Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2012 Lecture 5 Last week… Coase Theorem: in the absence of transaction costs, if property rights are well-defined and tradable, we’ll always get efficiency Or: if conditions are perfect, initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency Or, if property rights are complete enough, we can overcome externalities Two important caveats we’ll talk about today More expansive property rights are more costly to implement/enforce – need to make sure it’s worth it Coase only applies when no transaction costs – but when is that a good assumption? 1 When are stronger property rights “worth it”? 2 ORIGINAL GAME MODIFIED GAME Player 2 Player 2 Farm Steal Farm 10, 10 -5, 12 Steal 12, -5 0, 0 Farm Player 1 Player 1 We motivated property law by looking at a game between two neighboring farmers Steal Farm 10 – c, 10 – c -5 – c, 12 – P Steal 12 – P, -5 – c -P, -P Changing the game had two effects: Allowed us to cooperate by not stealing from each other Introduced a cost c of administering a property rights system 3 Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights” “A primary function of property rights is that of guiding incentives to achieve a greater internalization of externalities” “[ In order for an externality to persist, ] The cost of a transaction in the rights between the parties… must exceed the gains from internalization.” “Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.” 4 Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights” “Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.” Private ownership of land among Native Americans Cost of administering private ownership: moderate Before fur trade… externality was small, so gains from internalization were small gains < costs no private ownership of land 5 Harold Demsetz (1967), “Toward a Theory of Property Rights” “Property rights develop to internalize externalities when the gains from internalization become larger than the cost of internalization.” Private ownership of land among Native Americans Cost of administering private ownership: moderate Before fur trade… externality was small, so gains from internalization were small gains < costs no private ownership of land As fur trading developed… externality grew, so gains from internalization grew gains > costs private property rights developed 6 Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs” The date is 10,000 or 11,000 B.C. You are a member of a primitive tribe that farms its land in common. Farming land in common is a pain; you spend almost as much time watching each other and arguing about who is or is not doing his share as you do scratching the ground with pointed sticks and pulling weeds. …It has occurred to several of you that the problem would disappear if you converted the common land to private property. Each person would farm his own land; if your neighbor chose not to work very hard, it would be he and his children, not you and yours, that would go hungry. 7 Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs” There is a problem with this solution… Private property does not enforce itself. Someone has to make sure that the lazy neighbor doesn’t solve his food shortage at your expense. [Now] you will have to spend your nights making sure they are not working hard harvesting your fields. All things considered, you conclude that communal farming is the least bad solution. 8 Friedman tells a similar story: “we owe civilization to the dogs” Agricultural land continues to be treated as a commons for another thousand years, until somebody makes a radical technological innovation: the domestication of the dog. Dogs, being territorial animals, can be taught to identify their owner’s property as their territory and respond appropriately to trespassers. Now you can convert to private property in agricultural land and sleep soundly. Think of it as the bionic burglar alarm. -Friedman, Law’s Order, p. 118 9 So… Coase: if property rights are complete and tradable, we’ll always get efficiency Demsetz: yes, but this comes at a cost property rights will expand when the benefits outweigh the costs either because the benefits rise… …or because the costs fall Of course, Coase wasn’t completely ignoring costs… Next: what are transaction costs, how do we deal with them? 10 Transaction Costs 11 What are transaction costs? Anything that makes it difficult or expensive for two parties to achieve a mutually beneficial trade Three categories Search costs – difficulty in finding a trading partner Bargaining costs – difficulty in reaching an agreement Enforcement costs – difficulty in enforcing the agreement afterwards 12 Bargaining costs come in many forms Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection 13 Bargaining costs come in many forms Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection Private information (don’t know each others’ threat points) Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983), “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading” – always some chance of inefficiency 14 Bargaining costs come in many forms Asymmetric information Akerloff (1970), “The Market for Lemons” – adverse selection Private information (don’t know each others’ threat points) Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983), “Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading” – always some chance of inefficiency Uncertainty If property rights are ambiguous, threat points are uncertain, and bargaining is difficult 15 Bargaining costs come in many forms Large numbers of parties Developer values large area of land at $1,000,000 10 homeowners, each value their plot at $80,000 16 Bargaining costs come in many forms Large numbers of parties Developer values large area of land at $1,000,000 10 homeowners, each value their plot at $80,000 Holdout, freeriding Hostility 17 Example of high transaction costs with many sellers 18 Sources of transaction costs Search costs Bargaining costs Asymmetric information/adverse selection Private information/not knowing each others’ threat points Uncertainty about property rights/threat points Large numbers of buyers/sellers – holdout, freeriding Hostility Enforcement costs 19 So, what do we do? 20 What we know so far… No transaction costs initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency wherever they start, people will trade until efficiency is achieved Significant transaction costs initial allocation does matter, since trade may not occur (and is costly if it does) This leads to two normative approaches we could take 21 Two normative approaches to property law Design the law to minimize transaction costs “Structure the law so as to remove the impediments to private agreements” Normative Coase “Lubricate” bargaining 22 Two normative approaches to property law Design the law to minimize transaction costs “Structure the law so as to remove the impediments to private agreements” Normative Coase “Lubricate” bargaining Try to allocate rights efficiently to start with, so bargaining doesn’t matter that much “Structure the law so as to minimize the harm caused by failures in private agreements” Normative Hobbes 23 Which approach should we use? Compare cost of each approach Normative Coase: cost of transacting, and remaining inefficiencies Normative Hobbes: cost of figuring out how to allocate rights efficiently (information costs) When transaction costs are low and information costs are high, structure the law so as to minimize transaction costs When transaction costs are high and information costs are low, structure the law to allocate property rights to whoever values them the most 24 So now we have one general principle we can use for designing property law When transaction costs are low, design the law to facilitate voluntary trade When transaction costs are high, design the law to allocate rights efficiently whenever possible 25 Designing an efficient property law system 26 Four questions we need to answer what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? 27 Public versus Private Goods Private Goods rivalrous – one’s consumption precludes another excludable – technologically possible to prevent consumption example: apple Public Goods non-rivalrous non-excludable examples defense against nuclear attack infrastructure (roads, bridges) parks, clean air, large fireworks displays 28 Public versus Private Goods When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited 29 Public versus Private Goods When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied 30 Public versus Private Goods When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied Efficiency suggests private goods should be privately owned, and public goods should be publicly provided/regulated 31 Public versus Private Goods When private goods are owned publicly, they tend to be overutilized/overexploited When public goods are privately owned, they tend to be underprovided/undersupplied Efficiency suggests private goods should be privately owned, and public goods should be publicly provided/regulated 32 This accords with the principle we just saw Transaction costs low facilitate voluntary trade Private goods – low transaction costs Private ownership facilitates trade Transaction costs high allocate rights efficiently Public goods – high transaction costs Public provision/regulation of public goods required to get efficient amount 33 Four questions we need to answer what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? 34 Calabresi and Melamed treat property and liability under a common framework Calabresi and Melamed (1972), Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral Liability Is the rancher liable for the damage done by his herd? Property Does the farmer’s right to his property include the right to be free from trespassing cows? Entitlements Is the farmer entitled to land free from trespassing animals? Or is the rancher entitled to the natural actions of his cattle? 35 Three possible ways to protect an entitlement Property rule / injunctive relief Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime (Injunction: court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation) But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right) 36 Three possible ways to protect an entitlement Property rule / injunctive relief Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime (Injunction: court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation) But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right) Liability rule / damages Violations of my entitlement are compensated Damages – payment to victim to compensate for damage done Inalienability Violations punished as a crime Unlike property rule, the entitlement cannot be sold 37 Comparing property/injunctive relief to liability/damages rule Injuree (person whose entitlement is violated) always prefers a property rule Injurer always prefers a damages rule Why? Punishment for violating a property rule is severe If the two sides need to negotiate to trade the right, injurer’s threat point is lower Even if both rules eventually lead to the same outcome, injurer may have to pay more 38 Comparing injunctive relief to damages – example E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300 100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100 Electric company E emits smoke, dirties the laundry at a laundromat L next door E earns profits of 1,000 Without smoke, L earns profits of 300 Smoke reduces L’s profits from 300 to 100 E could stop polluting at cost 500 L could prevent the damage at cost 100 39 First, we consider the non-cooperative outcomes E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300 100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100 Polluter’s Rights (no remedy) E earns 1,000 L installs filters, earns 300 – 100 = 200 Laundromat has right to damages E earns 1,000, pays damages of 200 800 L earns 100, gets damages of 200 300 Laundromat has right to injunction E installs scrubbers, earns 1,000 – 500 = 500 L earns 300 40 E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300 100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100 Noncooperative payoffs Polluter’s Rights Damages Injunction E payoff (non-coop) 1,000 800 500 L payoff (non-coop) 200 300 300 1,200 1,100 800 Combined payoff (non-coop) 41 What about with bargaining? Polluter’s Rights Damages E profits = 1,000 L profits = 300 100 E prevention = 500 L prevention = 100 Injunction E payoff (non-coop) 1,000 800 500 L payoff (non-coop) 200 300 300 Combined payoff (non-coop) 1,200 1,100 800 Gains from Coop 0 100 400 E payoff (coop) 1,000 800 + ½850 (100) 500 + ½ (400) 700 L payoff (coop) 200 300 + ½350 (100) 300 + ½ (400) 500 Combined 1,200 1,200 1,200 42 Comparing injunctions to damages… Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer No need for court to calculate amount of harm done 43 Comparing injunctions to damages… Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer No need for court to calculate amount of harm done Damages are generally more efficient when private bargaining is impossible Three possibilities: injurer prevents harm, injuree prevents harm, nobody prevents harm (someone pays for it) Efficiency: cheapest of the three Damages: injurer can prevent harm or pay for it; injurer chooses whichever is cheapest Injunction: injurer can only prevent harm 44 So now we know… Any rule leads to efficient outcomes when TC are low Injunctions are cheaper to implement Damages lead to more efficient outcomes when TC high Leads Calabresi and Melamed to the following conclusion: When transaction costs are low, a property rule (injunctive relief) is more efficient When transaction costs are high, a liability rule (damages) is more efficient 45 High transaction costs damages Low transaction costs injunctive relief “Private bargaining is unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed strangers because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior is likely to occur. Large numbers of land owners are typically affected by nuisances, such as air pollution or the stench from a feedlot. In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy. On the other hand, property disputes generally involve a small number of parties who live near each other and can monitor each others’ behavior easily after reaching a deal; so injunctive relief is usually used in these cases.” (Cooter and Ulen) 46 A different view of the high-transaction-costs case… “When transaction costs preclude bargaining, the court should protect a right by an injunctive remedy if it knows which party values the right relatively more and it does not know how much either party values it absolutely. Conversely, the court should protect a right by a damages remedy if it knows how much one of the parties values the right absolutely and it does not know which party values it relatively more.” (Cooter and Ulen) 47 Low transaction costs injunctive relief Cheaper for the court to administer With low transaction costs, we expect parties to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently But… do they really? Ward Farnsworth (1999), Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain After Judgment? A Glimpse Inside The Cathedral 20 nuisance cases: no bargaining after judgment “In almost every case the lawyers said that acrimony between the parties was an important obstacle to bargaining… Frequently the parties were not on speaking terms... …The second recurring obstacle involves the parties’ disinclination to think of the rights at stake… as readily commensurable with cash.” 48 Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable Allocative externalities (enriched uranium) 49 Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable Allocative externalities (enriched uranium) “Indirect” externalities (human organs) 50 Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable Allocative externalities (enriched uranium) “Indirect” externalities (human organs) Paternalism source: http://www.shanghaidaily.com/nsp/ National/2011/06/02/Boy%2Bregrets%2Bselling %2Bhis%2Bkidney%2Bto%2Bbuy%2BiPad/ 51 (we’ll probably end here) 52 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? 53 what can be privately owned? what can an owner do? how are property rights established? what remedies are given? 54 What can an owner do with his property? Principle of maximum liberty Owners can do whatever they like with their property, provided it does not interfere with other’ property or rights That is, you can do anything you like so long as it doesn’t impose an externality (nuisance) on anyone else 55 So, what does an efficient property law system look like? What things can be privately owned? Private goods are privately owned, public goods are publicly provided What can owners do with their property? Maximum liberty How are property rights established? (Examples to come) What remedies are given? Injunctions when transaction costs are low; damages when transaction costs are high 56