/ _ DEWEY MIT LIBRARIES i ^-gS) "' 111 !l 1 ' lllllll" 'I' ' H' ! 3 9080 03317 5966 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series The "Other" Imbalance and Ricardo J. the Financial Crisis Caballero Working Paper 09-32 December 29, 2009 RoomE52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Network Paper Collection at httsp://ssrn.com/abstract=l 529764 Social Science Research , The "Other" Imbalance and the Financial Ricardo J. Crisis Caballero 1 December 29, 2009 Abstract One of the main economic before the villains crisis was the presence of large "global imbalances." The concern was that the U.S. would experience a sudden stop of capital which would unavoidably drag the world economy into a deep recession. flows, However, when the crisis finally come, the mechanism did not did feared sudden stop. Quite the opposite, during the were stabilizing rather a imbalance was of crisis than a destabilizing source. The a different kind: I at all resemble the net capital inflows to the U.S. argue instead that the root entire world had an insatiable demand for safe debt instruments that put an enormous pressure on the U.S. financial system and incentives (and this was result of the negative by regulatory mistakes). facilitated feedback loop between the initial The tremors in its was the crisis itself the financial industry created to bridge the safe-assets gap and the panic associated with the chaotic unraveling of this complex industry. Essentially, the financial sector was able to create "safe" assets from the securitization of lower quality ones, but at the cost of exposing the economy to a systemic panic. governments around the world This explicitly structural absorb a larger problem can be alleviated share of the systemic options for doing this range from surplus countries rebalancing their portfolios riskier assets, to private-public solutions good parts of the banks' if The toward risk. where asset-producer countries preserve the removing the systemic risk from the securitization industry while Such public-private solutions could be designed with fee balance sheets. structures that could incorporate all kind of too-big- or too-interconnected-to-fail considerations. Keywords: systemic Global imbalances, financial fragility, panic, crisis, safe assets shortage, securitization, complexity, Knightian uncertainty, contingent insurance, TIC, contingent CDS JEL Codes: 1 E32, E44, E58, F30, G01, MIT and NBER. Prepared 2009. I G20 for the Paolo Baffi Lecture delivered at the Bank of Italy on December 10* thank Francesco Giavazzi, Arvind Krishnamurthy, James Poterba and seminar participants of Italy for their comments, and Fernando Duarte, Jonathan Goldberg, and Matthew Huang research assistance. First draft: November 24, 2009. at the Bank for outstanding Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/otherimbalancefiOOcaba /. Introduction One main economic of the imbalances," which refer villains before the the to was the presence crisis massive and persistent of large "global current account deficits experienced by the U.S. and financed by the periphery. The IMF, then new mandate search for a imbalances as a paramount many around that would justify risk for in a desperate existence, had singled out these its the global economy. That concern was shared by the world and was intellectually grounded on the devastating crises often experienced by emerging market economies that run chronic current account The main trigger of these crises deal with a sudden reversal in expansion and current account is the abrupt macroeconomic adjustment needed to the net capital inflows that supported the previous deficits (the so called concern was that the U.S. would experience a similar drag the world economy However, when the into a deficits. "sudden stops"). The global fate, which unavoidably would deep recession. crisis finally did come, the mechanism did not feared sudden stop. Quite the opposite occurred: During the crisis at all resemble the net capital inflows to the U.S. were a stabilizing rather than a destabilizing source. The U.S. as a whole never experienced, not even remotely, an external funding problem. This observation to keep least not I in mind as it hints that it is an important not the global imbalances per-se, or at is through their conventional mechanism, that should be our primary concern. argue instead that the root imbalance was of a different kind (although not unrelated to global imbalances, see below): investors, but also many The entire world, including foreign central banks and U.S. financial institutions, had an insatiable demand debt instruments which put enormous pressure on the incentives (Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2008). interaction between the initial The tremors (caused by the financial industry created to supply safe-assets U.S. financial crisis itself rise in for safe system and was the its result of the subprime defaults) in the and the panic associated to the chaotic was able unraveling of this complex industry. Essentially, the financial sector to create micro-AAA assets from the securitization of lower quality ones, but at the cost of exposing the system to a panic, which In this view, the surge of safe-assets-demand and macroeconomic U.K., Germany, and profits of its finally did risk a concentration is take place. in financial institutions in few other developed economies), as these generated from bridging the gap between natural supply (more on this later on). 2 this rise in complex leverage rise in the U.S. (as well as the sought the institutions demand and In all likelihood, also a central force behind the creation of highly linkages, behind the a key factor the expansion the safe-asset shortage financial instruments is and which ultimately exposed the economy to panics triggered by Knightian uncertainty (Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2007, Caballero and Simsek 2009a, b). This is not to say that the often emphasized regulatory and corporate governance weaknesses, misguided homeownership policies, and unscrupulous lenders, played no role in creating the conditions for the surge in real estate prices However, it is to say that these were mainly important resistance path for the safe-assets imbalance to release structural sources of the dramatic recent Similarly, it is in its and its eventual crash. determining the minimum energy, rather than being the macroeconomic boom-bust not to say that global imbalances did not play 3 cycle. a role. Indeed, there is a connection between the safe-assets imbalance and the more visible global imbalances: The latter were caused by the funding their ability to countries' produce them (Caballero et al demand for financial assets 2008a, b), but this gap is in excess of particularly acute for safe assets since emerging markets have very limited institutional capability to Moreover, Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2008) show than rises as generates the demand a stable for that, paradoxically, the risk AAA-assets grows at the margin. The reason for income flow and Acharya and Schnabl (2009) document that it is precisely those developed that the drops rather for safe assets ABCP and economies where banks could exploit ABCP sought by money market funds around the world, and that experienced the largest stock-market declines during the countries' issuance of is initially demand positive wealth effect for the underlying asset producers. regulatory arbitrage through conduits that issued the between this premium crisis. Moreover, they show that there their current account deficits. is no relation produce these assets. greatly added to the U.S. NASDAQ 4 financial institutions. point, in however, latter provides a is mutual funds, insurance companies, for banks, This safe-asset excess to, that the gap to focus on demand was exacerbated is parsimonious account of many —something the of the main events prior to, as well as global (current account) imbalances view unable to do. demand for safe assets began to rise above what the mortgage-borrowers naturally could provide, mechanisms U.S. By 2001, as corporate world and safe- financial institutions began to search for to generate triple-A assets from previously untapped and riskier sources. Subprime borrowers were next loans, "banks" had to create large we Shifting the focus to the Within this perspective the main pre-crisis mechanism worked as follows: the by the not along the external dimension but along the safe-asset dimension. during, the onset of the crisis is a variety of collateral, developed economies. are so accustomed alone from the periphery for safe-assets crash which re-alerted the rest of the world of the risks inherent to the equity market even The demand economy's own imbalance caused by mandated requirements regulatory, and and other Thus, the excess all sorts of but in order to produce safe assets from their complex instruments and conduits that numbers and tranching securitization of in line, of their liabilities. Similar instruments payment streams, ranging from auto relied on the law of were created from to student loans (see Gorton and Souleles 2006). Along the way, and reflecting the value associated with creating financial instruments from them, the price of real estate and other assets short supply rose A sharply. positive appreciation of the underlying assets derivative See CDOs and Krishnamurthy related products. and Vissing-Jorgensen quantitatively very significant and that iucid description of (beyond some risk aversion). it in feedback loop was created, as the rapid seemed to justify a large triple-A tranche for Credit rating agencies contributed to this loop, (2007) for affects macro-prices persuasive evidence that safe-asset demand and quantities. See Gorton and Metrick (2009) for of the special features of safe debt (repos, in particular) that justify its high is a demand and so did greed and misguided homeownership the main structural causes behind the From a boom and policies, of triple-A assets than the traditional single-name highly rated bond. As Coval et al was much quality underlying assets will tend to default, in fact This means even that, between these complex assets distress if it riskier (2009) demonstrate, for a given unconditional probability of default, a highly rated tranche systemic event. they were not likely bust that followed. new found source systemic point of view, this but most made of lower can (nearly) only default, during a correctly rated as triple-A, the correlation and systemic distress is much higher than for simpler single-name bonds of equivalent rating. The systemic once fragility of risk in itself share of them was kept within the financial system rather than sold to a significant final investors. these instruments became a source of systemic Banks and their SPVs, attracted by the low capital requirement provided by the senior and super-senior tranches of structured products, kept them (and issued short term triple-A liabilities to fund in their books them), sometimes passing their (perceived) infinitesimal risk onto the monolines and insurance companies (AIG, particular). Schnabl The recipe was copied by the main European 2009). interconnected Through in this increasingly process, the core of financial centers (Acharya the complex ways and, as such, it financial system in and became developed vulnerability to a systemic event. The triggering event was the crash mortgage defaults that followed in 5 it. the real estate "bubble" and the rise But this cannot be all of it. in The global subprime financial system went into cardiac arrest mode and was on the verge of imploding more than once, which seems hard to attribute to a relatively small shock which was well within the range of possible scenarios. Instead, the real damage came from the unexpected and sudden freezing of the entire securitization industry. Almost instantaneously, The bubble was of the indirect in itself a reflection of the chronic shortage of assets (Caballero 2006) and, as demand stemming from securitization and complex safe-asset production. mentioned earlier, confidence vanished and the complexity which bread" during the boom, turned into imaginary. more possible the "multiplication of source of counterparty risk, Making matters worse, banks had to bring back of this both real and even senior and super-senior tranches were no longer perceived Eventually, as invulnerable. sheets a made new risk into their balance from the now struggling SIVs and conduits (see Gorton 2008). Knightian uncertainty took over, and pervasive flights to quality plagued the financial system. Fear fed into transactions, even among more worsened deficit of safe assets that in herd of these a new new boon for clients. In clients that money market in distress. had than their usual a higher risk-tolerance in demand for the flight to funds, which suddenly found themselves facing a in demand from clients, some money short-term commercial paper issued by the investment This strategy backfired after Lehman's collapse, Primary Fund "broke-the-buck" as a result of bankruptcy. Perceived complexity reached a private funds were no longer immune it levels. Initially, order to capture a large share of this expansion market funds began to invest banks was behind the whole perceived uncertainty further increased these assets. Safe interest rates plummeted to record low was financial newly found source of triple-A assets from the securitization as the industry dried up, and the spike quality in the prime financial institutions. Along the way, the underlying structural cycle engage fear, causing reluctance to its new to contagion. losses level as when the Reserve associated with Lehman's even the supposedly safest Widespread panic ensued and were not for the massive and concerted intervention taken by governments around the world, the financial system would have imploded. Global imbalances and their feared sudden reversal never played a significant role for the U.S. during this deep crisis. In fact, the worse things became, the foreign investors ran to U.S. Treasuries for cover and treasury rates more domestic and plummeted (and the in matched the downgrade Instead, the largest reallocation of funds dollar appreciated). 5 perception of the safety of the newly created triple-A securitization based assets. Note also that global imbalances per-se were caused by financial assets more broadly (Bernanke 2007 and Caballero main consequence (and has) the recurrent al developed world until it began to drift 7 was probably the This drift NASDAQ crash and demand al the increase in it was a It for 2008b) which had as a 2006 of bubbles (Caballero toward safe-assets. system became compromised, as financial emergence et 2008a), but this was not a source of systemic instability and Caballero et process. still demand large excess a the in was only then that the required input to the securitization result of the rise in risk awareness following the the relative importance of global public savings the in for financial assets. One approach explicitly bear to addressing these issues prospectively a greater share of the systemic On one hand, the approach. risk. would be There are two prongs within this surplus countries (those that on net assets) could rebalance their portfolios toward governments to for riskier assets. On demand financial the other hand, the asset-producer countries have essentially two polar options (and a continuum in between): Either the government takes care of supplying much of the triple-A assets or it lets the private sector take the lead role with government support only during extreme systemic events. If the governments in asset-producing countries were to do have to issue bonds beyond their risky assets fiscal needs, which themselves. From the point of view of a in it directly, turn would require securities a crisis seemed more information From even controlling for to have less was not the case RMBS risks buy to across reflected their relative for triple-A securities. Investors in these informed about the quality of the securitized assets than investors in riskier, sensitive, securities. this perspective, banks were not been rating, this them balanced allocation of Adelino (2009) documents that while the issuance prices of lower rated exposure to then they would the reason the NASDAQ-bubble crash did not cause a major systemic event a central input into securitization process the process of bubble-creation. and they did not diversify away enough In is because contrast, banks played a central role in the of the risk created by that process. the world, this option appears to be dominated by one countries (e.g., China) choose to demand in which sovereigns in surplus themselves. riskier assets Rather than discussing these purely public options, which are relatively straightforward to envision (although their implementation constraints), in this paper will I focus on the is subject to a large more cumbersome but public-private option within asset-producing countries. is that the main failure during the triple-A assets mechanism creation activity size shocks) was not The reason possible to preserve the It is to relocate the systemic risk away from the banks and and the government ante basis and for a fee, fair this potentially larger is an option at in good aspects of this process while component generated by This transfer can be this asset and medium done on an ex- which can incorporate any concerns with the complexity, and systemic exposure of specific financial institutions. There are options to do so, all of which amount to all the systemic vulnerability into private investors (for small (for tail events). of political the private sector's ability to create in through complex financial engineering, but created by this process. finding a crisis number some form of partially size, many mandated governmental insurance provision to the financial sector against a systemic event. The rest of the highlighted paper goes into in this a more detailed analysis of the three introduction: The prelude of the crisis, the crisis, and components a discussion of policies that can play the dual role of alleviating the safe-asset shortage while increasing the resilience of the financial system to panics. //. The Prelude The most large visible anomaly in international financial markets prior to the crisis and sustained current account danger was that between the it deficit of the U.S. Paradoxically, distracted attention from a global demand for safe assets more and the perhaps was the its biggest serious and critical imbalance, that ability of the U.S. private sector to generate these assets without over-stretching develop II. A this argument in more In this section I detail. Global Imbalances Prior to the crisis, there was widespread concern with "global imbalances," which a and persistent current account essentially refer to the massive the U.S. and financed by the periphery (see Figure Figure financial system. its deficits experienced by 1). 1. Current Account 1.5 1.1 0.7 o. Q U | 0.3 -0.1 ._*= t$ o s? -0.5 f \r* >»«>» \ -0.9 USA -1.3 -•-EU —•— Rest of World -1.7 .. -2.1 1990 1992 1996 1994 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 Source: IMF International Financial Statistics, author's calculations. In Caballero et al (2008a) we argued thatthe emerging market crises at the end of the 1990s, the subsequent rapid growth of China and other East Asian economies, and the associated emerging In rise in markets commodity prices toward the in United Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2007) we recent years reoriented capital flows from States. 8 In effect, emerging markets and described the emerging markets side of the story. We argued there that the financial underdevelopment of these economies naturally led to the formation of domestic asset commodity producers in need of sound and newfound wealth turned liquid financial instruments to store their to the U.S. financial markets and institutions, which perceived as uniquely positioned as providers of these instruments. developed in A were related story was Bernanke's (2007) famous savings glut speech. Concern about these "imbalances" was intellectually grounded on the devastating crises often experienced by emerging market economies that run chronic current account The main deficits. needed trigger of these crises to deal with a sudden reversal in is the abrupt macroeconomic adjustment the net capital inflows that supported the previous expansion and current account deficits (the so called "sudden stops"). Figure 2 from Calvo and Talvi (2005) and Calvo, Izquierdo and Talvi (2006) captures the dramatic events during the end of the 1990s. a In a sudden stop such as the matter of months, net capital flows as by double-digits, with a corresponding adjustment demand. The exchange one that affected South in share of a East Asia at GDP declined the current account and aggregate rate collapsed (and interest rates spiked), and along with it so did national income. The global concern by the mid-2000s was that the U.S. would experience which unavoidably would drag the world economy into when the crisis finally did come, the mechanism did not sudden stop. Quite the opposite occurred, during the U.S. were a stabilizing rather than deep a at crisis a destabilizing source. all a similar fate, recession. However, resemble the feared net capital inflows to the The experienced, not even remotely, an external funding problem. U.S. as a whole never Moreover, during the bubbles during periods of large net capital inflows. The crash of these bubbles lead to large capital flow reversals. The events of the late 1990s corresponded to a coordinated crash funds toward the U.S. large enough to lead to bubbles in in emerging markets and hence a reallocation of the U.S. and other developed economies (Caballero et al 2008b). 10 early phase of the crisis, Sovereign Wealth Funds were the primary providers of fresh capital to distressed U.S. banks. Figure 9 2. Sudden Stop in South East Asia* Boom and Capital Flows (in Ml of US dorian, taat fbut quartern) Cm Bust in Capital Flows % of GDP, laal four quarters) Boom jfifstflililllii Bust Aroragi 1934.08 paak199G paaa1996 trough 1998 Thailand v 422,9 -11* Indotntla 2,6 21.9 Jfl Koran *<* -14,6 3* Philip pints Bfl 10,3 -14,8 Malaysia B,1 *,T -10 J) CEO C3Bg> <3E> SEA-6 pa a k 1996 Real Exchange Rate Cun-ont Account (»%of GOP) SSKSSISSBSUSESSE ;~s;s;t;ssssrrrs >0>»a, Matayaia. PMIppinaa ztul I II I 1 II IEI ly jgj Thailand Source: Calvo and Talvi (2005) and Calvo, Izquierdo and Talvi (2006). Figure 3 shows that the U.S. current around since 2006, and that it account deficit was already experiencing a turn- indeed dropped sharply after the Lehman episode. But the key contrast with emerging markets experiencing large external adjustments is that the U.S. dollar appreciated sharply (and- U.S. interest rates plummeted) during this episode. That due is, the adjustment was the result of a contraction to domestic financial They did so until problems rather than due to a in aggregate demand sudden shortage of net external Secretary Paulson decided to exemplary punish shareholders during the Bear Stearns intervention. 11 B funding resulting from a observation to keep least not Figure in flight to quality mind as it away from the hints that it is U.S.. This is an important not the global imbalances per-se, or at through their conventional mechanism, that should be our primary concern. 3. US Current account and dollar-euro exchange "—Current -3.0 - -4.0 - rate l^"\ Account [\ O a. 1.4 a 3 QJ U \D Q. o * -5.0 TO - - 1.3 O O 111111111 OOOOCDOOOOOOOOOOO i i R) i i LOu~iLTit-DU3i-D'>or^r^-r^r^- oo oo do do = ~ —J^ o. <z ~ = *-> a. <c w —= o — " Jjj > a. <c ' LJ O — ra ex <E —= ' <-> o > i c> 1 on C3 'O— a. to 1 1.1 o~i O = i Source: IMF International Financial Statistics The Critical Safe Assets Imbalance II. Since the 1980s, there has been a surge those for risk "diversification"). than 160 percent of GDP Debt plays an important September 11, 2001 and in in financial Figure 4 shows that assets to store value U.S. financial assets 1980 to almost 480 percent in addition to grew from less the third quarter of 2007. role in this surge, especially in the NASDAQ crash (in 1980s and in the post period. 12 Figure 4, Assets U.S. Financial 600 500 Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- 52 57 62 67 Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- 82 87 92 97 02 07 77 72 I Debt Equity Source: Federal Reserve, CRSP. The growth in the ratio of debt to GDP was due debt outstanding rose from 12 percent 5). At the percent to same 15 time, the percent. in to an increase The domestic private sector, especially the financial sector. U.S. 10 1980Q1 to in financial sectors' share of 34 percent government share of outstanding (Unsurprisingly, this trend debt generated by the U.S. 2007Q3 in debt fell (Figure from 24 been reversed of has late.) Households and non-financial firms, which are the residual, were each responsible for a relatively flat share of the A fundamental growing debt-outstanding driver of this increase safe debt instruments. This also from many not be readily Debt is the U.S. financial institutions. met by sum liabilities demand came from of debt outstanding for was the insatiable demand for foreign central banks and investors, but The demand existing sources of triple-A debt. governments, the federal government and domestic of the NYSE, debt in pie. households, for safe Only a debt instruments could sliver of corporate debt, businesses (non-financial), state and financial sectors. Equity is the sum of local market capitalizations Nasdaq and Amex exchanges. 13 for example, carries a triple-A rating. safe-assets imbalance, which Figure is not Thus, the world likely to economy experienced a massive financial system. go away any time soon. 5. Government and financial sector debt 0.4 0.35 D 0.3 e ID i 0.25 O S a o a n 0.2 0.15 £ CO 0.1 0.05 Jan-80 Jan-84 Jan-92 Jan- Jan-96 Jan-00 Source: Federal Reserve This imbalance presented a system and its incentives. this The demand Jan-08 li large profit opportunity for the However, creating safe assets to meet financial Jan-04 Government Domestic financial sector U.S. put enormous pressure on the U.S. U.S. financial system created safe assets from unsafe ones by pooling assets and issuing senior claims on the payoffs of the pools. The senior claims are protected against losses because before the senior claims. more junior claims absorb losses The claims on these pools of assets are called collateralized debt obligations, or CDOs. Global issuance of CDOs grew from $185 billion in 2000 to $1.3 trillion in share of these assets carried triple-A ratings, at least before the Government crisis. includes federal, state, and local government. The denominator is 2007. 12 A large As of June 2007, total households, businesses (non-financial), federal, state and local government, and the domestic debt outstanding by financial sector. 14 Fitch, agency, gave a triple-A rating to almost 60 percent of ratings a structured products, according to a Fitch Ratings (2007) and Stafford (2009). 13 Benmelech and Dlugosz (2009) collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) issued issuance was rated triple-A, a percentage that In contrast, Fitch (in June 2007) and S&P (in document fairly stable is throughout the period. early 2008) gave a triple-A rating to less in 2000, the volume of debt issuance; by 2006, Corroborating government CDO this ratio triple-A assets was only 18 percent for these instruments, fast as did of the had risen almost four-fold. demand-pull the and CDOs. Corporate of U.S. issuance of corporate debt issuance issuance in the issuance of CDOs. debt issuance grew between 2000 and 2006, but not nearly as In sample of find that, in a large between 2000 and 2007, 71 percent of was slower than the increase compares the volume Figure 6 global cited in Coval, Jurek than one percent of single-name corporate issuers. Moreover, the increase of corporate debt all CDO volume issuance. of corporate 14 the as quantity non- of expanded, the yields required to hold them tightened. In January 2002, the spread between Moody's triple-A seasoned corporate bond rate and a 30-year U.S. Treasury was 1.19 percentage points. 15 began, the spread reached 0.55 percentage points. Moody's triple-A IMF Global seasoned corporate bond rate Due to the crisis, What Credit Ratings issuance of CDOs Mean," the corporate debt market in percentage of corporate debt issuance volume 2002. In early 2007, it shows the spread These numbers include both CDOs and Fitch Ratings, in is for first five CDO A 2. August 2007. first five the newly thawed debt markets, issuing 465 the same period. Thus, for the The spread between Moody's Figure 7 collapsed to less than 24 billion dollars during the 2009, while corporations rushed to secure financing in early 2007, before the crisis relative to a 20-year Treasury bond. Financial Stability report (2009), Figure 2.2. "Inside the Ratings: In months of 2009, CDO months of billion dollars issuance volume as a only five percent. triple-A rate and a 20-year Treasury was 0.9 percentage points in January reached 0.45 percentage points. 15 Figure 6. A 2001 2000 2002 - shift 2004 2003 CDO issuance toward CDOs 2006 2005 2007 2008 2009" as a share of corporate debt issuance 16 Source: SIFMA, IMF Global Financial Stability report (2009) Coval, Jurek and Stafford (2008) CDX tranches - find that with credit default swaps (CDS) as assets - carried similar yields to single-name similar loss rates ("despite their highly dissimilar analysis is September 2004 triple-A corporate to September bonds carried over for safe assets. became very complex, 2009a, b). Also, retained a large 2007'. economic risks"). number CDS with Their period of This suggests that the tight pricing of in financial institutions helped meet the global However, these securities and the linkages among firms leaving the system vulnerable to panic (Caballero senior CDO into the structured-finance market. The creation of CDOs and the leveraging demand essentially, tranches of a CDO tranches concentrate macroeconomic of these assets. risk, and Simsek and banks Thus, the response of the financial system to U.S. corporate bond issuance includes "all non-convertible debt, MTNs and Yankee bonds, but excludes CDs and federal agency debt." Both investment-grade and high-yield issues are included. Corporate debt issuance volumes are from the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association (SIFMA) and based on Thomson Reuters data. CDO issuance includes the issuance of CDOs and CDO A 2, from the IMF Global Financial Stability report (2009). The 2009 data covers through the end of June. 16 produced conditions the safe-assets imbalance uncertainty could do significant Figure damage in which an episode of Knightian (Caballero and Krishnamurthy 2007). 7. AAA corporate bond spread 2 1 1 - 5 o. a o> a c 0) u Ai k ' I l 1 ' 0} Q. 0.5 - 14-D SC-01 14-Jun-03 14-Dec-04 14-Jun-06 14-Dec-07 Sources: Federal Reserve II. C From Global to Safe Assets 14-Jun-09 17 Imbalances Having downplayed the conventional concern with global imbalances, note that there global is a imbalances: The latter were caused This figure plots the spread is a small is important to connection between the safe-assets imbalance and the more visible by the funding countries' financial assets in excess of these countries' ability to There it between Moody's triple-A rate demand for produce them (Caballero et al and a 20-year constant maturity Treasury. maturity mismatch because "Moody's tries to include bonds with remaining maturities as close as possible to 30 years." However, there is no 30-year constant maturity Treasury bond since the Treasury stopped issuing 30-year debt for a period. Thus, the spread for a shown good part of the 2000s, in the figure is a noisy measure of the maturity-matched spread. 17 2008), but this gap is particularly acute for safe assets since limited institutional capability to produce them. assets from the periphery greatly added emerging markets have very demand Thus, the excess to the U.S. for safe- economy's own imbalance caused by a variety of collateral requirements and mandates for mutual funds, insurance companies, and others. The point, however, external dimension we is that the gap to focus on FDI. owned by This is assets and figure 18 in However, 11, emerging markets liabilities this throughout after the 1990. this period, and FDI was liabilities a sharp as foreign board and particularly high return risky U.S. This is partially a price effect; but Cumulated whereas flows flows into U.S. into equity We debt debt into see this liabilities on the safe tranches of the asset in it also reflects Figure whole which and equity and FDI and FDI reached an risk in U.S. inflection point After the crash the assets as well and decided distribution. This phase resembled the Japanese (real estate) asset shopping spree during the 1980s, which to safe assets or their safe tranche but to 9, were growing exponentially attacks, tapering off thereafter. world came to realize that there was substantial 18 of the late 1990s, there toward debt and away from equity. dot-com crash and 9/11 to refocus of the trend turned around sharply after the dot-com crash and the shows the cumulated flows of foreign assets since crisis to U.S. equity U.S. assets across the 2001 attacks on the a shift in allocation liabilities liabilities according to careful estimates by Gourinchas and Rey (2007). The the ratio of U.S. debt September the U.S., the Figure 8, which gives the ratio of debt to equity and FDI for U.S. after the demanded investors assets. shown liabilities, in owned by the rest of the world are skewed toward debt, rather than equity and shows that decline not along the are so accustomed to, but along the safe-asset dimension. Relative to the liabilities of the rest of the world U.S. is was not targeted assets. 18 Figure 8. Ratio of debt to equity and FDI 1990q1 1992q1 1994q1 • Gross 1996q1 liabilities of 1998q1 US 2000q1 Gross assets 2D02q1 of 20Q4q1 US Source: Gourinchas and Rey (2007). Figure 9. Cumulated U.S. liabilities flows since 1990 g E S 1500 1990q1 1992q1 1 994q1 1996q1 Debt 1998q1 2000q1 2002q1 2004q1 Equity and FDI Source: Gourinchas and Rey (2007). 19 D Complexity and Systemic Risk Build-up II. "Banks" generated safe assets from risky ones by creating complex instruments that pooled assets, such as subprime mortgages, and creatively divvied up the flows from those assets. Figure 10 two shows the balance sheet of a CDO. properties: (1) pooling of assets; and (2) tranching of of the figure the a caricature of CDO is shows a individual assets RMBS or owned by CMBS CDO, A CDO can be defined by liabilities. here is where the tranching takes sometimes referred to CDO to CDO, a the more junior the blue boxes are bundles of residential It is right (liability) side has the liabilities of the place. The bottom tranche is liabilities liability is liabilities Similar instruments or CDO; it is the equity tranche, from protected from loss because equity and have to be wiped out before the given if here on the asset as "toxic waste." Although the implementation details vary given non-equity These more junior flows. The side left (asset) the CDO, represented by blue boxes; commercial mortgages. These blue boxes are the CDO's assets. side that pooling takes place. The liability all suffers any loss. serve as a buffer. The arrow shows the direction of the cash were created from securitization of all sorts of payment streams, ranging from auto to student loans. Figure 10. The Balance Sheet of a Assets CDO Liabilities AAA tranche AA tranche A tranche BBB tranche BBB- tranche Toxic waste 20 Consider a CDO each mortgage with two $1 mortgages as assets. Suppose the probability of default for is 10 percent and that in if default, the mortgage is worthless. Suppose further the defaults are uncorrelated. There are (essentially) three states of the world: no defaults; one default; and two defaults. What consisting of liabilities assets? Then the $1 two $1 liability liabilities would pay cents 18 percent of the time; and individual mortgage is individual mortgages, it CDO had the if that each received equal payoffs from the in full 81 percent of the time; diversification. But CDOs junior tranche and a $1 senior tranche. is The senior tranche pays created. However, very exposed to "systematic" risk; (Consider an additional asset in it would pay 50 "safer" than the Suppose there are new when both in full 99 percent of the CDOs "economic catastrophe bonds." when During asset defaults only 1 percent of the time, whereas the explored by Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2009a, b), catastrophes is of the mortgages default. the economy, which also pays senior tranche defaults 100 percent of the time.) like $1 99 percent of the in full time; suppose the asset's payoffs are uncorrelated with the mortgage payoffs. the global downturn, the a key to note that the senior tranche it is only defaults is create even safer assets by dividing their liabilities into tranches with different seniorities. time. Thus, a "safe" asset it would be worthless one percent of the time. An worthless ten percent of the time, so this asset because of only one class of who This point has been rigorously structured finance products call precisely during economic defaults on the asset side of the balance sheet are large enough to By design, it is eradicate the buffer protecting the senior tranches. As private-label securitizations increased,, the price of short supply rose sharply, in real estate and other assets in part reflecting the value associated with creating financial instruments from them. A positive feedback loop was created, as the rapid appreciation of the underlying assets seemed to justify a large triple-A tranche for derivative and related products. Credit rating agencies contributed to this loop, CDOs and so did greed 21 and misguided homeownership but as stated earlier: They were not the root policies, cause. shows the Figure 11 this period. risk in itself 19 fast growth of global private-label securitization issuance during The systemic once than sold to a significant final these instruments became fragility of a source of systemic share of them was kept within the financial system rather Banks and their SIVs, attracted by the high unleveraged investors. return and low capital requirement combination provided by the senior and supersenior tranches of structured products, kept their (then perceived as) infinitesimal risk (AIG, in particular). 20 them on The complex ways and vulnerable to light-blue bars represent increased from $25 billion use of CDO A 2 in money became interconnected a systemic event. CDOs that have other billion in 2006. in According to Acharya triple-A asset-backed securities all CDO A 2, CDOs 2000 to $338 quickly absorbed by institutions with insatiable appetite for safe assets. and Schnabl (2009), "about 30% of 19 was process, the core of the financial system this increasingly and indirect hoarding by issuing this direct highly rated short-maturity commercial paper, which Through sometimes passing onto the monolines and insurance companies They funded much of market funds and the many other their books, remained within Global issuance of as their assets. CDO A 2 As Coval, Jurek, and Stafford (2009a,b) point out, the only increases the correlation between default and systemic events. An important reason (2009): "In hindsight, was regulatory and it is for the creation of SIVs stemmed from regulatory arbitrage. From Brunnermeier one distorting force leading to the popularity of structured investment vehicles arbitrage. The Basel Accord (an international agreement that sets guidelines for bank clear that ratings I regulation) required that banks hold capital of at least eight percent of the loans on their balance sheets; this capital requirement capital charge at (called a 'capital charge') all was much lower for contractual credit lines. Moreover, there was no - noncontractual liquidity backstops that sponsoring banks for 'reputational' credit lines provided to structured investment vehicles to maintain their reputation. Thus, moving a pool of loans into offbalance-sheet vehicles, and then granting a credit line to that pool to ensure a AAA-rating, allowed banks to reduce the amount of capital they needed to hold to conform with Basel I regulations while the risk for the bank remained essentially unchanged. The subsequent Basel Accord, which went into effect on January 1, 2007 in Europe but is yet to be fully implemented in the United States, took some steps to correct this preferential treatment of noncontractual credit lines, but with little effect. While Basel implemented capital charges based on II II asset ratings, banks were able to reduce Because of the reduction of idiosyncratic their capital charges by pooling loans risk better rating than did the individual securities overall rating downgraded in off-balance-sheet vehicles. through diversification, assets issued by these vehicles received in the pool. In addition, issuing short-term assets a improved the even further, since banks sponsoring these structured investment vehicles were not sufficiently one reason the large banks kept exposure for granting liquidity backstops." According to Tett (2009), to the super senior tranches on their books on these tranches, eventually decided it was that AIG, which in the early stages of the had too much exposure and stopped providing boom provided insurance this insurance. 22 — the banking system, and fraction rises if one includes ABCP conduits and SIVs that had recourse, 50%." A November 2007 announcement by Citigroup shows to investment bank had $43 billion in exposure in super senior tranches of ABS "primarily" backed by subprime residential mortgages. Notably, total direct of of its exposure to U.S. subprime mortgages was $55 Citi's this its CDOs investment bank's so almost 80 percent billion, exposure was through super senior tranches. By 2007, the Federal Reserve Bank New trillion, York calculated that SIVs and similar vehicles had combined assets of $2.2 more than the assets of hedge funds ($1.8 assets of the five largest broker dealers ($4 trillion), trillion) (Tett and more than half the total 2009). Figure 11. Global private-label securitization issuance by type 4500 - 3500 - o + TH+ Mil iiiii 1 i 1000 500 - - - 2000 2001 2002 2003 ABCP 2004 ~~1~ — — 2005 2006 , 1 1 , 2007 2008 1 1 2009 MBS BABS bCDO «CD02 Source: IMF, Global Financial Stability Report, Figure 2.2. ///. The Crisis The conditions were thus far ripe for a severe systemic event, more force than anyone had anticipated. There estate prices and the corresponding rise in which eventually came with was the shock from declining real subprime defaults, but even under the most 23 pessimistic scenarios, these shocks pale in comparison with the that eventually followed once the panic set III. A magnitude of the crisis in. The Shock The triggering event was the crash mortgage defaults that followed system went into cardiac arrest the real estate "bubble" and the in But this cannot be it. mode and was on all of it. rise in subprime The global financial the verge of imploding more than once, which seems hard to attribute to a relatively small shock such as the real- estate/subprime In combo (see Caballero 2009). Caballero and Kurlat (2009), we constructed an estimate of mortgage-related losses were amplified by the estimate, we computed crisis how much banks' that these losses sparked. initial For this the evolution of the market value (equity plus long term debt) of the major U.S. banks since January 2007, which yielded an estimate of the right side of these banks' balance sheets. 21 Absent any feedback should be equal to the losses suffered by the assets on the sheets. However, as illustrated in Figure 12, we find that losses left total losses on effects, these losses side of the balance on the right side are on the order of three times the IMF's (evolving) estimates of losses related to mortgage assets accruing to U.S. banks. The procedure 22 for estimating this was as follows: For equity, bank's market capitalization, excluding increases in we simply tracked the evolution of each the market cap due to issues of new shares. For debt, we estimated the duration of each bank's long term debt (including any preferred shares) from the maturity profiles described in the 10-K statements as of December 2007, assuming the interest rate was equal to the rate on 10- year Treasuries plus the spread on 5-year CDS for each bank, obtained from JP Morgan. Assuming an unchanged maturity profile, we then tracked the changes basis of the evolution of the in the implied market value of each bank's long term debt on the CDS spread. The banks included in the calculation are the 19 banks that underwent the "stress tests" plus Lehman, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Wachovia, and Washington Mutual. The IMF uses a projection of macroeconomic variables and default market values to estimate losses on subprime-related overreacted due to fire sales, securities. rates to estimate losses on loans, and To the extent that market prices of securities our procedure understates the multiplier. 24 Beginning in 2008, and increasingly after the fall of Bear Stearns, the overall loss in market value became larger than the losses from subprime assets alone. The market began to price recession, its from the overall disruption of losses and losses on other types of assets which from the mortgage market FiRure 12. Losses far financial markets, the severe exceeded the estimated losses itself. from mortgage assets, total loss of market value and — — J 000 multiplier. TauHoitolnuikflniiiicleqjnYpiuideBllQf US binki u eiiimiltO by IMF Jfe_ 1500 rV 1000 1 sao 7Z r07 „„., hi 07 S*p07 4av07 anOS ,ii' as Mir oa ui 01 Oct OS Dae OS Mi' 09 Miy 09 MO Sources: IMF Global Financial Stability Reports, banks' financial statements and JP Morgan. From Caballero and Kurlat (2009). II LB The The Panic real damage came from the unexpected and sudden securitization industry. Securities in line in Figure 13 is "New The new issuance 23 series The is crisis in this the market sum over the real estate; autos; credit cards; is entire Issuance of Asset-Backed Previous 3 Months," from Adrian and Shin (2009); the data originally from JP Morgan Chase. commercial The blue freezing of the come apparent from the disappearance of following categories of ABS: "home equity (subprime)"; student loans; non-US residential mortgages; and other. The data were provided by Tobias Adrian. 25 new The red issuances. line is the implied spread on the 2006-1 measures the cost of insuring against default by mortgage-backed securities of the JP f irst-ha lf-of-2006 vintage. Morgan Chase and not only corroborates the but also makes it triple-A is tranches ABX, which of subprime The spread data are from impression from the quantity side crisis clear that the collapse in quantity AAA demand rather than supply driven. Figure 13. Freezing of the Asset-Backed Securities (ABS) market 700 o o o o 5 o a o o m m _ -^ £J m £ m jn '"" en m u\ 2O06-1AAAABX Sources: JP IS. 3 - New o a o o O O m m m r^ in fN o> Morgan Chase, Adrian and bread" during the boom, turned into a o o cr. ssua nee of Asset-B scked Securlt ei Confidence vanished and the complexity which (see Gorton o made Shin (2009). possible the "multiplication of source of counterparty 2008). Senior and super-senior tranches risk, real and imaginary were no longer perceived as invulnerable, and making matters worse, banks had to bring back into their balance sheets more of this new risk from the now struggling SIVs and conduits. 26 In December 2007, the SIVs' $49 assets were Citigroup provided a guarantee facility to billion in assets onto its balance sheet. financial-institutions debt. percent) assets. (6 percent); One hundred percent SIVs, essentially bringing About 60 percent of the Thirty-nine percent SIVs' were structured-finance and non-U. S. (12 percent) residential assets, including: U.S. (7 percent of total assets) MBS; CBOs, CDOs, and CLOs 24 its student loans (5 percent), and credit card of the structured-finance assets carried (5 Moody's triple-A ratings. Knightian uncertainty took over, and pervasive flight to qualities plagued the financial system. Fear fed transactions, even into more among fear, and caused reluctance to engage in financial the prime financial institutions (see Figure 14). Figure 14. TED Spread Source: Global Financial Data. "Citi Commits Support November 2008, to Purchase All Citi directly Facility for Citi-Advised SIVs," Citigroup press release, purchased the remaining assets of its SIVs. Remaining Assets," Citigroup press release, November "Citi Finalizes SIV December 13, 2007. In Wind-down by Agreeing 19, 2008. 27 As the crises spread there was a sharp shift of the maturity structure of asset-backed commerciai paper (ABCP) toward very short-term maturities. At the height of the crisis, nearly 80 percent of the asset-backed paper issued had a maturity of only one to four an increase of more than 40 percentage points since January 2004. days, shortening of the maturity structure was decline in September 2008. ABCP declined from 17 days in a pronounced Figure 15, the average in August 2008, to 9 days in has long been understood that funding through short-maturity It generates rollover emerging market was gradual, but there September 2008, when Lehman collapsed. As shown maturity of newly issued liabilities fairly This crises risk, but, as by Broner et al it has been documented in the context of do not have many other (2008), borrowers options during severe financial crises. Figure 15. Average maturity of newly issued ABCP (estimate) Jan-06 Jan-07 Jul-06 Jul-07 Jan-08 Jul-08 Jan-09 Jul-09 Sources: Federal Reserve, author's estimate. In 25 the months following Lehman's collapse, there was also a sudden short-term maturities in the CP market for financial companies, as The weighted average maturity 80] day CP is is estimated as follows: [1-4] day CP is move toward shown in very Figure 16. 26 treated as (4+l)/2 = 2.5 days; [41- treated as (80+41)/2 = 60.5 days; etc. For [80+] day CP, a value of 90 days was used. 28 The decline was precipitous because market participants were surprised by the depth of and the chaotic aftermath of Lehman's collapse, whereas financial firms' difficulties participants fact, as knew (since at least problems festered of the 2007) about problems in the ABS market. the ABS market during the early phases of the in financial firms conservatively summer lengthened their CP maturities. In in one crisis, August 2008, 50 percent commercial paper issued by financial companies matured November, 87 percent of the paper issued matured In in one to four days. By to four days. Figure 16. Average maturity of newly issued financial CP (estimate) 25 20 ^~^ Q A ILL/ \/^ 10 5 Jan-06 Jan-07 Jul-06 Jul-07 Jan-08 Jul-08 Jan-09 Jul-09 Sources: Federal Reserve, author's estimate. Along the way, the underlying structural cycle, worsened deficit of safe assets that as the newly found source of triple-A assets industry dried up, and the spike Safe interest rates plummeted There was also substantial in uncertainty further increased was behind the whole from the securitization demand for safe assets. to record low levels (see Figure 17). volatility of in the maturity structure during this period, likely the result of a desire of financial firms to push out the maturity structure and a willingness of investors to absorb longer maturities that varied with volatile market conditions and expectations of government involvement. 29 Figure 17. 3-Month Treasury Bill rate Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Initially, the flight to quality was a boon for the found themselves with demand from a clients. money market In investment banks in distress. Reserve Primary Fund bankruptcy. to invest than their usual clients, This strategy backfired after Lehman's collapse, "broke-the-buck" Perceived as a complexity result in some commercial paper from the short-term in funds, which suddenly order to capture this expansion clients having a preference for riskier assets money market funds began Lehman's new herd of St. Louis. of reached its a losses new when the associated with level as even the supposedly safest private funds were no longer immune to contagion. Widespread panic took over and had it not been for the massive and concerted intervention taken by governments around the world, the financial system would have imploded 27 Reserve Primary Fund had invested $785 million assets. Immediately after Lehman filed for in Lehman 27 debt, which constituted about 1.2% of bankruptcy, the fund suffered a massive run, with over $30 its billion in 30 While the end of the panic has removed some of the pressure on the safe-assets world, the crisis destroyed a significant share of the financial industry created by the private demand sector to satisfy the large triple-A assets gap now worse than it around the world. The shortage of was before the crisis, and unless a solution to this found soon, many of the weaknesses that were created before the is reemerge IV, is for safe assets in same the crisis will mutated form. or a The Policy Options The core policy question is how to bridge the safe-asset gap without over-exposing the financial sector to systemic risk. One approach explicitly bear to addressing these issues prospectively greater share of the systemic a risk. would be for There are two prongs within this approach. On one hand, the surplus countries (those that on net assets) could rebalance their portfolios toward governments to riskier assets. On demand financial the other hand, the asset-producer countries have essentially two polar options (and a continuum in between): Either the government takes care of supplying much of the triple-A assets or it the private sector take the lead role with government support only during lets extreme systemic events. Should the governments would have to buy to issue risky assets the flight to quality asset-producing countries choose to do bonds beyond their fiscal needs, which themselves. From the point of view of redemption requests (about a.m. the following day. in half of its Money market total assets) before it a in directly, they turn would require them it balanced allocation of risks stopped accepting redemption requests at $1 at 11 funds had been considered extremely safe, and had indeed benefited from billion (34%) since mid 2007. The drop in the caused investors to question the safety of the entire industry. There were net during the previous year, growing by about $850 Reserve Primary Fund's NAV billion during that week, as well as a large shift from prime funds towards funds government debt. In order to stem the panic, on September 19 the U.S. Treasury guarantee program that would compensate investors if the NAV of participating funds fell below $1. redemptions for about $170 investing exclusively announced a in 31 across the world, this option appears to be dominated by one surplus countries (e.g., demand China) choose to riskier assets Rather than discussing these purely public options, cumbersome but potentially in this in themselves. paper option public-private larger which sovereigns in will I focus on the within more asset-producing countries. The reason the public-private venture the main failure was not complex in is an option despite the recent in that that the private sector's ability to create triple-A assets through financial engineering (although rating agencies the process), but crisis, is may have excessively facilitated the systemic vulnerability created by this process. Public-private ventures preserve the successful parts of this asset creation activity while finding mechanism to reallocate the systemic risk sheet to private unlevered investors government component (for it small and creates from the banks' balance medium size shocks) and the (for tail events). Just raising capital requirements achieves the goal of reducing vulnerability but it does so at the cost of exacerbating the structural problem of excess safe-asset demand. this sense, a it is In not a stand-alone policy. There are two broad categories of recent proposals to reduce crisis risk without excessively limiting the financial sector's ability to bridge the safe-assets gap: • Pre-paid/arranged contingent capital injections, and • Pre-paid/arranged contingent asset and capital insurance injections. The basic purpose of the former, contingent capital associated with the holding of capital this when approach recognizes that access to advance, since kind differ in it is it is injections, is not needed. However, and centrally, capital during crises needs to be arranged often hard to raise capital during a severe crisis. their sources of this contingent capital, in particular, sector and the government. Within the former, in to reduce the costs in Proposals of this between the private some proposals the contingent funds 32 come primarily from existing stakeholders (e.g., through contingent debt/equity swaps) while others the funds in problems extreme events, a point highlighted theory and AIG (and the monolines) Flannery's (2002) proposal his outsiders. However, outsiders' commitments the extent to which the private sector can serve as the source of this limit capital during come from in made one by Holmstrom and Tirole (1998) in practice. of the first significant steps in this direction with proposal for "reverse convertible debentures." Such debentures would convert to equity whenever the market value of One problem of this early proposal idiosyncratic shocks. calls for The Kashyap equity a firm's that is et al it falls made no below a certain distinction threshold. between aggregate and (2008) proposal deals with this distinction and banks to buy capital insurance policies that pay off when the banking sector experiences a negative systemic shock. Private investors would underwrite the policies and place the amount insured into a "lock box" invested in US Treasuries. Investors who are themselves subject to capital requirements would not be allowed to supply this insurance. The insurance would be triggered when aggregate bank number amount; of quarters exceed not be included in some significant determining whether the insurance losses over a certain losses at the covered is bank would triggered. Combining both contributions, the Squam Lake Working Group on Financial Regulation has a proposal (2009) similar to Flannery's except that conversion from debt to equity is triggered only during systemic events and only for banks that violate certain capital- adequacy covenants. Yet another variant on capital insurance is for the insurance policy to regulator, instead of the firm. Under amount would be proportional to an estimate risk? of insurance required posed by the bank, systemic in this proposal, pay out to the by Acharya and others (2009), the of the systemic order to discourage firms ex-ante from taking on excessive risk. 33 Hart and Zingales (2009) advocate an alternative approach; CDS rise above issue equity in its CEO is it at risk. in of time to the bank is Although If the regulator determines the bank's debt is not at the bank by lending to the bank; otherwise, the regulator with a trustee, the bondholders. If a bank's CDS spread, the regulator reviews the bank's books and determines the regulator invests component, window order to bring the CDS spread back below the threshold. whether the bank's debt replaces the allows the bank a a certain threshold, a regulator unable to reduce risk, when spreads on who approach does have this also relies heavily the bank and pass the proceeds to will liquidate on the resolution of a contingent capital-injection financial firms, which can be a useful disciplinary device during normal times but can be highly counterproductive during a systemic episode. More the generally, the contingent capital approach crisis a central may is mostly one of fundamentals. However, feature of most financial crises, then most is it if is likely to restore stability the panic component is significant, not the most cost-effective, and it well trigger further panic as fear of dilution and forced conversion increases. This takes us to the second set of proposals, contingent insurance injections. idea of this approach is that the pure panic costly capital injection to subside. All that will when is component needed be available should conditions worsen. Despite cost of such a policy is low because underlies the panic. That is, the it derives enormous its is its a The basic of a crisis does not require a broad guarantee that resources high notional value, the expected power from the very same feature that distortion in perceived probabilities of a catastrophe also means that economic agents greatly overvalue public insurance and guarantees. Providing these can be as effective as capital injections in dealing with the panic at a fraction of the expected cost (when assessed at reasonable rather than panicdriven probabilities of a catastrophe). In Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2007) uncertainty, a we showed that during an episode of Knightian government concerned with the aggregate will want to provide insurance 34 against extreme events even sector. The reason fears itself to be is in a it has no informational advantage over the private that during a panic of this kind, each individual bank and investor worse than the average, an event that cannot be true for situation the collective. By providing to react if broad guarantee, the government leads the private sector a more than one-for-one since it also closes the gap between the true average and the average of panic-driven expectations. During the current argument panic is for why crises, it developed may there were many Krishnamurthy (2008b). institutions face a constraint such that value-at-risk equity. In normal times, these are "multiplied" 28 The be optimal to support assets rather than inject capital during a Caballero and in asset-insurance injection proposals. this structure many times in must be less practice, In financial than some multiple of speaks to the power of equity injections, since relaxing the value-at-risk constraint. In contrast, insuring assets reduces value-at-risk by reducing risk directly, which typically does not involve a multiplier. assets, such as However, when uncertainty CDOs and CDO-squared, can is rampant, some illiquid reverse this calculation. In and complex such cases, insuring the uncertainty-creating assets reduces risk by multiples, and frees capital, more effectively than directly injecting equity capital. Moreover, it turns out that the recapitalize banks when this is the government can pledge a capital (Caballero 2009a). same principle of insurance-injection can be used to the chosen solution. Rather than directly injecting capital, minimum This future price guarantee for newly privately raised mechanism is very powerful because private investors overvalue the guarantee, and because the recapitalization event that less likely. Caballero once the equilibrium mechanism significantly and Kurlat (2009a) quantified response of equity prices itself this is makes a catastrophic mechanism and showed taken into account, reduces the effective exposure of government this resources relative to a public equity injection. 2S See, e.g., Caballero (2009a,b), Mehrling and Milne (2008) and Milne (2009) for proposals. 35 Many of the actual programs implemented during the had elements of guarantees crisis rather than being pure capital injections. Perhaps the clearest case of this approach announced that followed by the UK. Their asset protection scheme, provided insurance against 90 percent of losses above portfolios of corporate a "first-loss" is provided in exchange for a fee. RBS and Lloyds Banking Group, with respectively. The main January 2009, The APS covered £552 a first-loss criticism to the U.K.'s CDO amount approach In billion portfolios of of £19.5 billion and £25 billion, is that they charged such a high economy to their failure than socially optimal. we Caballero and Kurlat (2009b) guarantee access to insurance flexible The obligations. fee for the insurance that most banks chose not to engage, leaving the overall more exposed on threshold and leveraged loans, commercial and residential property loans, and structured credit assets such as RMBS, CMBS, CLO, and insurance in is manner discussed a policy framework which would not only the event of an SFA episode, but in that integrates the role of the government it would do so in a as an insurer of last resort with private sector information on the optimal allocation of contingent insurance. In that framework, the government would would be purchased by financial issue tradable insurance credits (TICs) institutions, some of which which would have minimum each TIC would entitle its holder to attach a government guarantee to newly-issued and legacy securities. All regulated holding requirements. During a systemic financial institutions would be allowed crisis, to hold funds, corporations, and possibly hedge funds. flexible and use In TICs, as well as private equity principle, TICs could be and readily available substitute for many of the during the crisis. that were created The basic mechanism would consist of attaching them to variants could include attaching particular facilities them needs of the distressed assets, but to liabilities and even equity, depending on the institutions as collateral-enhancers for discount used as a and markets, and they could also operate window borrowing. 36 TICs are equivalent to CDS during systemic TICs are contingent-CDS. They become normal times. That crises but not during activated only when a systemic crisis arises. is, By targeting the event that needs protection, this contingent feature significantly lowers the cost of insurance for financial institutions and therefore raises the protection they can be required to hold for unit of systemic Note also that TICs' tradability system would be Lehman better misbehaving institution To conclude, is to V. remove of the Final most fails, did and failed), at protected as they against dire need. And if distressed risk their survival for a higher the very least the rest of the financial the turmoil would be holding the that could arise if the TICs. important to highlight that the point of these insurance arrangements it is (for a fee) institutions, while many in chose to not seek to stock up on TICs and return (as probably they choose to hold. would allow private agents to use markets to reallocate the access to insurance toward financial institutions institutions risk amount of the systemic risk from leveraged and interconnected financial they continue to produce the triple-A assets whose shortage main global macroeconomic phenomena of the last is behind two decades. Remarks The world entered the current emerged from it financial crisis with a shortage of safe financial assets with an even more acute deficit. The crisis itself was the and result of the collapse of the financial industry created to bridge the original gap, and of the severe panic caused by the chaotic unraveling of this complex industry. with this dual problem — the shortage of safe assets and the financial by the private sector's solutions to absorb a larger resort, and not it share of the systemic would include modifying One approach — is risk their portfolios for fragility governments around the world (and be compensated for it). to deal created explicitly This approach and becoming the provider of insurance of lost just the lender of last resort, for widespread panics. 37 Bibliography Acharya, Viral and V. "Do 2009. Schnabl. Philipp Banks Global Spread Imbalances? The Case of Asset-Backed Commercial Paper During the Financial Global Crisis of 2007-09." November. Acharya, Viral V. and Philipp Schnabl. 2009. Chapter 2 Stability: Acharya, Viral V. and in How John Wiley & "How Banks Played the Leverage 'Game'", Matthew Richardson, to Repair a Failed System, New eds., Restoring Financial York University Stern School of Business, Sons. Acharya, Viral V., Lasse Pedersen, "Regulating Systemic Risk." Thomas NYU mimeo, Philippon and Matthew Richardson. 2009. January. Adelino, Manuel. 2009. "Do Investors Rely Only on Ratings? The Case of Mortgage- Backed Scurities." MIT mimeo, November. Adrian, Tobias and Hyun Song Shin. 2009. "Money, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Liquidity, Brunnermeier, Markus Press, NY. and Lasse Heje Pedersen. 2009. "Deciphering the K. Credit Crunch 2007-08," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. Caballero, Ricardo Crisis ." 2009a. J., " Dow Boost and Policy." Vol. 99, No. 2. CDS Delivery Options. Bloomberg Boberski, David. 2009. and Monetary a (Nearly) Private 1, Liquidity and 77-100. Sector Solution to the VOX, February 22. Caballero, Ricardo J., 2009b. " A Global Perspective on the Great Financial Insurance Run; Causes, Consequences, and Solutions ." MIT mimeo, January 20. Caballero, Ricardo The of Money: Role J., 2006. " On the Macroeconomics Money and Monetary Policy in of the Asset Shortafies ." Twenty-First In Century 38 The Fourth European Central Banking Conference 9-10 November, Andreas Beyer and Lucrezia Reichlin, editors. Pages 272-283. Caballero, Ricardo 2003. J., " The Future of the IMF ." American Economic Review, Papers and Proceeding, 93(2), 31-38, May. Caballero, Ricardo Crash, Commodity Activity, Fall, Emmanuel J., Prices, Farhi and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2008a. " Financial and Global Imbalances ." Brookings Papers on Economic pp 1-55. Caballero, Ricardo Equilibrium Model J., Emmanuel Farhi of "Global Imbalances" and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, 2008b. " An and Low Interest Rates ." American Economic Review, 98:1, pgs 358-393. Caballero, Ricardo Fragility, " and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2009. J. " Global Imbalances and Financial American Economic Review, May. Caballero, Ricardo a Flight to Quality and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2008a. J. " Collective Risk Episode ." Journal of Finance, Vol. 63, Issue Caballero, Ricardo J. 5, Volatility: Ricardo J. " and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2006. in October. and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2008b. "Knightian uncertainty and implications for the TARP," Financial Times Economists' Forum, Caballero, ManaRement November its 24. Bubbles and Capital Flow Causes and Risk Management ." Journal Monetary of Economics, 53(1), pp. 35- 53, January. Caballero, Ricardo J. and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2001. Collateral Constraints in a Model of Emerging Market " International and Domestic Crises ." Journal of Monetary Economics 48(3), 513-548, December Caballero, Ricardo J. and Pablo Kurlat, 2009. " Public-Private Partnerships for Liquidity Provison ." MIT mimeo, March. 39 Caballero, Ricardo Remarks and Caballero, and Pablo J. a Literature Ricardo Flight to Quality and Bailouts: Policy Review ." MIT mimeo, October. and J. " Kurlat, 2008. Stavros Panageas, " 2008. Hedging Sudden Stops and Precautionary Contractions ." Journal of Development Economics, 85 pp 28-57. Caballero, Ricardo J. and Stavros Panageas, 2007. Sudden Stops and External Caballero, Ricardo J. Liquidity " A Global Equilibrium Model of Management." MIT mimeo, September. " and Alp Simsek, 2009a. Complexity and Financial Panics ." MIT mimeo, June. Caballero, Ricardo mimeo, J. and Alp Simsek, 2009b. " Fire Sales in a Model of Complexity ." MIT July. Calvo, Guillermo A. 2005. "Crises in Emerging Market Economies: A Global Perspective," NBER Working Paper No. 11305. Calvo, Guillermo A. and Economic Collpase Latin in Talvi, Ernesto. 2005. "Sudden Stop, Financial Factors and America: Learning from Argentina and Chile," NBER Working Paper No. W11153. Calvo, Guillermo A., Izquierdo, Alejandro and Talvi, Ernesto. 2006. Phoenix Miracles Caplin, in Emerging Markets," American Economic Review 96(2), Andrew and John May Leahy, 2004. "Business as Usual, Market Crashes and after the Fact," American Economic Review, pp. 548-565. Coval, Joshua D., Bonds." "Sudden Stops and Jakub W. Jurek and Erik Stafford. 2006. Wisdom 2008. "Economic Catastrophe HBS Finance Working Paper No. 07-102. Coval, Joshua D., Jakub W. Jurek and Erik Stafford. 2009. "The Economics of Structured Finance." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23, No. 1, Winter. 40 and Coval, Joshua, Erik Stafford. 2007. "Asset Fire Sales (and Purchases) Markets," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 86, No. 2, in Equity November. Mark, 2002, "No Pain, No Gain? Effecting Market Discipline via 'Reverse Flannery, Convertible Debentures'," Working Paper, November. and Lawrence Summers. 2009. "A Geithner, Timothy, Washington New Financial Foundation." Post, June 15 Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier and Helene Rey. 2007. "From World Banker to World Venture US External Adjustment and The Exorbitant Capitalist: editor, G7 Privilege," in Richard Clarida, Current Account Imbalances: Sustainability and Adjustment, The University of Chicago Press, pp. 11-55. Gorton, Gary 2008. "The Panic of 2007." B. Financial System. Proceedings of the Bank of Kansas Gorton, Gary Gorton, in a Changing 2008 Jackson Hole Conference, Federal Reserve City. and Andrew Metrick. 2009. "Haircuts." NBER B., Gary Maintaining the Stability In B., and Nicholas Souleles. 2006. WP #15273, "Special Purpose Securitization." In The Risks of Financial Institutions, edited by Rene August. Vehicles Stulz and and Mark Carey. University of Chicago Press. Hart, Oliver Institutions." and Luigi Zingales. 2009. "A New Capital Regulation for Large Financial Harvard mimeo. September Holmstrom, Bengt. 2008. "Comment on: 'The Panic of 2007,' by Gary Gorton," Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System, Federal Reserve of Kansas City at Jackson Hole, Investment Company Institute. in Symposium sponsored by The Wyoming. 2009. Report of the Money Market Working Group. 41 Monetary Fund. 2009. Global Financial International Stability Report: Navigating the Financial Challenges Ahead, October. Kashyap, Anil Regulation," K., Raghuram G. Rajan and Jeremy Maintaining Stability in in C. Stein. 2008. "Rethinking Capital a Changing Financial System, Symposium sponsored by The Federal Reserve of Kansas City at Jackson Hole, Wyoming. Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jorgenses, 2007. "The Aggregate for Treasury Debt," Kellogg Lehman Demand mimeo. Brothers. 2008. "Residential Credit Losses - Going into Extra Innings?" Mehrling, Perry and Alistair Milne, 20008. "Government's role as credit insurer of resort and how it can be fulfilled," mimeo Milne, Alistair. 2009. The Fall of the Cambridge and New last October. House of Credit. Cambridge University Press, York. Office of the Special Inspector General for the Troubled Asset Relief Program. 2009. Quarterly Report to Congress, July. Wayne W. Roxburgh, Charles, Susan Lund, Charles Atkins, Stanislas Belot, Pierce. 2009. "Global Capital Markets: Entering a New Era," McKinsey Global report. September. Squam Lake Working Group on Financial Regulation. 2009. Mechanism Tett, Gillian. Hu, Moira " S. Institute An Expedited Resolution for Distressed Financial Firms: Regulatory Hybrid Securities ." April. 2009. Fool's Gold: How Unrestrained Greed Corrupted a Dream, Shattered Global Markets and Unleashed a Catastrophe. Little, Woodford, Michael. 1990. "Public Debt as Private Brown. Liquidity," The American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 2 (May), pp. 382-88. 42