 1990 1.6 Globalization (continued) Globalization and capital: Two similar waves of globalization in the capital markets. Sharp increase in capital mobility since the 1960thies. Globalization and migration: Two modern waves of migration: 1820-1913: 40 millions migrants mainly form Europe to US, Canada, South America and Australia, young and mainly low skilled workers. After WW2 (not yet ended): Since the 1990thies the source countries are now mainly Asian and Eastern European countries. Many countries have quotas to restrict inward migration. Labor markets are less globally integrated than goods and capital markets. International Economics Page 24 Figure 1.9: Foreign capital stocks, assets / world GDP Foreigncapital stocks; assets / worldGDP 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1860 International Economics 1880 1900 1920 1940 Page 25 1960 1980 2000 Figure 1.10: Relative migration flows, Western Europe and Western Offshoots Relative annual immigration flows, 1870-1998 (per 1000) 6 4 2 0 1870-1913 1914-1949 1950-1973 -2 Western Europe International Economics Page 26 Western Offshoots 1974-1998 1.7: Some Stylized Facts for Austria International Economics Page 27 1.7: Some Stylized Facts for Austria International Economics Page 28 1.7: Some Stylized Facts for Austria Austria‘s most important trading partners (exports in 2009) International Economics Page 29 1.7: Some Stylized Facts for Austria Austria‘s FDI Position International Economics Page 30 Chapter 3 Classical Trade: Technology International Economics Page 31 Overview Ricardian (classical) model • Technology differences between countries are the driving force behind international trade flows • Relative (or comparative) differences are crucial, not absolute differences • Absolute differences are important for determining a country’s wage rates and welfare level • The production possibility frontier summarizes the state of technology and the available factors of production in final goods space • Trade flows increase welfare (technology gains from trade) International Economics Page 32 David Ricardo (1772-1823) “When a country can either import a commodity or produce it at home, it compares the cost of producing at home with the cost of procuring from abroad; if the latter is less than the first, it imports.” International Economics Page 33 Assumptions of the Ricardian technology model • • • • • • • • • General (example) Two countries (EU and Kenya) Two final goods (Food and Chemicals) One factor of production (Labour) Constant returns to scale production functions Perfect competition Labour is mobile between sectors, but not between countries. Costless trade in final goods (no impediments to trade) Technology as reflected by labor productivity differs between countries International Economics Page 34 Technology differences between countries Production technology is summarized in a productivity table: Labour units required to produce one unit of output Food Chemicals EU 2 8 Kenya 4 24 The EU technology is more productive for both goods The EU has an absolute advantage in Food production: it requires less labour (2 units instead of 4) The EU also has an absolute advantage in Chemicals production: it requires less labour (8 units instead of 24) International Economics Page 35 Comparative advantage: productivity method Labour units required to produce one unit of output Food Chemicals EU 2 8 Kenya 4 24 • The EU is twice as productive in the Food sector (4/2 = 2) • The EU is three times as productive in the Chemicals sector (24/8 = 3), so The EU has a comparative advantage in Chemicals, and Kenya has a comparative advantage in Food International Economics Page 36 Comparative advantage: opportunity cost method Labour units required to produce one unit of output Food Chemicals EU 2 8 Kenya 4 24 • An extra unit of Chemicals needs 8 units of labor in the EU • This labor could have made 8/2 = 4 units of Food; the opportunity cost of Chemicals production in the EU is 4 Food. • An extra unit of Chemicals in Kenya needs 24 labor • This labor could have made 24/4 = 6 units of Food; the opportunity cost of Chemicals production in Kenya is 6 Food The EU has a comparative advantage in Chemicals, Kenya in Food International Economics Page 37 The ppf is a straight line in the Ricardian model Labour units required to produce one unit of output Food Chemicals EU 2 8 Kenya 4 24 • Suppose the EU has 200 units of labour available and Kenya has 120 units available (remember: it is just an example) • If all workers in the EU produce only Food, the EU can make 200/2 = 100 Food (and 0 Chemicals) • If all workers in the EU produce only Chemicals, the EU can make 200/8 = 25 Chemicals (and 0 Food) • Similarly, if all workers in Kenya produce Food total output is 120/4 = 30 Food (and 0 Chemicals); if they all produce Chemicals total output is 120/24 = 5 Chemicals (and 0 Food) International Economics Page 38 Production possibility frontier (ppf) Definition: all possible combinations of efficient production points of final goods, given the available factors of production and the state of technology; Note that: • It is a technical specification: the ppf does not depend on the type of market competition • The ppf depends on the available factors of production: if, e.g., more labour becomes available more goods can be produced • The ppf depends on the state of technology: if new techniques become available, output increases with the same use of inputs International Economics Page 39 Production possibility frontiers Kenya can produce The EU can produce Food (0 Chemicals, 100 Food) or (0 Chemicals, 30 Food) or (20 Chemicals, 0 Food), or (5 Chemicals, 0 Food), or any combination in between any combination in between Resurce constraint :L a C a F EU C EU F EU 100 EU ppf L a EU C PPF :F C EU a a F F EU B C Opportunit y costs :a a F D 30 Kenya ppf E C A 0 International Economics 5 25 Chemicals Page 40 Production in the EU; pC/pF = relative price of Chemicals • Producer maximizing profits in Food this setting is equivalent to maximizing total revenue, given the final goods price ratio pC/pF PrEU • If pC/pF is low, this implies only production of Food EU Chemicals International Economics Page 41 Production in the EU; pC/pF = relative price of Chemicals • Producer maximizing profits in Food this setting is equivalent to maximizing total revenue, given the final goods price ratio pC/pF • If pC/pF is high, this implies only production of Chemicals EU PrEU Chemicals International Economics Page 42 Production in the EU; pC/pF = relative price of Chemicals • Producer maximizing profits in Food this setting is equivalent to maximizing total revenue, given the final goods price ratio pC/pF • If pC/pF is equal to the slope of the ppf, production can be EU anywhere along the ppf (to be determined by other factors) •Under Autarky it must hold that pC/pF is equal to the slope of the ppf. Chemicals International Economics Page 43 Gains form Trade Relative to autarky trade increases the rel. price of chemicals in the EU (exporter) and decrease it in Kenya (importer). Consumption can be extended in both trading partners (gains form trade). Food 120 100 EU budgetline EU ppf B 30 F Kenya budgetline A Kenya ppf 0 International Economics 5 G 6.25 25 Page 44 Chemicals Equilibirum Value of consumption =Value of production, trade is balanced in each country. Product prices are determined at the World market equating world demand =world supply. Marginal rate of substitution of consumers = PC/PF. Wages have to adjust according to productivity in each country . EU EU EU 1 EU PC w ac w PC ac K K K PF w PF 1 EU w aF aF Due to lower wages food producers of Kenya (holding the comparative advantage) are competitive on the world market. International Economics Page 45 Some empirical evidence Figure 3.5 Kenya–EU exports and productivity, various sectors 100 Kenya export (%) - import (%) food 50 0 0 50 100 150 200 chemicals machinery -50 Relative productivity ratio (Kenya/EU); % International Economics Page 46 Some empirical evidence - continued The Balassa index Share of industry j in country exports A A BI j Share of industry j in reference country exports BI 1 Revealed comparativ e advantage of country in good j A j A Exports of 28 manufacturing sectors for the member of OECD countries Reference country is the group of all OECD countries Observe high values for countries with a smaller industrial base such as Italy and Finland. Observe the persistence of comparative advantages. International Economics Page 47 Some empirical evidence - continued Figure 3.7 Highest Balassa index, selected countries International Economics Page 48 Some empirical evidence - continued Figure 3.7 Highest Balassa index, selected countries c Brazil d USA 20 5 18 16 4 14 12 3 10 8 2 6 4 2 0 2001 1 Oil seed, oleagic fruits, grain, seed, fruit, etc, nes Works of art, collectors pieces and antiques Sugars and sugar confectionery 2002 2003 International Economics 2004 2005 Aircraft, spacecraft, and parts thereof 2006 2007 2008 0 2001 Page 49 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Concluding remarks, Ricardian (classical) model • Technological differences between countries are the classical driving force for international trade flows. • Only comparative costs, not absolute costs, are important for determining the direction of trade flows. • Absolute costs are important for determining a country’s welfare level. • Allowing for more countries and more goods is easy, allowing for more than one factor of production is not (see neoclassical model). International Economics Page 50 Chapter 4 Production Structure International Economics Page 51 Overview Production Structure • The neoclassical model focuses on differences in relative factor endowments as a cause for international trade flows. • The main contributors are Eli Heckscher, Bertil Ohlin, and Paul Samuelson: it is therefore referred to as the HOS model. • This chapter reviews the production structure of the model. • Neoclassical production functions with two inputs and constant returns to scale. • Optimizing economic agents, taking prices as given. • The impact of technology differences is analyzed in Chapter 3, we therefore assume identical technology from now on. International Economics Page 52 Paul Samuelson (1915–2009) “Funeral by funeral, theory advances” www.brainyquote.com International Economics Page 53 Assumptions of the neoclassical (HOS) model • • • • • • • • • • • • General (example) Two countries (Austria and Bolivia) Two final goods (Food and Manufactures) Two factors of production (Capital and Labour) Constant returns to scale production functions Perfect competition in all markets Capital and Labor is mobile between sectors, but not between countries Costless trade in final goods (no impediments to trade) Identical production technology in the two countries No factor-intensity reversal Identical homothetic tastes in the two countries Countries differ in their (relative) factor endowments International Economics Page 54 Main results of the neoclassical (HOS) model The HOS model derives 4 main propositions in Chapters 5-7: • Factor Price Equalization: Trade in goods (which equalizes final goods prices) leads to the equalization of factor prices. • Stolper-Samuelson theorem: An increase in the price of a final good increases the (real) reward to the factor used intensively in the production of that good and reduces the (real) reward to the other factor of production. • Rybczynski theorem: An increase in the quantity of a factor of production, at constant final goods prices, leads to an increase in the production of the good using that factor intensively and a decreased production of the other good. • Heckscher-Ohlin theorem: A country will export the final good which makes relatively intensive use of the relatively abundant factor of production. International Economics Page 55 Neoclassical production functions Characteristics of our neoclassical production functions • Two inputs: capital (K) and labour (L) • Substitutability: a given output level can be produced using different combinations of inputs, i.e. the use of one input can be substituted for the use of another input • Positive marginal product: if more capital or more labour is used output increases • Diminishing marginal product: given the use of capital, an increase in the use of labour leads to ever smaller increases in output (similarly for capital) • Constant returns to scale: an increase in the use of both inputs by z% also leads to an increase in output of z% International Economics Page 56 Structure of the equilibrium delivery of manufactures (spending m on manufactures) capital services capital owners (rental income) production manufactures producers consumers labourers labour services production food (wage income) delivery of food (spending (1-m) on food) direction of goods and services flows (direction of money flows) International Economics Page 57 Production functions: substitutability and isoquant • Let M be the output of Capital Manufactures, Km the input of capital, Lm the input of labour and m a capital intensity parameter (0 < m < 1); this is a possible production function: m 1m MK mL m • The figure on the left depicts isoquant an isoquant for this function; note the substitutability between capital and labour Labour International Economics Page 58 Production is constant returns to scale (CRS) Capital • At point A1 production M = 1 M=1 • Reducing inputs by 30% leads to point A2 • CRS implies at point A2 B1 production M = 0.7 • Similarly for points B1 and B2 B2 • Conclusion: A1 isoquant M = 0.7 is a radial A2 blow-up of isoquant M = 1 M=0.7 D Labour International Economics Page 59 Profit maximization: two-step procedure Producer profits = revenue – production costs Maximizing profits is a two-step procedure • First, given how much you want to produce: minimize production costs • Second: determine the optimal output level International Economics Page 60 Cost minimization Capital • Suppose you want to M=1 produce M=1 at minimum cost taking wage rate w and rental rate r as given • Total cost = wLm + rKm , a straight line in (labour, capital) K space with slope = - w/r A • Minimum costs are achieved at a point of tangency between the isocost line and the isoquant; point A, using K L International Economics Labour Page 61 capital and L labour Constant returns to scale and production costs Under constant returns to scale (CRS) the isoquants are radial blow-ups of one another Minimizing production costs is now simple: • First, we determine the cost-minimizing input combination for producing one unit of output, say K and L • Second, determine the output level, say z units. Proportionally adjust the unit inputs to produce z output, so using: zK and zL • Under CRS: total cost = (per unit cost) output International Economics Page 62 Profit maximization, CRS, and perfect competition Profits = [price – (per unit cost)] output There are three possibilities • price < unit cost: optimal output level = 0, no profit • price = unit cost: optimal output level undetermined (can be determined by other factors); profit level = 0 • price > unit cost: optimal output level = infinite, profit level is infinite not possible in economic equilibrium Conclusion: CRS + perfect competition implies: • price unit cost • output > 0 price = unit costs International Economics Page 63 Impact of a fall in the wage rate Capital The figure shows the costM=1 minimizing input combination at point A for the ratio w0/r Suppose the wage rate falls to w1; rotates the isocost line A Minimum costs are now B achieved at point B with a lower capital/labor ratio Labour International Economics Page 64 Food production with lower capital intensity Capital • The figure shows the costM=1 minimizing input combination F=1 at point A for M=1 and w/r • Suppose Food production has a lower capital-intensity parameter: F < M A • For the same w/r minimum costs for Food production are at point B with a lower B capital/labour ratio Labour International Economics Page 65 Empirical Evidence Figure 4.4 Capital stock per worker×1000 $; 1990 in 1985 $ 80 70 S w itz erland 60 50 W . G erm any 40 Japan US A 30 UK 20 10 India 0 International Economics Page 66 Empirical Evidence – continued Primary products exports (% of country's manufacturing exports), 2008 Saudi Arabia Japan Korea South Taipei Nigeria Hong Kong Singapore Un Arab Em Rus s ia China Switzerland Banglades h Norway Germ any Mexico Un Kingdom Aus tria Sweden Italy World Philippines Belgium USA Poland Malays ia Canada France Thailand India Spain Netherlands Pakis tan Vietnam Indones ia Aus tralia Brazil Ethiopia 0 International Economics 10 20 30 40 Page 67 50 60 70 80 90 Concluding remarks Production Structure • The neoclassical (HOS) model explains trade flows based on differences in relative factor abundance • The HOS model derives 4 main propositions • Production uses 2 inputs (substitution between inputs) under constant returns to scale (CRS) • The cost-minimizing input combination depends on: – The capital-intensity parameter () – The wage-rental ratio (w/r) • With CRS and perfect competition: – if a good is produced price = unit production costs International Economics Page 68