Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation 14 December 2011 HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation 2011 http://darp.lse.ac.uk/HMRC-HMT 10.1 Tax Evasion and Compliance Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Overview... Tax Evasion and Compliance Background How compliance fits into public economics TAG model Interaction models Evidence 2 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Tax compliance: Questions Fundamental questions about non-compliance The how much? question: tax evasion important special case to be distinguished from tax avoidance? several ways of drawing the line between the two The what drives it? question: simple quantification does it matter? The what is it? question: How much? What is it? What drives it? how to represent non-compliance in an economic model how does tax evasion fit into the economics of taxation? complex relation between the individual taxpayer and society as a whole Begin with numbers… 3 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation 2001 US Federal Tax Gap ($billion) Underreported nonbusiness income 56 Underreported business income 109 Overreported Offsets to Income & Credits 32 Individual Income Tax 197 Employment Tax 54 Corporation Income Tax 30 Estate and Excise Taxes 5 Total underreporting 285 Nonfiling 27 Total underpayment 34 Gross tax gap 345 Enforced and other late payments -55 Net tax gap (tax not collected) 290 Source: US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service (2006) 4 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation UK Tax Gap Estimates 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 per cent 2007-08 2008-09 2009-10 Value Added Tax (VAT) Excise duties and other indirect taxes 11.7 8.6 15.2 7.8 13.5 8.6 12.4 7.7 15.5 7.7 13.8 6.5 Income Tax, National Insurance Contributions, Capital Gains Tax Corporation Tax Other direct taxes Total tax gap 6.2 5.4 5.4 5.2 5.2 5.8 14.7 8.4 8.5 11.1 7.2 8.3 9.3 7.5 7.4 10.3 6.5 8.1 11.7 4.9 7.9 Total tax gap 35 36 10.6 7.5 8 £bn 37 36 39 35 Source, HMRC (2011) Tables 1.2, 1.3 5 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Tax compliance: broader issues Tax gap Lack of information? (McManus and Warren 2006) US, UK evidence is not bad but elsewhere can be scanty Shadow economy broader than tax evasion / avoidance includes other illegal, unobserved actrivities estimates from Schneider and Enste (2000) based on currency demand Sweden Denmark Norway Germany United States Austria Switzerland 1960 2% 4.5% 1.5% 2% 3.5% 0.5% 1% 1995 16% 17.5% 18% 13.2% 9.5% 7% 6.7% Should we find this alarming? definition of shadow economy is not always consistent shadow economy estimates vary enormously according to method difficult to test proposition that change in relationship due to non-compliance 6 Case 1 – a large economy? Roman Greek [+] [−] [ + ] (b, B) (d, A) [ − ] (a, D) (g, C) Roman Greek Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Public sector and the Public (1) [+] [−] [ + ] (b, B) (g, A) [ − ] (a, C) (d, D) Case 1 equilibrium Case 2 – a small economy? Case 2 equilibria Case 1 •A large tax-financed public sector may be perceived as desirable (b, B) •People will still try to default on taxes •Need a “policeman” Case 2 •“policeman” may still be needed… •…to avoid disaster (d, D) •…to avoid inequity (a, C) or (g, A) 7 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Agenda Outline main approaches to tax compliance Consider some important variants 1 TAG 2 Strategic interaction 3 Social interaction public goods and the public sector the role of firms Will lay basis for policy lecture Literature overviews: Andreoni et al (1998) Cowell (1990, 2004) Slemrod (2007) Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002) 8 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Overview... Tax Evasion and Compliance Background Risk-taking behaviour and compliance TAG model Strategic interaction Social interaction Evidence 9 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation TAG model Standard model is essentially one of Taxpayer As Gambler The gamble involves a bet with the tax authority based on Allingham and Sandmo (1972) Individuals make bets on whether they will be caught concealing income …or not reporting at all …or working in underground economy Appropriateness relies on a special set of assumptions about motivation of individuals about the way that the government is perceived 10 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation TAG: taxes, penalties, returns Tax payer/evader has true income y Tax authority audits: if evader is caught, pays a surcharge s on the evaded tax te perceived probability of this happening is p Parameters determine returns to evasion: is supposed to pay tax on all of this at rate t chooses to conceal an amount e, pays tax on the remainder consider rate of return to $1 of evasion activity... r = – s with probability p r = 1 with probability 1 – p expected rate of return is 1 – p – ps Consumption (disposable income) is a function of: income y and tax rate t random rate of return r evasion choice e c = [1 – t] y + rte (a random variable) 11 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation TAG: budget constraint c': consumption if not caught c'': consumption if caught A: Payoffs if absolutely honest B: Payoff if blatantly dishonest Consumption possibilities for all e 1 A cut in the surcharge rate s 2 A cut in the tax rate t 3 Increase in income y c" c' = [1 – t] y + te if not audited / convicted c'' = [1 – t] y – ste if audited and convicted A [1t]y [1tst]y B c' [1t]y y 12 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation TAG: Preferences and beliefs Tax payer has von-Neumann Morgenstern preferences Consumer’s welfare is expected utility of consumption: Eu(c) = [1 – p] u(c' ) + p u(c'' ) Eu(c) = [1 – p] u([1 – t] y + te) + p u([1 – t] y – ste) Cardinal utility function u has the “usual properties”: gets no intrinsic pleasure from evasion and feels no shame correctly perceives probability of detection p assumes that it is exogenously given uc(•) > 0 (first derivative) ucc(•) 0 (second derivative) Both u and p determine shape of ICs in (c', c'' )-space curvature of ICs depends on risk aversion – ucc(•)/uc(•) slope of ICs where crosses 45º line is [1 – p]/p 13 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Equilibria of the tax-evader Feasible set A: corner solution (honesty) c" B: corner solution (dishonesty) C: Interior (partial honesty) E: Expected payoff solution depends on •tax parameters t:= (p, s, t) •income y •personal attributes a e* = e(t, y, a) •E •A •C E(ruc(c)) ≤ 0 if e* = 0 •B 0 E(ruc(c)) ≥ 0 if e* = y E(ruc(c)) = 0 if 0 < e* < y c' 14 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Comparative statics Focus on the interior solution Effect of increased p: Indifference map “rotates” For given budget constraint, tangency moves closer to A Effect of increased s: what happens to this when tax and enforcement parameters change? do this graphically or analytically differentiate the first-order condition E(ruc(c)) = 0 Point B moves down For given utility function, tangency moves closer to A Effect of increased t: assume decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA) amount “invested” in a risky asset increases with resources so in this model, given DARA, evasion rises with y but this will also imply that evasion falls with t 15 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Extending the model Government budget constraint: Define economy-wide aggregates R = tY t ∫ re(t, y, a) F(p) So budget constraint becomes aggregate income: Y := ∫ y dF(y, a) aggregate nominal tax receipts: tY aggregate “leakage” from evasion: ∫ re(t, y, a) dF(y, a) cost of enforcing probability p across economy F(p) Composition of revenue R ≥` R revenue actually raised ≥ required target revenue tY t ∫ re(t, y, a) F(p) ≥`R But this ignores how the government revenue may be used… 16 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation TAG model: Public Sector Taxes are used to pay for a public good z Government budget constraint in this extended model is: Individuals benefit from provision of the good E(ruc(c,z)) = 0 essentially as before Response of e in this model is much the same for some cases: …but they prefer that someone else pay for it so there is still a motive for tax evasion and expected utility is now Eu(c,z), where uz(c,z) > 0 FOC for an interior maximum is: R ≥ yz where y is the (constant) marginal rate of transformation Surcharge Probability of detection But for the tax rate t we have new insights… 17 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation The effect of a rise in the tax rate There are still the conventional “income” and “substitution” effects But t also affects amount of public good available Increasing t will: Eua Desirable to increase t? reduce private consumption c increase availability of public good z depends on amount of public good already available Expect a “hump” shape: for t close to 0 we have z close to 0: raising t is desirable for t close to 1 we may have satiation in z: lowering t is desirable “underprovision” z < z*a “overprovision” z > z*a 18 t Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Preferences for public and private goods How is z* determined? Optimal provision uses standard SMRS = MRT rule Because of the risk component general formula is unwieldy c So take a simplified set of preferences ua(c, z) = c + va(z) ma := uza(c, z)/uca(c, z) = vza(z) m := Sma = MRT Evasion erodes effectiveness of tax in providing z... feeds back into effect of tax on evasion change in (et) has sign of m – y / zt a simple criterion for determining under / over provision slope = m z 19 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Effect of a rise in the tax rate If the public goods are… But individuals differ in: ty risk aversion taste for public goods income So, different responses: under-provided: a rise in t increases the amount of evasion over-provided: a rise in t decreases the amount of evasion Cowell and Gordon (1988) te constrained by e ≤ y high marginal evaluation low marginal evaluation t Get a more complex relationship between t and evasion overall 20 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Overview... Tax Evasion and Compliance Background Reporting models. Climate of evasion and social sanction TAG model Interaction models Evidence 21 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Strategic interaction Based on a application of game theory Intuition of simple strategic model: simultaneous move if tax authority plays “audit” best response of taxpayer is “report” if taxpayer plays “report” best response of tax authority is “not audit” etc, etc. no equilibrium in pure strategies Intuition of simple strategic model: leader-follower Two players: tax authority and taxpayer Tax authority chooses whether or not to investigate Taxpayer chooses whether or not to cheat if tax authority moves first, perhaps get a simple outcome Develop this into a richer policy model? focus on tax-collector/tax-payer interaction what role is there for beliefs about others’ goals and actions? can tax authority precommit to an audit strategy? 22 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Social interaction Different countries, different types of compliance behaviour? 1 Symmetric consumption externality the more others evade… …the easier to find a corrupt accountant leads to reduction in “noncompliance costs” 3 May also be induced by tax authority if you evade maybe I feel less pain if caught behaving antisocially social stigma (Benjamini and Maital 1985, Kim 2003) 2 Technological (production) externality develop a model of a compliance climate? (Cummings, et al. 2009) others’ evasion choices affect my evasion decision (Fortin et al. 2007) several possible foundations… auditing rules may induce a perceived interdependence creates a “co-ordination game” – Alm and Mckee (2004) Develop the first of these variants. 23 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Climate: model Evasion decisions affect outcomes in two ways Nature of the consumption externality e: Own evasion activity E: aggregate evasion In principle there are two subcases: aggregate evasion affects utility moral climate? Utility of an a-type is Va(e,E) where each person’s outcome affected by own choices (as before) also affected by evasion of others (independently of public goods) 1 where aggregate E increases utility 2 where aggregate E reduces utility Focus on case 2 24 The Evasion-Utility Space Payoffs if act honestly utility Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Interaction: model behaviour • Payoffs if act dishonestly Check incentive to switch Dominant behaviour Va(0,E) Find equilibrium… Check stability… min E = 0, max E = Y low E : individual switches to 0 high E: individual switches to y ◦• E < E*: switching decreases E E > E*: switching increases E Va(y,E) • Y 0 E* aggregate evasion Three equilibria: •E = 0 (stable) E •E = E* (unstable) •E = Y (stable) 25 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Overview... Tax Evasion and Compliance Background What do we know? What can we know? TAG model Interaction models Evidence 26 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Empirical evidence Few governments/agencies publish data Best data (TCMP) enable one to address only a restricted set of questions Survey data obviously problematic Experimental data sometimes useful (Alm et al. 1990 ) Indirect methods are often seriously flawed Focus is on false reports. Limited info on non-filers. Last full TCMP in 1988 recently (2005/6) updated in National Research Program Private data must be treated with caution For survey see Andreoni et al (1998) Focus on aggregate expenditure/income gaps or the demand for currency neglect measurement error and other sources of discrepancy Some micro-data studies are useful focus on relationship between expenditure and income for self-employed on regularly employed (Pissarides and Weber 1989) focus on charity giving and different types income (Feldman and Slemrod 2007) 27 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Personal compliance Behaviour varies by income type and population group (TCMP) Effect of tax rates: weak relationship with probability of audit weak relationship with severity of penalties Detection is imperfect (TCMP): Less compliance in audit classes with higher marginal tax rates? Corroborated by evidence on the reporting of capital gains Corroborated also by time series? Enforcement parameters work in expected direction (TCMP): Personal taxpayers income-elasticity of underreporting: 0.3 Farm business income income-elasticity of underreporting: 0.65 Source of income rather than level which is a significant determinant of evasion. Married people evade more than single persons variation in detection rates at least as important as… variations in personal characteristics Slemrod et al (2001) controlled experiment results: as expected for modest incomes and for those with high opportunity to evade But high-income people reported less than those in control group 28 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Compliance by firms Surveys: Nur-tegin (2008), Slemrod (2004) Evidence: Rice (1994) based on TCMP Highlights lack of ... theoretical models corporate income tax compliance microdata; confidence in microdata on tax compliance Two key results: compliance positively associated with being publicly traded and belonging to a highly regulated industry having low profits relative to the industry median is correlated with higher corporate tax evasion 29 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation Evidence: summary TCMP evidence is broadly in line with evidence of responses from TAG model Confirmation as to evasion patterns by different groups according to income and personal characteristics However implied detection probability suggests that there is far too little tax evasion going on…! may neglect heterogeneity of effective detection probability also taxpayer ignorance Responses are also borne out by experimental evidence (Alm et al.1990 ) 30 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation References (1) Allingham, M. and A. Sandmo (1972) “Income tax evasion: a theoretical analysis,” Journal of Public Economics, 1, 323-338 Alm, J. and Mckee, M. (2004) “Tax compliance as a coordination game,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 54, 297-312 Alm, J., Bahl, R. and Murray, M. N. (1990) “Understanding Taxpaying Behavior: A Conceptual Framework with Implications for Research,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72,603-613 * Andreoni, J. Erard, B. and Feinstein, J. (1998) “Tax Compliance”, Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 818-860 Benjamini, Y. and Maital, S. (1985) “Optimal tax evasion and optimal tax evasion policy: behavioral aspects,” in Gaertner, W. and Wenig, A. (eds) The Economics of the Shadow Economy, Springer Verlag, Berlin Cowell, F. A. (1990) Cheating the Government, MIT Press, Cambridge MA Cowell, F. A. (2004) “Carrots and Sticks in Enforcement” in Aaron, H. J. and Slemrod, J. (ed.) The Crisis in Tax Administration, The Brookings Institution, Washington DC, 230-275 Cowell, F. A. and Gordon, J. P. F. (1988) “Unwillingness to pay: tax evasion and public good provision,” Journal of Public Economics, 36, 305-321 Cummings, R. G., Martinez-Vazquez, J., McKee, M. and Torgler, B. (2009) Tax morale affects tax compliance: Evidence from surveys and an artefactual field experiment, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 70, 447-457 Feldman, N. E. and Slemrod, J. (2007) “Estimating tax noncompliance with evidence from unaudited tax returns,” The Economic Journal, 117, 327–352 Fortin, B., Lacroix, G. and Villeval, M.-C. (2007) “Tax evasion and social interactions,” Journal of Public Economics, 91, 2089–2112 HM Revenue and Customs (2011) Measuring Tax Gaps 2011 Kim, Y. (2003) “Income distribution and equilibrium multiplicity in a stigma-based model of tax 31 evasion”, Journal of Public Economics, 87 1591–1616 Frank Cowell: HMRC-HMT Economics of Taxation References (2) McManus, J. and Warren, N. (2006) “The Case for Measuring Tax Gap,” eJournal of Tax Research, 4, 61-79 Nur-tegin, K. D. (2008) “Determinants of Business Tax Compliance,” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 8, Article 18 Pissarides, C. and Weber, G. (1989) “An Expenditure-Based Estimate of Britain's Black Economy,” Journal of Public Economics, 39, 17-32 Rice, E. M. (1994), “The corporate tax gap: evidence on tax compliance by small corporations”, in Slemrod, J. (ed.) “Why people pay taxes”, University of Michigan Press, p. 125-161 Slemrod, J. (2004) “The Economics of Corporate Tax Selfishness,” National Tax Journal, 57, 877-899 Slemrod, J. (2007) “Cheating Ourselves: The Economics of Tax Evasion,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 25-48 Slemrod, J., Blumenthal, M. and Christian, C. (2001) “Taxpayer Response to an Increased Probability of Audit: Evidence from a Controlled Experiment in Minnesota,” Journal of Public Economics, 79, 455-483 Slemrod, J. and Yitzhaki, S. (2002) “Tax avoidance, evasion and administration,” Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 3, pp 1423-1470, North-Holland, Elsevier * Schneider, F. and Enste, D.H. (2000) “Shadow economies: size, causes and consequences” Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 77-114 US Department of the Treasury, Internal Revenue Service (2006) Updated Estimates of the TY 2001 Individual Income Tax Underreporting Gap. Overview. February 22. 32 Washington, D.C.: Office of Research, Analysis, and Statistics.