Mergers efficiencies and the failing firm defence – a change of emphasis – panel discussion
Efficiencies
●
General framework
●
Efficiencies are hard to demonstrate
●
Types of efficiencies and a few (!) case examples
-
Supply side efficiencies
-
Demand-side efficiencies
-
Dynamic efficiencies?
●
Difference between efficiencies and relevant customer benefits
Exiting firm scenario
●
General framework
●
Evidential hurdles and challenges
●
Case study – Kingfisher/Focus
Falling short of the exiting firm scenario – space for flailing firm arguments?
●
Efficiencies can enhance rivalry so that a merger does not give rise to an SLC
●
The OFT must be satisfied (or CC must expect) that
-
The efficiencies are timely, likely and sufficient to prevent an SLC from arising
-
The efficiencies are merger specific
●
To negate an SLC efficiencies must be rivalry enhancing so that there is no substantial ‘net’ loss of competition
-
It should be possible to weigh them directly against other factors that might make an SLC likely – so they should directly impact competition
-
Efficiencies that are not rivalry enhancing would not negate an SLC but can be assessed as Relevant Customer Benefits and may give rise to an exception to duty to refer (as explained later)
●
In practice the evidentiary standard for efficiencies is high
-
Most of information concerning efficiencies is held by merging firms and can often be difficult for the Authorities to market test
-
It can be difficult to weigh up whether efficiencies are sufficient to negate an SLC or outweigh it
-
Merging parties may often be discouraged from submitting detailed arguments and evidence on efficiencies
●
But firms should assess whether they have a plausible case for efficiencies because they can be quantified and verified and may potentially negate an SLC
-
For example, Asda/Netto (the OFT took account of the evidence on efficiencies, although it did not change the overall number of local SLCs in the case)
-
Marginal SLC finding in some cases can reduce the overall burden the efficiency argument must meet to overcome such concerns
●
Supply-side efficiencies
-
Cost reductions
-
Product repositioning
●
Demand-side efficiencies
-
Network effects
-
Pricing effects
-
Efficiencies in vertical mergers
●
Dynamic efficiencies?
-
Combining complementary distribution or marketing assets
-
Economies of scale and scope in R&D
-
Upgrading management
●
Merger may lead to economies of scale or scope or reductions in variable costs, for example, the merged firm may benefit from more efficient production processes or working methods of one of the merger firms
●
Challenges:
-
Can be difficult to demonstrate that reductions in fixed costs would be passed on, ultimately to consumers
-
Best approach is to seek to ascertain evidence on variable cost reductions and weight these up against an SLC. The challenge is twofold: forward looking data, held by the merging parties and therefore can be difficult to test and verify assumptions and conclusions.
●
Sources of verification do exist. For example, where benchmarking across the merging firms is possible (e.g. where one firm has access to cheaper inputs)
●
Case example: Asda/Netto. Merger of two a major grocery store and a so-called
‘local assortment discounter’ with both parties operating across the UK.
●
Parties submitted that merger would result in significant efficiency gains due to
higher purchasing volumes
variable cost savings with some suppliers due to consolidation of distribution chain into one destination
●
Evidence consisted of Asda’s existing internal analysis based on past experience
(not specifically produced for merger) as well as existing purchasing conditions.
●
To the extent possible, the OFT took account of this evidence on efficiencies.
However, it was not sufficiently compelling to negate an SLC finding at a local level and had no impact on the overall number of local SLCs in this case.
●
Mergers of producers of differentiated products may result in product repositioning of the merged firm and its rivals. Can increase variety, but price effect ambiguous.
●
Likely to generally be very difficult to establish product repositioning efficiencies in practice. However…
●
Case example: Global/GCap . OFT accepted evidence on demand side efficiencies partly from product repositioning and product complementarities (products were to some extent complements rather than substitutes; a particular set of circumstances applied).
-
Efficiencies ‘tipped the balance’ in relation to campaigns in Greater London, where a very marginal SLC was found. In other areas, SLCs were stronger and evidence on efficiencies less compelling.
●
Removal of double marginalisation
-
Vertical mergers may allow the merged firm to internalise any pre-existing double mark-ups.
-
Double marginalisation must be significant pre-merger (this may not be the case, e.g., if pre-merger vertical supply agreements include a price mechanism which eliminates the mark-up on the input).
-
Useful evidence: data on pre-merger mark-ups, vertical supply agreements.
●
Solving the investment hold-up problem
-
Efficiencies may result from aligning the incentives within the merged firm to invest in, for example, new products, new processes or marketing (for example, a retailer may be reluctant to invest in promoting certain products if its investment may also benefit competing retailers).
-
Useful evidence: verifiable facts for hold-up problem (incentives of merging parties pre- and post-merger).
●
Network effects
-
Whether direct or indirect, may arise when services are provided over a network or through a platform, where customers value the network or platform more highly when it is used by a greater number of other customers. Useful evidence: customer valuation of network effects.
-
Case example: Digital Property Group/Zoopla. As part of assessment of unilateral effects, OFT placed some weight on the argument that merged entity would provide a stronger constraint on Rightmove than the parties were able to premerger. Efficiencies provided further weight to the overall arguments for clearance.
Support from third party evidence.
●
Pricing effects/Cournot effect
-
May lead to product bundles at a lower combined price (bundling); similar effect to double marginalisation in vertical mergers. Useful evidence: pricing models for bundle offers; quantification of customer incentives.
-
Accepted in Global/Gcap in relation to campaigns in Greater London (a marginal
SLC) .
●
One-stop shopping
-
A type of economy of scope, from the demand side. Useful evidence: quantification of customer incentives; examples of industry practice.
Examples of dynamic efficiencies
●
Combining complementary distribution or marketing assets
-
BSkyB/Easynet Group : merger facilitates a (more rapid) provision of triple play services in competition with other providers. Efficiencies provided further weight to the overall arguments for clearance.
●
Economies of scale and scope in R&D
-
Limagrain/Advanta European Seed Business : the OFT noted that combining the two breeding programmes will increase the merged parties’ chances of developing better varieties. Efficiencies provided further weight to the overall arguments for clearance.
●
Upgrading management
-
Superior management team replaces target company‘s inferior team making possible a sustained improvement in performance.
●
Uncertainty
-
Dynamic efficiencies are generally more uncertain than static efficiencies, particularly R&D
●
Timing
-
Dynamic efficiencies might require several years to materialize
●
Measuring Innovation
-
R&D spending is not necessarily a good proxy for innovation as some
R&D spending might be far more productive than other
●
Information asymmetry
-
Authorities often have to rely exclusively on information provided by the merging parties
●
A given efficiency may potentially be relevant either as a means of preventing an SLC from occurring (rivalry-enhancing efficiencies) or as an
RCB
●
At Phase 1, RCBs operate as a potential exception to the duty to refer
-
The OFT will have regard to the benefits of a Phase 2 investigation, including the possibility of remedies being obtained that preserve any RCBs
-
RCBs must outweigh the SLC and the adverse effects of the SLC in all affected markets
●
At Phase 2, RCBs are considered once the existence of an SLC is determined, by considering the extent to which alternative remedies may preserve such benefits
●
RCBs are limited by s.30(1) EA to benefits in the form of:
lower prices, higher quality or greater choice of goods or services in any market in the United Kingdom, or
greater innovation in relation to such goods or services
●
RCBs must be accrued to any customers (not just final consumers) within a reasonable period from the merger, and would be unlikely to accrue without the merger or a similar lessening of competition
●
The application of the SLC test involves a comparison of the merger scenario against the competitive situation without the merger
(counterfactual analysis).
●
Alternative counterfactuals may be used at Phase 1, where the prospect of prevailing (pre-merger) conditions continuing is not realistic. In practice, the use of alternative counterfactuals at Phase 1 is rare.
●
Phase 2 may allow for additional detailed investigation of alternative counterfactuals. However, only developments that are likely and foreseeable on the basis of the facts available can be considered.
●
The exiting firm scenario is often raised by merger parties. Three limbs need to be met:
-
Exit inevitable
-
No less anticompetitive purchasers
-
Sales go to the other merging party
●
Limb 1 - Would the firm have exited?
-
The inevitability of exit must be established for the exiting firm scenario to be considered at Phase 1. A more nuanced analysis possible at Phase 2.
-
Firms failing financially are the classic case. Change in corporate strategy
(including divestment of a branch or subsidiary) may also be considered, but the inevitability of exit is often difficult prove.
-
Evidence that has not been prepared in contemplation of the merger (e.g. exit plans, balance sheets) is particularly important.
●
Limb 2 - Would there have been an alternative purchaser for the firm or its assets?
-
Challenges for parties to demonstrate that all plausible purchasers have been approached.
-
Unwillingness of alternative purchasers to pay the seller the asking purchase price would not rule out a counterfactual with an alternative purchaser.
●
Limb 3 - What would have happened to the sales of the exiting firm?
-
Paradoxically, an easy test to meet in merger to monopoly cases!
Kingfisher/ Focus
●
Acquisition by Kingfisher plc, the parent company of B&Q, of 30 former Focus
DIY stores.
●
Focus went into administration on 5 May 2011. OFT decision announced on 7
July 2011.
●
Potential SLC finding in 10 local areas – but was an alternative counterfactual to the prevailing conditions of competition appropriate?
●
Discussions held with the administrator, investment bankers, Focus' former senior management and its owners, possible purchasers and other relevant parties.
●
OFT concluded that that there was no alternative purchaser which would result in a less anti-competitive outcome.
●
The OFT completed its investigation 19 working days , rather than the usual 40 working days. Prompt replies from third parties, OFT experience in retail mergers and targeting the investigation on the core issues were key.
●
In certain exceptional circumstances, as part of the overall SLC analysis, the fact that a firm may not continue to be a rivalrous force in a market, absent the merger, can, taken in combination with other factors, mitigate competition concerns. This is rare.
●
Potential examples of this being a feature of cases include:
-
2 Sisters Food Group/Vion Poultry
-
University College London Hospitals (UCLH)/Royal Free London neurosurgery services
-
Imerys Minerals/Kaolin business of Goonvean
Guidance
●
OFT1254/CC2, Merger assessment guidelines (September 2010)
( http://www.oft.gov.uk/shared_oft/mergers/642749/OFT1254.pdf
)
See in particular Sections 4.3 (The ‘counterfactual’) and (5.7 (efficiencies)
●
OFT1122, Mergers: Exceptions to the duty to refer and undertakings in lieu of reference guidance ( http://www.oft.gov.uk/shared_oft/mergers/Consultations/oft1122.pdf
)
See in particular Section 4 (Relevant Customer Benefits)
● CMA2, Mergers: Guidance on the CMA’s jurisdiction and procedure (January 2014)
( https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/270256/CMA
2_Mergers_Guidance.pdf
)
Cases
●
Limagrain/Advanta European Seed Business (OFT 2005) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2005/limagrain
●
BSkyB/Easynet Group (OFT 2005) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2005/bskyb
●
Global/GCap (OFT 2008) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2008/globalradio http://www.oft.gov.uk/news-and-updates/press/2008/95-08
●
Asda/Netto (OFT 2010) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/Mergers_Cases/2010/Asda3
●
Kingfisher/Focus (OFT 2011) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2011/kingfisher http://www.oft.gov.uk/news-and-updates/press/2011/78-11
●
Digital Property Group/Zoopla (OFT 2012) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2012/digital
●
University College London Hospitals (UCLH)/Royal Free London neurosurgery
services (OFT 2013) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2013/ucl-hospitals
●
Imerys Minerals/Kaolin business of Goonvean (OFT 2013) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/decisions/2013/imerys-minerals
●
2 Sisters Food Group/Vion Poultry (OFT 2013) http://www.oft.gov.uk/OFTwork/mergers/Mergers_Cases/2013/2Sisters
Mergers efficiencies and the failing firm defence – a change of emphasis – panel discussion