CHESAPEAKE BAY COMMERCIAL FISHING BENEFITS ANALYSIS Steve Newbold U.S. Environmental Protection Agency National Center for Environmental Economics October 2011 National Center for Environmental Economics 1 OUTLINE 1. Key economic concepts for fishery benefits estimation – Consumer and producer surplus, common pool resources, rent dissipation 2. Major Chesapeake Bay fisheries 3. Proposed modeling approach – Bioeconomic framework: EwE/Atlantis + harvester response functions for each stock – Deacon et al. (2011), illustrative example 4. Data needs and modeling challenges National Center for Environmental Economics 2 KEY CONCEPTS • Producers of commercially harvested fish will benefit from the TMDL to the degree that the fish stocks they target become more abundant and therefore easier to catch. • Consumers of commercially harvested fish will benefit from the TMDL to the degree that the lower harvesting costs are passed on in the form of lower prices of fish at the market. • To estimate benefits in the commercial fishing sector, we need data on prices and quantities of harvested fish with and without the TMDL. National Center for Environmental Economics 3 KEY CONCEPTS • Economic benefits = WTP = consumer + producer surplus change National Center for Environmental Economics 4 KEY CONCEPTS • Fish stocks are common pool resources • “Tragedy of the commons”: with no restrictions on harvesting the stock will be over-exploited and all rents dissipated (Gordon 1954, Scott 1955) • Large literature on fishery economics that examine alternative management approaches (Wilen 1999) • Fisheries managed by catch shares less likely to collapse (Costello et al. 2008) • Slope of supply curve, and therefore benefits of water quality improvements, will depend on the nature of the management regime (Freeman 1991) National Center for Environmental Economics 5 MAJOR FISHERIES IN CHES. BAY CHESAPEAKE BAY Avg. landings and revenues 200-2009 "Fisheries Ecosystem Planning for Chesapeake Bay," 2006 Relative Relative abundance exploitation MT $/MT Revenue Cum. % % of Atl. rev. Blue crab 24128 2085 50542512 49 54 low over Atlantic menhaden 178591 139 24824149 74 85 medium full Striped bass 1965 3849 7563285 81 56 high limited Atlantic croaker 5425 875 4746875 86 55 high medium Eastern oyster 367 11665 4281055 90 22 low over Summer flounder 1324 3077 4073948 94 17 medium over Blue crab (peelers) 650.7 4887.55 3387422 97 57 low over Black sea bass 299 5737 1715363 99 25 low over Weakfish 290 1808 524320 99 26 high low Horseshoe crab 238 967 230146 99 27 not est. unknown Bluefish 293 639 187227 100 7 low over Spanish mackerel 51 2029 103479 100 4 moderate full Blue crab (soft) 12 7980 100983 100 3 low over Black drum 32 2368 75776 100 56 not est. unknown American shad 39 1467 57213 100 7 low low Spotted sea trout 13 3155 41015 100 9 not est. unknown Tautog 7.1 3182 22592 100 4 low over Red drum 2.5 2747 6868 100 3 not est. over National Center for Environmental Economics 6 PREVIOUS STUDIES - GENERAL • Clark (1990)—“Bible” of bioeconomic modeling • Homans and Wilen (1997)—estimated a model of a regulated open access fishery • Lipton and Hicks (2003)—DO and striped bass recreational fishery in the Chesapeake Bay • Massey et al. (2006)—water quality and summer flounder recreational fishery in MD coastal bays • Finnoff and Tschirhart (2008)—general equilibrium bioeconomic model of an 8-species ecosystem • Smith and Crowder (2011)—transitional rents from N reductions in open access blue crab fishery • Deacon et al. (2011)—calibrated model of capacity constrained fishery National Center for Environmental Economics 7 PREVIOUS STUDIES – CHES. BAY • Kahn and Kemp (1985)—fishery support by SAV in Chesapeake Bay • Anderson (1989)—seagrass and blue crabs in VA • Lipton and Hicks – DO and recreational catch of striped bass in the Chesapeake Bay • Mistiaen et al. (2003)—low DO and blue crabs in tributaries of Chesapeake Bay • Sanchirico et al. (2006)—ecosystem management of Chesapeake Bay fisheries • Kar and Chakraborty (2009)—bioeconomic model of Chesapeake Bay oyster fishery National Center for Environmental Economics 8 OUR TASK • We want to develop a general but relatively simple framework that can be applied to multiple species parameterized using readily available fishery statistics and results from previous studies • Must represent management constraints and the incentive structure these constraints provide to the harvesters • Integrate harvester and manager response functions with biological production functions to form a multispecies bioeconomic model National Center for Environmental Economics 9 PROPOSED APPROACH Estimate (as in Homans and Wilen 1997) or calibrate (as in Deacon et al. (2011) a fishing effort production function for each stock for integration with EwE and/or Atlantis: • Fishing mortality rate: 1 b F = q éêaL + (1 - a )K ù ú ë û b b F é1 - e - (F + M )T ù ú û F + M êë • Harvest: H= A • Profits (rents): P = pH - wLT - rK • Biological dynamics: At + 1 = g ( A t - H t , Q ) ( EwE / Atlantis ) National Center for Environmental Economics 10 PROPOSED APPROACH Can represent a range of management regimes: • Open access: K increases until profits = 0 • Regulated open access (e.g., TAC): regulator closes season ( limits T ) to ensure H £ Hˆ , but with no limit on entry K still increases until profits = 0. • Capacity constrained: K restricted to ensure sH £ Hˆ . Other inputs may expand but unless they are perfect substitutes for K then profits > 0 • Optimal management: K and L chosen to maximize profits National Center for Environmental Economics 11 DEMAND MODEL • Multistage Demand Model – Allocates household income to expenditure categories – Captures substitution between different commodities and harvests from different estuaries • Changes in consumer welfare – Demand is a function of • • • • Income (total expenditures) Prices of Chesapeake harvest Prices for harvest from other regions Price indices for other commodities – Expenditure function is used with projections of income and prices to estimate changes in consumer surplus National Center for Environmental Economics 12 ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE Consider the mythological fish “Atlantic henmaden” (similar to Atlantic menhaden, but not quite the same) • 2 life stages, B-H stock-recruitment function • Take α and M from pervious fisheries biology studies • Set H, F, p to match recent levels for Atl. menhaden • Calibrate β assuming steady-state conditions • Assume w =$40K /yr, K = 20, L = 1000, assume open access to calibrate r, guess b = -2, and calibrate a assuming cost minimization, price elasticity ¶¶ Hp Hp = -0.3 • Suppose TMDL will increase α and β by 10%, decrease M by 5% (increase eq. A by 27%) National Center for Environmental Economics 13 ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLE Benefits depend on the management regime: Open Access Optimal management Regulated open access Capacity constrained Base TMDL Base TMDL Base TMDL Base TMDL A [109 fish] 2.78 2.99 4.21 4.94 4.32 5.06 3.80 4.29 K [vessels] 28 36 11 13 24 35 14 18 L [laborers] 1196 1466 536 654 1568 2373 783 1017 F [yr-1] 0.74 0.94 0.30 0.36 0.70 1.02 0.39 0.51 1 1 1 1 0.39 0.33 1 1 H [10- fish] 11.9 15.1 8.7 12.2 9.4 13.5 10.0 14.0 P [107 $/yr] 0 0 7.9 12.8 0 0 7.3 11.7 T [yr/yr] PS [107 $/yr] 0 4.94 0 4.33 CS [107 $/yr] 2.4 2.7 3.2 3.1 National Center for Environmental Economics ≈ $25-75 million / yr 14 THE MOST IMPORTANT SLIDE Data needs & modeling challenges 1. Data on H and p from NOAA’s comm. fishery stats 2. K and L (& w?) from vessel observer programs ( ? ) 3. w from BLS (by state, possibly county, probably not by stock) 4. How to obtain data on r? (calibrate if open access) 5. How to estimate, calibrate, or transfer b? 6. How to characterize existing and future management regimes in each fishery? 7. How to handle spillover effects due to fish migrations? (Massey et al. 2006) National Center for Environmental Economics 15