1 Theme # 5: Macroeconomic policy. Part 1: Fiscal policy Introduction • Repetition of AD-AS model, fixed exchange rate. • AD-AS model for floating exchange rate regime. • Role of fiscal policy in baseline model (B&W 15.3, Short-run stabilization) Ragnar Nymoen University of Oslo, Department of Economics • Public debt (B&W 15.4 and 15.5) • Issues in demand management (B&W 16) April 22, 2004 • Supply-side (B&W 17) 2 1 2 Aggregate demand and Phillips curve (revisited) The building blocks of the AD-AS model (as given earlier in the course) Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, ρ) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, σ) SP , definition P∗ ρ = i − π̄, real interest rate M = L(Y, i), money-market P i = i∗ − se, financial market arbitrage condition π = π̄ − a(Y − Ȳ ), AS σ= In line with OEM, and unlike B&W we assume that expected appreciation is linked to the level of the exchange rate: se = se(S), s0e ≷ 0 s0e may depend both on regime (e.g., credibility of fixed exchange rate regime) and on time-horizon. fixed float short-run long-run s0e < 0 s0e = 0 0 se < 0 s0e < 0 Notation is as in B&W, except that we use se for the expected rate of appreciation and that we use ρ for the real interest rate. The arbitrage condition amounts to an assumption of perfect capital mobility: It defines S as an increasing function of i. From portfolio model, we know that a similar (but less steep) relationship holds for less than perfect capital mobility (called it Ei-curve there). 3 4 2.1 Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, S, S−1, Ȳ , P, σ−1. Fixed exchange rate a) Short-run version of the model: b) Long-run version of the model As we did in Part 3 of the course (“Inflation and the macroeconomy”) obtain the relative change of σ ∆σ = (s + π − π ∗)σ−1 and, using s = S/S−1 − 1: ∆σ = ((S/S−1 − 1) + π − π ∗)σ−1. The equilibrium is defined by Y = Ȳ , π = π̄, and σ = σ−1 Imposing this gives the long run model Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1) M = L(Y, i), P i = i∗ − se(S) Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ) P∗ P =σ , S π = π ∗, M = L(Ȳ , i) P i = i∗ − se(S). Endogenous: Y, i, M, and π. (Note: since perfect capital mobility, M cannot be sterilized) The third equation follows from the constancy of σ in equilibrium, and that S/S−1 − 1 = 0 in equilibrium. 5 6 Then write the current real exchange rate as σ = (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1. π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ ) Devaluation: Assume that the economy is initially in equilibrium. The devaluation (e.g., dS = −1) means that s0e(−1) > 0. Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i∗ − se(S) − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1) M = L(Y, i∗ − se(S)) P π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ ) Endogenous: M , i, σ, π and P . Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, Ȳ . The first equation defines an AD-curve in terms of Y and π. The slope of this curve: dπ ¯¯ 1 − CY − P CAY < 0. ¯AD,f ix,short = dY P CAσ σ−1 The slope of the short run AS curve: dπ ¯¯ ¯AS,short = a > 0 dY The AD schedule is shifted horizontally by a change in S: dY ¯¯ ¯AD,f ix,short = −Iρs0e + P CAσ σ−1/S−1 < 0, dS so a devaluation shifts the AD curve to the right. 7 8 2.2 Summary of short run effects: Y % , π % , i & and M %. (The slope of the long run AD curve is steeper than the short run AD). There is however no shift in this curve since S/S−1 − 1 = 0 and s0e = 0 in the long run. Floating exchange rate a) Short-run model Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1) M = L(Y, i), P i = i∗ − se(S) π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ ) Summary: Long run effects (i.e., compared to initial equilibrium): S & (since initial increase was not reversed), P % (since σ unchanged), M %. Y and i unchanged relative to initial equilibrium. Endogenous: Y, i, S, and π. Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, M , Ȳ , P, S−1, σ−1. Money market equilibrium defines i = i( M , Y ), iM/P ≤ 0, iY ≥ 0. P 9 10 b) Long-run version of the model Foreign exchange equilibrium defines: The equilibrium is defined by M , Y ), Si∗ ≤ 0, SM/P ≤ 0, SY ≥ 0 P The float AD curve is defined by: Y = Ȳ , and π = π̄, σ = σ−1 S = S(i∗, Y = C(Ω̄, Y −T̄ )+I(q̄, i( M M , Y )−π̄)+Ḡ+P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S(i∗, , Y )/S−1+π−π ∗)σ−1) P P Slope: dπ dY ¯ 1 − CY − P CAY − IρiY − P CAσ SY σ−1/S−1 ¯ <0 ¯AD,float, short = P CAσ σ−1 meaning that the ADfloat curve is steeper than ADfix. AS curve is the same as in fix regime. 11 and s = se(S) = 0, correct expectations where s = S/S−1 − 1 (as above). Imposing this gives the long run model Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ) P∗ P =σ , S π∗ = π M = L(Ȳ , i) P i = i∗, 12 2.3 Fiscal policy in the AD-AS model Fiscal policy serves several purposes Endogenous: i, σ, π,S, and P . Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, M, π ∗, i∗, π̄, Ȳ 1. Provision of public goods and services. More compactly written 2. Redistributive goals. (Equity versus efficiency?) Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i∗ − π ∗) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ) M ∗ ∗ = L(Ȳ , i ) σ PS with σ and S as endogenous. 3. Macro-economic stabilization 3. is complementary/alternative to monetary policy, and is our main concern here Use AD-AS model as reference framework. 14 13 Vertical shift in AD curves: −1 dπ ¯¯ ¯AD,f ix,short = dḠ P CAσ σ−1 −1 dπ ¯¯ ¯AD,float,short = dḠ P CAσ σ−1 Role of capital mobility: Baseline model assumes perfect capital mobility. If we (instead) assume imperfect capital mobility we have the following modifications: Hence fiscal policy has larger effect under fixed exchange rate. 1. Only minor in float case. Why? (Money market analysis as before, and positive relationship between i and S in the foreign exchange marker (same as the downward sloping “Ei-curve” in the OEM model). Key mechanism: In a clean float regime i % in the money market leads to σ % in the market for foreign exchange. Both effects reduce the effect relative to the fixed exchange rate regime. 2. In a fixed exchange rate regime, the government might choose to control money supply, through sterilization. In that case i % also in this regime, thus reducing the expansive effect. The conclusion applies to the short run. In the long run net, exports are crowded out by increased expenditure in both regimes. 15 16 3.1 3 The budget surplus The activity corrected surplus Replace the baseline model’s assumption about exogenous taxes T̄ , with a tax-function While the rationale for modern fiscal policy is to affect the overall activity level (and thus unemployment rates), it most direct impact is on the government’s own financial situation. That side of the issue is always important, i.e., prudent governments always try to keep down/revert deficits in order to maintain financial independence (for a rainy day, and in order to maintain and strengthen the beliefs in the stability of the currency and the solvency of the government). Sometimes, government deficients become the overriding concern of financial policy, either because of past sins (large debt), or because of new political priorities. T = τY which (though exceedingly simple) is more realistic. Clearly the tax-function makes the government primary surplus T −G dependent on whether the activity level is high or low. Today a good deal of emphasis on activity correction, which would be τ Ȳ − G A much used decomposition of the budget is then τ (Y − Ȳ ) + τ Ȳ − G 18 17 3.2 In practice (more complicated computation though). Used to characterize a budget as “really” expansionary or contractive. Popular among politicians. Debt financing and debt stabilization Using B&W notation, the change in real public debt (B), is equal to the total budget deficit ∆B = G − T + rB (15.1) where r is a real interest rate. rB is referred to as “debt service”. Alternative to using model multipliers of Y wrt G to characterize the budget. Seemingly more free of assumption, but in reality just as model dependent (cf calculating the trend GDP output level Y ). Over time governments must stabilize the debt to income ratio B/Y B G − T + rB ∆( ) = Y Y Rewrite left hand side B ∆B ∆Y ∆BY − ∆Y B ∆ = = − B 2 Y Y Y Y so that (*) can be written B B ∆( ) = G − T + (r − g) Y Y 19 20 (*) (15.3) To stabilize debt at a certain level, the primary surplus T − G must equal B . “Easiest” when interest rates are low and growth is high (e.g., (r − g) Y Europe in the 1950’s and 1960s). Deficit reduction has been the way chosen by many European countries as a result of the Maastricht treaty in 1991 and the Stability and Growth Pact of 1997. Has contributed to high European unemployment, though only temporary according to AD-AS with Phillips curve. Modifications: Seigniorage and inflation tax. Down the years governments debt (in real terms!) has also been able to reduced by high inflation, which (as we have seen) takes away the gains from owing fixed income assets (bonds), hence is referred to as inflation tax. Adoption of low inflation as a target of monetary policy as greatly reduced the inflation tax. In practice, not all public debt is interest bearing. If the government finances a deficit by printing money, it obtains an interest free loan from the public. This source of “income” to the central government is called seigniorage. Without the monopoly right to printing money the government would have sell bonds and pay interest instead. The Stability pact “forbids” this form of debt financing. 22 21 4 Issues in demand management. The rationale and scope for “activist fiscal policy” is a main controversy in economics. B&W ch 16 is highly recommended. 4.1 Slope of AS schedule and adjustment lags B&W point out that the rationale for demand adjustment is larger if short-run AS curve is flat and it takes (long) time before the short sun curve “moves back” to the vertical long run position. Answer hinges on the shape of the Phillips curve (non-linearities is essential), and about how fast Here, comment only on a few of the issues covered by B&W: 1. Slope of AS schedule and adjustment lag • core inflation adjusts 2. Policy and effectiveness lags • and also how fast unemployment changes (not mentioned by B&W) towards its natural rate However, a more overriding concern is the status of the Phillips curve natural rate model itself. 3. Lucas critique 23 24 4.2 Is the long run AS curve vertical? As we have seen there are competing models of wage and price setting which refute that thesis. Aukrust/bargaining model: Inflation stabilizes at the foreign rate of inflation at “any” level of unemployment. Implying that the equilibrium level of unemployment need not coincide with the Phillips curve natural rate. Policy and effectiveness lags A very relevant caution against too ambitious demand control is related to the fact that various lags makes it difficult in practice to carry out the intention of counter cyclical fiscal policy. 1. Recognition lag (data measurement) 2. Decisions lag (political system) 3. Implementation lag (“red tape”) 4. Effectiveness lag (from change in instrument to effect in target) 26 25 4.3 5 Lucas critique No controversy that expectations are important in macroeconomics. The Lucas critique takes the extreme view that expectations are rational and that they dominate the economic decisions of households and firms. Hence impossible to predict reactions to economic policy changes on the basis of current and past behaviour (e.g., as summarized in an econometric consumption function). If valid empirically, the Lucas critique takes away the rationale for demand management. Supply-Side Policy (B&W ch 17) The important sections for our course is section 17.4. Note in particular the discussion about active and passive labour market programmes, Box. 17.5., which reflects the view that the comparatively low Nordic unemployment rates is due to active programmes. Rødseth and Nymoen (2003) find no strong evidence for the positive influence of programmes on employment, and at the same time report that demand management and devaluations have been important. Role of labour unions. However, empirical tests show that the empirical relevance of the Lucas critique is overstated. Separate handout provides shows that if bargaining is coordinated (“centralized”), union based wage setting might entail quite flexible wages (in line with Gjedrem’s talk at the start of the term). 27 28