Economic policy. Fiscal policy 1 Introduction

advertisement
1
Economic policy.
Fiscal policy
Introduction
• Baseline model (B&W ch 13). Corrects B&W floating ex-rate version of
model.
• Role of fiscal policy in baseline model (B&W 15.3, Short-run stabilization)
• Public debt (B&W 15.4 and 15.5)
Ragnar Nymoen
University of Oslo, Department of Economics
November 3, 2003
• Issues in demand management (B&W 16)
• Supply-side (B&W 17)
2
1
2
Aggregate demand and Phillips curve (revisited)
The building blocks of the AD-AS model:
Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, ρ) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, σ)
derivatives:
SP
, definition
P∗
ρ = i − π̄, real interest rate
M
= L(Y, i), money-market
P
i = i∗ − se, financial market arbitrage condition
σ=
In line with OEM, and unlike B&W we assume that expected appreciation is
linked to the level of the exchange rate:
se = se(S), s0e ≷ 0
s0e may depend both on regime (e.g., credibility of fixed exchange rate regime)
and on time-horizon.
fixed
float
short-run long-run
s0e < 0
s0e = 0
0
se < 0
s0e < 0
π = π̄ − a(Y − Ȳ ), AS
Notation is as in B&W, except that we introduce se for the expected rate
of appreciation and that we use ρ for the real interest rate. The arbitrage
condition amounts to an assumption of perfect capital mobility, as explained
in OEM.
3
4
2.1
Fixed exchange rate
b) Long-run version of the model
The equilibrium is defined by
a) Short-run version of the model:
From the definition of the real exchange rate, obtain the relative change of σ
∆σ = ((S/S−1 − 1) + π − π ∗)σ−1
where σ−1 is last periods real exchange rate. Express the current real exchange
rate as σ = (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1:
Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1)
M
= L(Y, i),
P
i = i∗ − se(S)
π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ )
Endogenous: Y, i, M, and π. (Note: since perfect capital mobility, M cannot
be sterilized)
Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, S, S−1, Ȳ , P, σ−1.
5
Y = Ȳ , π = π̄, and σ = σ−1
Imposing this gives the long run model
Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ)
P∗
P =σ ,
S
π = π ∗,
M
= L(Ȳ , i)
P
i = i∗ − se(S).
The third equation follows from the constancy of σ in equilibrium, and that
S/S−1 − 1 = 0 in equilibrium.
Endogenous: M , i, σ, π and P .
Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, Ȳ .
6
Devaluation: Assume that the economy is initially in equilibrium. The devaluation (e.g., dS = −1) means that s0e(−1) > 0.
Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i∗ − se(S) − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1)
M
= L(Y, i∗ − se(S))
P
π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ )
The first equation defines an AD-curve in terms of Y and π. The slope of this
curve:
dπ ¯¯
1 − CY − P CAY
< 0.
¯AD,f ix,short =
dY
P CAσ σ−1
The slope of the short run AS curve:
dπ ¯¯
¯AS,short = a > 0
dY
The AD schedule is shifted horizontally by a change in S:
Summary of short run effects: Y % , π % , i & and M %.
(The slope of the long run AD curve is steeper than the short run AD). There
is however no shift in this curve since S/S−1 − 1 = 0 and s0e = 0 in the long
run.
Summary: Long run effects (i.e., compared to initial equilibrium): S & (since
initial increase was not reversed), P % (since σ unchanged), M %. Y and i
unchanged relative to initial equilibrium.
dY ¯¯
¯AD,f ix,short = −Iρs0e + P CAσ σ−1/S−1 < 0,
dS
so a devaluation shifts the AD curve to the right.
7
8
2.2
Floating exchange rate
Foreign exchange equilibrium defines:
a) Short-run model
Y = C(Ω̄, Y − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π̄) + Ḡ + P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S/S−1 + π − π ∗)σ−1)
M
= L(Y, i),
P
i = i∗ − se(S)
M
, Y ), Si∗ ≤ 0, SM/P ≤ 0, SY ≥ 0
P
The float AD curve is defined by:
S = S(i∗,
Y = C(Ω̄, Y −T̄ )+I(q̄, i(
π = π̄ + a(Y − Ȳ )
M
M
, Y )−π̄)+Ḡ+P CA(Y, Y ∗, (S(i∗, , Y )/S−1+π−π ∗)σ−1)
P
P
Slope:
Endogenous: Y, i, S, and π.
dπ ¯¯
1 − CY − P CAY − IρiY − P CAσ SY σ−1/S−1
<0
¯AD,float, short =
dY
P CAσ σ−1
Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, π ∗, i∗, π̄, M , Ȳ , P, S−1,
σ−1.
meaning that the ADfloat curve is steeper than ADfix.
Money market equilibrium defines
AS curve is the same as in fix regime.
i = i(
M
, Y ), iM/P ≤ 0, iY ≥ 0.
P
10
9
b) Long-run version of the model
The equilibrium is defined by
Y = Ȳ , and π = π̄, σ = σ−1
and
s = se(S) = 0, correct expectations
Endogenous: i, σ, π,S, and P .
Predetermined and/or exogenous: Ω̄, T̄ , q̄, Ḡ, Y ∗, M, π ∗, i∗, π̄, Ȳ
More compactly written
where s = S/S−1 − 1 (as above).
Imposing this gives the long run model
Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i − π) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ)
P∗
P =σ ,
S
π∗ = π
M
= L(Ȳ , i)
P
i = i∗,
11
Ȳ = C(Ω̄, Ȳ − T̄ ) + I(q̄, i∗ − π ∗) + Ḡ + P CA(Ȳ , Y ∗, σ)
M
∗
∗ = L(Ȳ , i )
σ PS
with σ and S as endogenous.
12
2.3
Fiscal policy in the AD-AS model
Fiscal policy serves several purposes
1. Provision of public goods and services.
Vertical shift in AD curves:
−1
dπ ¯¯
¯AD,f ix,short =
dḠ
P CAσ σ−1
−1
dπ ¯¯
¯AD,float,short =
dḠ
P CAσ σ−1
Hence fiscal policy has larger effect under fixed exchange rate.
2. Redistributive goals. (Equity versus efficiency?)
Key mechanism:
3. Macro-economic stabilization
In a clean float regime i % in the money market leads to σ % in the market for
foreign exchange. Both effects reduce the effect relative to the fixed exchange
rate regime.
3. is complementary/alternative to monetary policy, and is our main concern
here
The conclusion applies to the short run. In the long run net, exports are
crowded out by increased expenditure in both regimes.
Use AD-AS model as reference framework.
13
14
3
Role of capital mobility:
Baseline model assumes perfect capital mobility. If we (instead) assume imperfect capital mobility we have the following modifications:
1. Only minor in float case. Why? (Money market analysis as before, and
positive relationship between i and S in the foreign exchange marker (same
as the downward sloping “Ei-curve” in the OEM model).
2. In a fixed exchange rate regime, the government might choose to control
money supply, through sterilization. In that case i % also in this regime,
thus reducing the expansive effect.
15
The budget surplus
While the rationale for modern fiscal policy is to affect the overall activity level
(and thus unemployment rates), it most direct impact is on the government’s
own financial situation.
That side of the issue is always important, i.e., prudent governments always try
to keep down/revert deficits in order to maintain financial independence (for a
rainy day, and in order to maintain and strengthen the beliefs in the stability
of the currency and the solvency of the government).
Sometime, government deficients become the overriding concern of financial
policy, either because of past sins (large debt), or of changes in political priorities.
16
3.1
The activity corrected surplus
Replace the baseline model’s assumption about exogenous taxes T̄ , with a
tax-function
In practice (more complicated computation though).
Used to characterize a budget as “really” expansionary or contractive. Popular
among politicians.
T = τY
which (though exceedingly simple) is more realistic Clearly the tax-function
makes the government primary surplus
T −G
Alternative to using model multipliers of Y wrt G to characterize the budget.
Seemingly more free of assumption, but in reality just as model dependent (cf
calculating the trend GDP output level Y ).
dependent on wether the activity level is high or low.
Today a good deal of emphasis on activity correction, which would be
τ Ȳ − G
A much used decomposition of the budget is then
τ (Y − Ȳ ) + τ Ȳ − G
17
3.2
18
Debt financing and debt stabilization
Using B&W notation, the change in real public debt (B), is equal to the total
budget deficit
∆B = G − T + rB
(1)
where r is a real interest rate. rB is referred to as “debt service”.
Over time governments must stabilize the debt to income ratio B/Y
∆
B
G − T + rB
=
Y
Y
B
∆B ∆Y
∆BY − ∆Y B
=
=
−
B
Y
Y2
Y
Y
so that (*) can be written
∆
B
B
= G − T + (r − g)
Y
Y
19
Deficit reduction has been the way chosen by many European countries as a
result of the Maastricht treaty in 1991 and the Stability and Growth Pact of
1997. Has contributed to high European unemployment, though only temporary according to AD-AS with Phillips curve.
Modifications: Seigniorage and inflation tax.
(*)
Rewrite right hand side
∆
To stabilize debt at a certain level the primary surplus T − G must equal
B . “Easiest” when interest rates are low and growth is high (e.g.,
(r − g) Y
Europe in the 1950’s and 1960s).
(15.3)
In practice, not all public debt is interest bearing. If the government finances a
deficit by printing money, it obtain an interest free loan from the public. This
source of “income” to the central government is called seigniorage. Without
the monopoly right to printing money the government would have sell bonds
and pay interest instead.
The Stability pact “forbids” this form of debt financing.
20
4
Down the years governments debt (in real terms!) has also been able to reduced
by high inflation, which (as we have seen) takes away the gains from owing
fixed income assets (bonds), hence is referred to as n inflation tax.
Adoption of low inflation as a target of monetary policy as greatly reduced the
inflation tax.
Issues in demand management.
The rationale and scope for “activist fiscal policy” is a main controversy in
economics.
B&W ch 16 is highly recommended.
Here, comment only on a few of the issues covered by B&W:
1. Slope of AS schedule and adjustment lag
2. Policy and effectiveness lags
3. Lucas critique
22
21
4.1
Slope of AS schedule and adjustment lags
B&W point out that the rationale for demand adjustment is larger if short-run
AS curve is flat and it takes (long) time before the short sun curve “moves
back” to the vertical long run position.
Answer hinges on the shape of the Phillips curve (non-linearities is essential),
and about how fast
Is the long run AS curve vertical?
As we have seen there are competing models of wage and price setting which
refute that thesis.
Aukrust/bargaining model: Inflation stabilizes at the foreign rate of inflation
at “any” level of unemployment. Implying that the equilibrium level of unemployment need not coincide with the Phillips curve natural rate.
• core inflation adjusts
• and also how fast unemployment changes (not mentioned by B&W) towards its natural rate
However, a more overriding concern is the status of the Phillips curve natural
rate model itself.
23
24
4.2
Policy and effectiveness lags
A very relevant caution against too ambitious demand control is related to the
fact that various lags makes it difficult in practice to carry out the intention of
counter cyclical fiscal policy.
1. Recognition lag (data measurement)
2. Decisions lag (political system)
4.3
Lucas critique
No controversy that expectations are important in macroeconomics.
The Lucas critique takes the extreme view that expectations are rational and
that they dominate the economic decisions of households and firms. Hence
impossible to predict reactions to economic policy changes on the basis of
current and past behaviour (e.g., as summarized in an econometric consumption
function).
If valid empirically, the Lucas critique takes away the rationale for demand
management.
3. Implementation lag (“red tape”)
However, empirical tests show that the empirical relevance of the Lucas critique
is overstated.
4. Effectiveness lag (from change in instrument to effect in target)
25
5
Supply-Side Policy (B&W ch 17)
The important sections for our course is section 17.4.
Note in particular the discussion about active and passive labour market programmes, Box. 17.5., which reflects the view that the comparatively low Nordic
unemployment rates is due to active programmes.
Rødseth and Nymoen (2003) find no strong evidence for the positive influence
of programmes on employment, and at the same time report that demand
management and devaluations have been important.
Role of labour unions.
Separate handout provides shows that if bargaining is coordinated (“centralized”), union based wage setting might entail quite flexible wages (in line with
Gjedrem’s talk at the start of the term).
27
26
Download