REVIEWS The demographic transition: are we any closer to an evolutionary explanation? Monique Borgerhoff Mulder D emographic transitions The radical shift in human reproduction in reflects historical demographers’ normally entail two feathe late 19th century, known as the recognition that the 19th century tures. First, there is a radidemographic transition, constitutes a fertility decline coincided with two cal decline in the number major challenge to evolutionary processes: the devaluation of child of offspring that parents produce, approaches to human behaviour. labour in cottage industry and its despite overall increases in the Why would people ever choose to limit banning in factories, and the growavailability of resources1. This is their reproduction voluntarily when, at the ing benefits associated with the particularly true of the 19th cenpeak of the Industrial Revolution, education of children for employtury European transition, where resources were apparently so plentiful? ment in an increasingly competitive marital fertility halved in less than Can the transition be attributed to open-market economy11. It is also 30 years in some countries (Fig. 1), standard life history tradeoffs, is it a linked to the observation that parbut also characterizes some 20th consequence of cultural evolutionary ents in land-limited agrarian comcentury transitions in the develprocesses, or is it simply a maladaptive munities selectively abandoned oping world, such as in Thailand2. outcome of novel and environmental later-born sons to reduce the numSecond, rich (and often aristo- social conditions? Empirical analyses and ber of potential inheritance claims cratic) families reduce their fertility new models suggest that reproductive on the estate12, thereby avoiding earlier, and often more markedly, decision making might be driven by a impoverishment and loss of family than the rest of the population3, human psychology designed by natural rank. This hypothesis poses the such that the positive correlations selection to maximize material wealth. quantity and/or quality trade-off commonly found between wealth If this is the case, the mechanisms (first pioneered for clutch size and fertility in predemographic governing fertility and parental investment variation by Lack6) that has strucpopulations disappear: censuses are likely to respond to modern conditions tured much subsequent thinking from England and Wales in 1911 with a fertility level much lower than that in life history analysis, including (Ref. 4) demonstrate this point that would maximize fitness. work on humans13,14. (Table 1). Attractive as this hypothesis The fact that people in an is, it has no direct support. Kaplan Monique Borgerhoff Mulder is at the increasing number of societies et al. tested its central prediction Dept of Anthropology, University of California at Davis, that the number of grandchildren worldwide voluntarily reproduce Davis, CA 95616, USA at lower levels than would apparwould peak at an intermediate level (mborgerhoffmulder@ucdavis.edu). ently maximize their lifetime reproof fertility15. Using data on conduction poses a major challenge temporary men in the state of New to evolutionary anthropologists. Mexico (USA), they did not find a Indeed, the sociologist Daniel Vining identified this puzzling curvilinear relationship (Fig. 2). Indeed, although it is well trend as the ultimate challenge to evolutionary approaches known that higher parental fertility in modern societies is to human behaviour4. In some senses, this view is naive: linked to lower investment in individual children, the low many social scientists fail to appreciate that natural selec- income of children from large families does not decrease tion favours different optimal allocations of effort to repro- their fertility. In short, although birth rates can respond alduction in different ecological and social environments and most instantaneously to changes in the costs of children hence that lower-than-maximum levels of fertility might be (such as was seen in the precipitous decrease in fertility in optimal. Nevertheless, behavioural ecologists are puzzled East Germany once state benefits contingent on children by the dramatic nature of the decline. They are also deeply were withdrawn at reunification16), the overall fitness benpuzzled by the emerging negative correlations between efits of such adjustments remain elusive. wealth and reproduction, when evidence that the wealthy Until recently, attempts to support this hypothesis analytioutreproduce the poor is so prevalent in predemographic cally have also failed. Investigators modelling the competitransition populations5. Consequently, a range of hypoth- tive environments in which high levels of parental investeses are now being explored to explain why parents with ac- ment are critical to offspring success have been unable to cess to plentiful resources choose low fertility rates (Box 1). simulate the classic features of demographic transitions17. Although they can show that low fertility is favoured when Three hypotheses for demographic transition the costs of raising children are high18 and when the effects In the first hypothesis, evolutionary anthropologists sug- of parental investment on offspring quality diminish slowly19, gest that, in modern societies, lowered fertility rates are they cannot simulate situations in which high-income groups optimal (with respect to fitness) because of the competitive maximize their fitness by producing fewer offspring than environment in which offspring are raised – a world in which low-income groups17,20. The failure of both empiricists and high levels of parental investment are critical to a child’s modellers to support Lack’s hypothesis is disappointing, as success9 and costly to the parent10. This hypothesis closely it had seemed such a good candidate. 266 Copyright © 1998, Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. 0169-5347/98/$19.00 PII: S0169-5347(98)01357-3 TREE vol. 13, no. 7 July 1998 REVIEWS Enter evolutionary psychology Perhaps because of difficulties with each of these hypotheses, attention has turned recently to the psychological TREE vol. 13, no. 7 July 1998 0.9 Belgium Netherlands 0.8 Bulgaria 0.7 Russia Index of marital fertility (Ig) The second hypothesis (Box 1) is that lowered rates of fertility are a consequence of darwinian, but nongenetic, mechanisms of inheritance. This view stems from the recognition that, as a result of cultural evolutionary processes, not all human traits and institutions need to be seen as serving individual reproductive interests8. The argument is that traits that do not necessarily enhance genetic fitness can spread through a population as a result of imitation, especially if these traits are expressed by people who are otherwise very successful. Because, in a competitive market economy, childless individuals (or people with fewer than the average number of children) are often highly successful in careers as teachers, communicators or politicians, these people serve as models for others in the population. In the model, if a suite of traits are imitated indiscriminately, low fertility might spread. Boyd and Richerson8 have used mathematical models to show how this process (which they call indirect bias) might arise through ordinary evolutionary processes if the costs associated with reaching adaptive solutions are high. This idea is intriguing. It may well account for the rapid spread of fertility-limiting behaviour through populations (as, for example, in Sweden21) and is intricately linked to the notion, now popular among demographers and social scientists, that it is changes in ideas (rather than changes in the economy) that cause fertility transitions22. However, the cultural evolutionary hypothesis poses problems. First, there is no clear reason why influential trendsetting individuals choose lower fertility in the first place. Granted, there will be trade-offs between seeking socioeconomic status and reproducing early and often. But why reproduction is sacrificed to such extremes still needs to be explained or at least raises questions about how such status-seeking becomes stable in a population where there may be countervailing selection for high fertility. Second, theorists working on cultural inheritance build their models with very different assumptions concerning the mechanisms of evolutionary processes than do behavioural ecologists. Such abandoning of the basic organic evolutionary model may still be premature, although the potential importance of such mechanisms is pointed to in newer work, outlined here. The third hypothesis (Box 1) is that low fertility is maladaptive – a by-product of changes in our environment that serves no adaptive function. The commonest cause cited here is the availability of cheap and efficient birth control methods. Thus, Perusse23 has shown that wealthier men in his Canadian sample achieve higher copulation rates than their poorer counterparts: without the availability of contraceptives, the wealthy would outreproduce their less wealthy competitors. This is an interesting finding but not a sound explanation for the demographic transition. The European transition started long before effective birth control technology was available. Furthermore, in many contemporary African nations the transition fails to occur, despite the availability of contraceptives. Finally, this perspective does not explain why some sectors of the population adopt contraceptive use before others. Most importantly, the hypothesis that low fertility is a maladaptive by-product of rapid social change is not an explanatory theory at all because it fails to specify precisely what has changed in the environment, why these changes lead to lowered fertility and even what kinds of evolved mechanisms might underlie this response15. The overall justification of an evolutionary approach is given in Box 2. Italy England Hungary 0.6 Ireland 0.5 0.4 France Spain Portugal 0.3 0.2 0.1 1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 Date Fig. 1. Index of marital fertility (Ig) in selected national populations of Europe. From Ref. 1, with permission. Table 1. Surviving children per married couple (where wife’s age exceeds 45 years) classified by social status, 1911, England and Walesa Social class Professional Lower white collar Skilled manual Semiskilled manual Unskilled Textiles Coal mining Agricultural labourers a From Surviving children per married couple 2.94 3.38 3.82 3.79 3.88 3.31 4.45 4.57 Ref. 4, with permission. mechanisms underlying reproductive behaviour. Can mechanisms be identified (and we are considering here primarily psychological mechanisms) that would have been favoured in pretransition human populations and can also account for the fertility patterns seen in modern societies? Rogers20 became interested in identifying the conditions in which material motivations might be selected over reproductive motivations, an important issue considering that consumption of material goods seems to compete with childbearing. His first model showed that, in environments where wealth is heritable, an individual’s wealth is a better predictor of the number of second and third generation descendants produced than is fertility17. Under such conditions, material motivations could be selected over pure reproductive motivations through conventional darwinian processes. Unfortunately, a more realistic diploid version of the model20 could simulate no such equilibrium. 267 REVIEWS Box 1. Evolutionary hypotheses for demographic transitions Box 2. Why an evolutionary theory of fertility transitions is required? Lowered rates are: (1) Optimal because of the competitive environment in which offspring are raised. In conditions where high levels of parental investment are critical to offspring and costly to parents, parents optimize fitness by producing a few children with high levels of investment rather than many with less investment per capita. This hypothesis implies a trade-off between offspring quantity and quality6,7. (2) A consequence of darwinian but nongenetic mechanisms of inheritance. Boyd and Richerson8 suggest that traits (such as low fertility) associated with successful individuals are preferentially imitated by others in the population. Indiscriminate imitation of the traits of successful models might evolve through ordinary organic adaptive processes if the costs to an individual reaching the local optimal value for traits through experimentation and individual learning are high. (3) A maladaptive by-product of rapid environmental change that has no adaptive value. Owing to the radical changes in the social, economic, political and ecological conditions that modern humans now experience, evolved mechanisms (either psychological or physiological) no longer generate appropriate responses to external conditions. As a result, maladaptive levels of fertility are observed. A theory of fertility should specify what causes both the overall reduction in fertility and the observed relationships between independent variables (such as wealth) and fertility. It must also account for why these changes produce a demographic transition on the basis of a broader model of fertility determinants. Demography, as a discipline, has little theory of its own; accordingly, Keyfitz24 observes that demography ‘has withdrawn from its borders and left a no-man’s land which other disciplines have infiltrated’. Evolutionary theory is one such intruder25. Another is economics, but recent overviews suggest that economic theories of fertility suffer from several conceptual weaknesses. Most notably, demand-orientated models (‘how many children do people want?’) are poorly linked to broader explanations for why humans behave as they do26. So what can evolutionary theory offer? Most fundamentally, it provides a justification for why organisms, including humans, are designed by natural selection to maximize fitness – economics offers no such causal closure. As regards fertility, models can be formulated of how fertility is likely to be affected by extrinsic features of the environment, in conjunction with evolved physiological and psychological mechanisms25,27; this work is often informed by work on other species28. Although it is increasingly recognized that not all aspects of human behaviour can be characterized as adaptations, variability in fertility is one trait for which simple adaptive models are likely to be valuable, at least as a starting point [Box 1 (1)], because fertility differentials are so exposed to selection. Where such models fail, evolutionary, but less explicitly adaptationist, perspectives are being investigated [Box 1 (2), (3)]. 90 80 Grandchildren 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 Father's children 14 16 18 20 Fig. 2. The relationship between the fertility of Albuquerque men (number of offspring produced) and their production of grandchildren. If the number of grandchildren peaks at an intermediate level of fertility (as in a tradeoff model), a second order polynomial regression should yield a positive linear term and a negative squared term. No such effect is found. The model (reduced to include only significant effects) shows that the number of children produced is by far the strongest predictor of variation in the numbers of grandchildren produced. In other words, men with the most children have the highest number of third generation descendants, contrasting sharply with the observed modal fertility of two children in this population. From Ref. 15, with permission. Kaplan also focuses on psychological mechanisms25. He retains the assumption that, as in all organisms, human fertility is the outcome of an allocation decision between the number and the quality of offspring and, therefore, a function of the effects of resources on reproductive success. However, because optimizing fertility relative to the impact of parental investment on the reproductive outcomes of the next generation is such a difficult problem to solve, simple decision making rules (‘rules of thumb’) could have evolved15. Specifically, psychological mechanisms might have been designed by natural selection to maximize the sum of the energetic resources stored by individuals and their descendants. Kaplan and Lancaster are starting to test elements of this model using empirical data from their sample of contemporary New Mexico men, with considerable success29. 268 But what about pretransition societies? Social anthropologists and historical demographers commonly argue that parents exhibit fertility schedules that serve to protect the integrity of a family’s material property. For example, primogeniture and unigeniture (whereby the complete inheritance is given to the first or last born son, respectively) have long been interpreted as strategies for preventing impoverishment and loss of family rank, and infanticide has been interpreted as a means of shaping appropriate sets of heirs30,31. However, in highly pronatal communities, such as many parts of contemporary Africa (and indeed most pre-transition populations), it is generally assumed that people have as many children as they can (or at least as many as women can subject to the trade-off between offspring survival and interbirth interval13). A recent collaborative project uses empirical data to explore whether reproductive or material motivations better predict the marital and reproductive decisions of men in a highly pronatal Kenyan Kipsigis community32. The results (Box 3) show that material motivation is pre-eminent, even though no obvious heir-shaping strategies are evident in this society. In summary, there are now intriguing arguments and scattered seeds of evidence that a highly materialistic human psyche might be evolutionarily stable and deeply rooted in our past, and not just an aberrant outcome of modern society. Closing in on an explanation So why, within societies, do richer people have fewer children? Several studies are closing in on an explanation for this second puzzle posed by the demographic transition. Assuming there is a general human psychology designed to maximize the sum of the incomes of all descendants produced, Kaplan et al. argue that rich, highly skilled parents have fewer children than poorer, less skilled parents because the time and resources the former put into their offspring are intrinsically more valuable (i.e. produce more skills) than the time and resources invested by the latter15,25. It is widely recognized that the rate at which a child learns depends on the knowledge and skills that it already possesses. If such a nonlinear effect is real, then the opportunity TREE vol. 13, no. 7 July 1998 REVIEWS Conclusion The demographic transition that has, or is, affecting so many parts of the world is a highly complex phenomenon with no single form and no common set of causes36. At least two phenomena need to be explained: the reduced levels of fertility despite relative material plenty; and the erosion of the widespread correlations between resources and fertility characterizing predemographic transition populations. The contribution of behavioural ecology to this perplexing issue consists of disentangling the notion of ‘the transition’ and tackling its various components with appropriate theory. Although rapid declines in fertility may ultimately prove to be a maladaptive by-product of massive changes in the market place (because no data currently attest to long-term fitness payoffs), our explanations increasingly specify precisely what has changed in the environment and what kinds of evolved mechanisms might underlie this phenomenon. More broadly, these developments point to how evolutionary psychology, behavioural ecology and cultural inheritance models – three approaches once characterized as mutually incompatible – each stand poised to contribute to an evolutionary explanation for the complexities of human behaviour. Acknowledgements Thanks to Tim Caro, Sarah Hrdy and Eric Smith for comments and discussion, and to Alan Rogers for permission to cite an unpublished result. References 1 Coale, A.J. and Treadway, R. (1986) A summary of the changing distribution of overall fertility, marital fertility, and the proportion married in the provinces of Europe, in The Decline of Fertility in Europe (Coale, A.J. and Watkins, S.C., eds), pp. 31–181, Princeton University Press 2 Knodel, J. et al. (1982) Fertility in Thailand: Trends, Differentials, and Proximate Determinants, National Academy of Sciences 3 Livi-Bacci, M. (1986) Social-group forerunners of fertility control in Europe, in The Decline of Fertility in Europe (Coale, A.J. and Watkins, S.C., eds), pp. 182–200, Princeton University Press TREE vol. 13, no. 7 July 1998 Box 3. Dynamic state models: do Kipsigis men marry for money or love? Dynamic state models33 are increasingly used in studies of human fertility 18,34 to identify how environmental factors affect reproductive decisions. In a study of a Kenyan Kipsigis community32, a dynamic model is used to determine the precise nature of the terminal payoff (wealth or children) individual men appear to be maximizing, as judged by their life history decisions. A model was built of men’s marital careers, with the aim of predicting when they should take subsequent wives. In the model, men are characterized by different states – their capital (livestock and land), the number of their wives and the number of their children. Their economic productivity depends on their capital assets – the labour of their wife (or wives) and various stochastic factors. Net food surpluses, after family consumption, are invested in livestock. Children are born and entail costs (illnesses, education) that are met by livestock sales. Marrying a wife is costly (the bride-wealth payment) and each year every man gets the option to choose another wife (there is no divorce in the population). The analysis was in three steps. First, an array of terminal functions (or maximands) were constructed, based on differently weighted combinations of offspring and wealth-per-offspring (capturing a continuum of reproductive to material motivation). Second, using backward runs of the model33, the optimal marital career was determined for each weighting of the terminal function. This showed that, given the same initial starting conditions, men concerned with maximizing wealth per child married fewer wives than men concerned with maximizing the numbers of their children. The former also had a higher wealth threshold at which they took additional wives. The third and key step entailed comparing each set of optimal strategies (predicated on different terminal functions) with what Kipsigis men actually do. The figure shows that the best fit between the model and the observed behaviour occurs where the terminal function is heavily weighted towards accumulating a lot of wealth for each child. In other words, a Kipsigis man’s behaviour seems optimally designed to accumulate material resources over the lifespan, resources that are divided among his sons at death. 6000 5800 5600 Total SSQ costs of producing an additional child are greater among the rich than they are among the poor, driving the negative or curvilinear relationships between parental wealth and fertility noted by Vining. Mace35 models a similar process in which different strata in society optimize fitness (with different fertility levels) as a result of following different decision rules. Therefore, although wealth and fertility may be positively correlated within strata, the relationship can break down between strata. Finally, Rogers, who was until recently unable to simulate an environment in which optimal fertility decreases with wealth20, now reports that in environments in which inheritance greatly boosts an individual’s ability to earn an income (each dollar inherited generates on average two dollars of earned income) wealthy parents can attain higher long-term fitness at equilibrium than poorer parents by producing fewer children (A.R. Rogers, unpublished). In summary, the rich and skilled may produce fewer children than the poor and unskilled because different groups within a society vary in the learning trajectories of their offspring, in the effects of inherited wealth on earning power, and in wealth. This outcome arises purely from mechanisms shaped by ordinary adaptive processes. Furthermore, once such fertility reductions appear among the rich, they can potentially spread to other social classes, even if the appropriate conditions do not exist in these groups, by the process of indirect bias posited by cultural evolutionists [Box 1 (2)]. 5400 5200 5000 4800 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Gamma The total sum of squares (total SSQ) measures the error between the optimal strategy predicated on a particular terminal function and the observed behaviour of real men. The terminal function (gamma) represents the conflicting ‘motivation’ to maximize children (gamma = 0) or wealth per child (gamma = 1). The values of gamma are shown by filled circles and the line is interpolated for ease of viewing. Results proved robust to sensitivity analyses. From Ref. 32, with permission. 4 Vining, D.R. (1986) Social versus reproductive success – the central theoretical problem of human sociobiology, Behav. Brain Sci. 9, 167–260 5 Cronk, L. (1991) Wealth, status and reproductive success among the Mukogodo, Am. Anthropol. 93, 345–360 6 Lack, D. (1947) The significance of clutch size, Ibis 89, 302–352 7 Smith, C.C. and Fretwell, S.D. (1974) The optimal balance between size and number of offspring, Am. Nat. 108, 499–506 8 Boyd, R. and Richerson, P.J. (1985) Culture and the Evolutionary Process, University of Chicago Press 269 REVIEWS 9 Irons, W.G. (1983) Human female reproductive strategies, in Social Behavior of Female Vertebrates (Wasser, S.K., ed.), pp. 169–213, Academic Press 10 Turke, P. (1989) Evolution and the demand for children, Popul. Dev. Rev. 15, 61–90 11 Lesthaeghe, R. and Wilson, C. (1986) Modes of production, secularization, and the pace of fertility decline in Western Europe, 1870–1930, in The Decline of Fertility in Europe (Coale, A.J. and Watkins, S.C., eds), pp. 261–292, Princeton University Press 12 Voland, E. and Dunbar, R. (1995) Resource competition and reproduction: the relationship between economic and parental strategies in the Krummhorn population (1720–1874), Hum. Nat. 6, 33–49 13 Blurton Jones, N. (1987) Bushman birth spacing: direct tests of some simple predictions, Ethol. Sociobiol. 8, 183–203 14 Hill, K. and Hurtado, A.M. (1996) Ache Life History, Aldine de Gruyter 15 Kaplan, H.S. et al. (1995) Fertility and fitness among Albuquerque men: a competitive labour market theory, in Human Reproductive Decisions (Dunbar, R.I.M., ed.), pp. 96–136, St Martin’s Press 16 Conrad, C., Lechner, M. and Werner, W. (1996) East German fertility after unification: crisis or adaptation, Popul. Dev. Rev. 22, 331–358 17 Rogers, A.R. (1990) The evolutionary economics of human reproduction, Ethol. Sociobiol. 11, 479–495 18 Beauchamp, G. (1994) The functional analysis of human fertility decisions, Ethol. Sociobiol. 15, 31–53 19 Pennington, R. and Harpending, H. (1988) Fitness and fertility among Kalahari !Kung, Am. J. Phys. Anthropol. 77, 202–319 20 Rogers, A.R. (1995) For love or money: the evolution of reproductive and material motivations, in Human Reproductive Decisions (Dunbar, R.I.M., ed.), pp. 76–95, St Martin’s Press 21 Carlsson, G. (1966) The decline of fertility: innovation or adjustment process, Popul. Stud. 20, 149–174 22 Watkins, S.C. (1990) From local to national communities: the transformation of demographic regimes in western Europe, 1870–1960, Popul. Dev. Rev. 16, 241–272 23 Perusse, D. (1993) Cultural and reproductive success in industrial societies: testing relationship at the proximate and ultimate levels, Behav. Brain Sci. 16, 267–322 24 Keyfitz, N. (1984) Introduction: biology and demography, in Population and Biology (Keyfitz, N., ed.), pp. 1–7, Ordina Editions 25 Kaplan, H.S. (1996) A theory of fertility and parental investment in traditional and modern human societies, Yearb. Phys. Anthropol. 39, 91–135 26 Robinson, W.C. (1997) The economic theory of fertility over three decades, Popul. Stud. 51, 63–74 27 Ellison, P.T. et al. (1993) Population variation in ovarian function, Lancet 342, 433–434 28 Wasser, S.K. (1994) Psychosocial stress and infertility, Hum. Nat. 5, 293–306 29 Kaplan, H.S. and Lancaster, J.B. The life histories of men in Albuquerque: an evolutionary–economic analysis of parental investment and fertility in modern society, in Human Behavior and Adaptation: an Anthropological Perspective (Cronk, L., Chagnon, N.A. and Irons, W., eds), Aldine de Gruyter (in press) 30 Wrigley, C. (1978) Fertility strategy for the individual and the group, in Historical Studies of Changing Fertility (Tilly, C., ed.), pp. 135–154, Princeton University Press 31 Hrdy, S.B. and Judge, D.S. (1993) Darwin and the puzzle of primogeniture, Hum. Nat. 4, 1–45 32 Luttbeg, B., Borgerhoff Mulder, M. and Mangel, M. To marry again or not? A dynamic model for demographic transition, in Human Behavior and Adaptation: an Anthropological Perspective (Cronk, L., Chagnon, N.A. and Irons, W., eds), Aldine de Gruyter (in press) 33 Mangel, M. and Clark, C.W. (1988) Dynamic Modeling in Behavioral Ecology, Princeton University Press 34 Mace, R. (1996) When to have another baby: a dynamic model of reproductive decision-making and evidence from Gabbra pastoralists, Ethol. Sociobiol. 17, 263–273 35 Mace, R. An adaptive model of human reproductive rate: why people have small families, in Human Behavior and Adaptation: an Anthropological Perspective (Cronk, L., Chagnon, N.A. and Irons, W., eds), Aldine de Gruyter (in press) 36 Low, B.S. (1994) Men in demographic transition, Hum. Nat. 5, 223–254 Molecules remodel the mammalian tree T Wilfried W. de Jong hese are exciting times for DNA sequences provide a direct record and Lagomorpha (rabbits, pikas, those who are interested in of the genealogy of extant species. etc.); Archonta, grouping Primammalian relationships. This tremendous reservoir of phylogenetic mates, Scandentia (tree shrews), Changes are rapid, and coninformation is only beginning to be Dermoptera (flying lemurs) and troversies abound. Just six years exploited. If progress in molecular Chiroptera (bats); and an ungulate ago, an influential review summaphylogeny is being made, it should be clade comprising Artiodactyla rized the state of the art in mammost conspicuous amongst mammals, (even-toed ungulates), Cetacea malian phylogeny1. Combining moras their evolution is probably the (whales), Perissodactyla (oddphological and some molecular best-studied. Indeed, surprising changes toed ungulates), the paenungulate evidence, it presented a rather well have recently been proposed for the tree orders Proboscidea (elephants), resolved tree of the 18 currently of mammalian orders. These range from Sirenia (sea cows) and Hyracoidea recognized orders of placental grouping whales with hippos, to placing (hyraxes), and the monospecific mammals (Fig. 1a). This tree incorAfrican golden moles closer to elephants order Tubulidentata (aardvark). porated the most prevalent and than to their fellow insectivores. The relationships of Insectivora dominant opinions of the time. and Carnivora with other extant Monotremata – the egg-laying Platyorders remained enigmatic, and the Wilfried de Jong is at the Dept of Biochemistry, pus and Echidna – and Marsupialia Macroscelidea (elephant shrews), University of Nijmegen, PO Box 9101, successively branch off from the Pholidota, Artiodactyla and Hyra6500 HB Nijmegen, and the Institute for Systematics main stem towards the Eutheria, coidea were considered to have and Population Biology, University of Amsterdam, the placental mammals. Edentata relatively uncertain relationships. 1090 GT Amsterdam, The Netherlands (or Xenarthra: sloths, anteaters Thus, it would appear that (w.dejong@bioch.kun.nl). and armadillos), probably together after more than a century of palewith Pholidota (pangolins), constiontological and morphological intute the sister group of all other quiry, complemented with more placental orders. Among the latter, some widely accepted recent molecular findings, progress was being made towards superordinal clades are shown: Glires, combining Rodentia a gradually growing consensus, reflected by the topology in 270 Copyright © 1998, Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved. 0169-5347/98/$19.00 PII: S0169-5347(98)01335-4 TREE vol. 13, no. 7 July 1998