MIT LIBRARIES DUPL FMHJilliillll 3 9080 02618 4579 ^'^''lllil!:; i Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/institutionalchaOOeeck L/L:^yyfcr ^ B31 4415 6/1 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Institutional Change in the Non-Market Endogenous Matching Economy: Chennai's Chit Fund Auctions in Jan Eeckhout Kaivan Munshi Working Paper 03-01 December 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 02142 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Network Paper Collection at Social Science Research http://papers.ssrn. com/paper.taf?abstract_id=xxxxx http://papers.ssm.com/abstract_id4572801 3 Change Institutional Endogenous Matching Non-Market Economy: in the Chennai's Chit Fund Auctions* in Jan Eeckhout^ Kaivan Munshi* December 2002 Abstract This paper tests the proposition that non-market institutions can respond flexibly to changes in the economic environment that they operate in, using data from Chennai's chit fund auctions. These auctions bring borrowers and lenders together 1993, legal restrictions exogenously capped the of endogenous matching is proposed, in Data small groups, and starting from September in the auctions. A theory which borrowers and lenders sort themselves into groups with different characteristics, which also predicts policy experiment. in amount that could be bid collected before and how after the new institution settles remarkably quickly into its the participants will re-sort following the experiment reveals that this non-market equilibrium. Consistent with the theory, a completely different composition of borrowers and lenders in the groups, and a completely different group structure is observed. Keywords. Roscas. Non-market Institutions. Endogenous Matching. Financial Intermediation. JEL. 012. 017. G20. D40. Introduction 1 The importance and the persistence of non-market institutions in developing economies has gener- ated a great deal of interest among economists While the analysis of comparative in recent years. agrarian institutions, notably sharecropping, has a long history in the economics literature, this line of research has been extended over the last decade to rotating savings *We thank Ajit Menon and in collecting the data. cicJ his team of Poorti Marino, field investigators, Nauman support from the McArthur Foundation, and Newman, is lison, Sergei gratefully acknowledged. and the staff at and credit associations Shriram Chit Funds, and Aldo Colussi provided superb research for their assistance assistance. Finan- initial collaboration on this project with Patrick Legros and Andrew Ilias We have benefited from many helpful discussions with R. Chandrasekar, Glenn El- Izmalkov, R. Kanan, George Mailath, Marco Manacorda, Steve Matthews, Volker Nocke, Nancy Rose, R. Sadanandam, R. Thyagarajan, and seminar participants 'University of Pennsylvania, eeckhout@ssc.upeiin.edu ^University of Pennsylvania (Besley, and MIT, munshiOmit edu . at UPenn, Maryland, Andy MIT and Postlewaite, Georgetown. Coate and Loiiry 1993, 1994), cooperatives (Banerjee, Besley and Guinnane 1995), mutual insurance arrangements (Townsend 1994), and informal credit institutions (Udry 1994). The prevailing view this research is that non-market institutions are opportunistic arrangements that exploit social ties to overcome information, enforcement, and coordination problems. Despite these institutions may still their obvious inefficiencies, do better than their competitors when market institutions function imper- In this view, non-market institutions should not be seen as vestiges of a traditional economy, fectly. dominated by tutions may social ties and reciprocal exchange, that encouraged, or at the very least been the case The essentially hinder change. Instead, these insti- economy actually play an active role in the transition from the traditional market economy. As a policy recommendation, in many left this suggests that alone, instead of being discoiuraged and strictly regulated as we have just described relies more appropriate as the economic environment changes over the course of the development process. empirical work that studies how different the economic environment that they operate may in.^ marriage and traditional societies (see, for example, se, position in this paper Non-market institutions, But there has in institutions often use social sanctions is fertility and such social has been documented to be remarkably rigid in Munshi and Myaux that this rigidity is 2002). not a feature of non-market institutions per but a consequence of the restrictions that sometimes keep them social regulation will decline as these institutions evolve, improvement on the leave these institutions relatively unresponsive to change. Consistent with this view, social regulation surrounding Our has non-market institutions respond to changes to ensure that individuals do not deviate from cooperative patterns of behavior, regulation modern developing economies. optimistic assessment of non-market institutions that little to the non-market institutions should be idea that these institutions will alter their structure, or be replaced by been in in their flexibility. We which has evolved to the point where test this it The importance in place. of and we would expect to see a corresponding view by studying a classic non-market institution, displays several features, such as relative anonymity competition, that are associated with the market. As expected, we and will see this particular institution respond swiftly and appropriately to an exogenous economic change. The subject of this paper is the rotating savings and credit association (Rosea). Roscas are informal financial institutions, which are popular throughout the developing world, and are even found among migrant groups in the U.S. and other advanced economies. In Rosea consists of a small group of individuals with amount of money to a "pot," at fixed intervals of time. period, either by lot or by auction, In its social ties to each other The amount and each participant in in the its traditional form, the who pot is contribute a fixed disbursed in each the Rosea receives the pot once only. simplest form, as analyzed by Besley, Coate and Loury (1993, 1994), the Rosea facilitates the consumption of consumer durables. For example, imagine that ten residents of a village get together Previous empirical work on non-market institutions has typically taken a static approach to analyze the structure and the performance of these institutions (as in Udry 1994, Banerjee et al. 2001). to save ten dollars each every month. one hundred dollars. Once a member first month, won the participant has period until every all interested in purchasing a bicycle, which costs each individual saved independently If month, starting from the autarky. are With the random Rosea, one member the bicycle. in each They group drawn at random receives the bicycle of the so everyone pot, he must would take him ten months to buy it at least as well off as they is still would be in continue to contribute his share in each of the group has received the pot, so social ties play an important role in ensuring that the Rosea participants do not renege on their institutional obligations. Turning to the setting of this paper, while simple South India, the institution that we study system was nationalized in in this Roscas have been popular paper is based in the city. for centuries in rural The Indian banking known the early 1970s, and the urban Roscas, or chit funds as they are in South India, emerged shortly them legal loop-hole that allowed Chit funds apparently took advantage of a after nationalization. to function as financial intermediaries, in competition with the banks, as long as their organizational structure precisely matched the basic structure of the simple Roscas described above. that members What distinguishes the urban chit funds from their rural predecessors is of a group have no direct social ties to each other. Large companies bring thousands of participants together into these small groups, and the organizers, in exchange for a participation fee, are responsible for any defaults that an auction (often an English auction) all the members of the in may Moreover, the pot occur. each period. The bid amount group as a "dividend" . is is now dispersed through among distributed equally This process continues, with a fresh auction in each period, until aU the participants have received the pot once - there is of course no auction and no dividend in the final period. Although the participants is still in the urban chit funds a social aspect to the institution. centuries, and so it is level of trust and even in Edison, While the simple Rosea similar characteristics, the The Participants can be sustained even New is in the city. is chit is this paper is mechanism that played company that very much a non-market Tamil institution. typically brings together individuals with fund acts as a financial intermediary, matching borrowers and who wins generated over the course of the chit fund. rate that is away as Mumbai, on the western coast the pot early are effectively borrowers, while those it is almost generated endogenously within a group acts as the interest payment. effectively lenders - the participant within the group, and far Indeed, while the is Jersey, such forays are always restricted to the expatriate a sa\'ings urban dividend that who win other personally, there South India, where participants understand how the game community. The institution that we study in lenders. know each Chit funds have been popular in rural South India for provided us with the data has organized a few groups as of India, not not surprising that the urban version of this traditional institution entirely restricted to centers in and where some may last receives his principal in The dividend thus consequently not at all reflects the who wait until the end are return for all the dividends competitive price of capital surprising that the chit funds generate an interest at least 3-4 percentage points higher than what could be obtained by depositing capital in the monopsonistic banking system (James Raj Commission Report 1975).^ Businesses, and borrowers in general, also benefit Not from this institution, since credit so severely rationed by the banks. is surprisingly, chit funds have captured a substantial share of the credit market over time. Starting with almost no registered companies in the 1970s, deposits in registered chit funds were 10% estimated to be roughly of the volume of bank deposits by 1993 (Bouman 1995), and 15% of the deposits in the South Indian state of Tamil Nadu in the neighboring state of Kerala (where chit funds play a more prominent role in the local economy) in 1987 (Shah and Johnson 1989). report that the in amount of credit made Tamil Nadu and 25% of the credit available by the in Kerala.^ chit The same sources fund companies was 12.5% of bank credit Chit funds clearly provide serious competition to the banking system, at least in South India, where they are most prevalent. As discussed in Section 2, government regulators and the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) were quick to notice the emerging popularity of this non-market institution. RBI reports from as early as the 1970s explicitly identify chit funds as direct competitors to the banking system, and take note of the higher interest rates that these institutions could provide. ultimately led to the passing of the Chit strict Efforts to regulate the chit funds Fund Act by the Indian parliament in 1982, which down guidehnes uniformly regulating the functioning of this institution throughout the country. For our purpose, the most significant feature of the Chit Fund Act was the imposition of a the bids - continuing with our simple example, this says that the maximum dollar pot could not exceed thirty dollars. This restriction effectively chit funds could generate, were successful wound upheld in The its initially, its 30% in we will exploit in the empirical analysis. inefficiencies associated with the chit fund - trade These is is obtained from a single chit fund restricted within the inefficiencies are group and the oppor- unavoidable since the chit funds to a precise organizational structure, as specified by law, in order to be allowed to function. Yet, they appear to compete very effectively with the banking system; the interest rate calculations that we report later paper suggest that the difference Our the structure of the institution responded to this exogenous change in tunities for inter-temporal substitution are severely limited. must adhere But the case ceihng in 1993, eleven years after the passing of the Chit Fund Act, the economic environment. The data that we use for the analysis There are obvious in 1983. They ceiling. September 1993. provides an exogenous institution-specific shock, which how 30% and the 1982 Chit Fund Act was ultimately judicial system, by the Supreme Court objective will be to study on capped the interest rate that the winning a stay order from the Madras High Court imposition of the ceiling narrowing their comparative advantage over the banks. Not surprisingly, way through the Indian entirety 30% bid for the one hundred the chit fund companies went to court, seeking to overturn the imposition of the slowly set in interest rates in this between chit funds and the nationalized banks could be as high as 9 percentage points. Statistics to from the references cited above are combined with barrking compute these numbers. There non-market institution along the same in lines, in is httle doubt that these statistics from Reserve Bank of India documents statistics substantially underestimate the importance of this the local economy, since they do not account for the myriad unregistered chit funds, organized these states. company, one of the largest in the country, with branches in multiple set provides the value of the bid paid in the city of by the winner Chennai (formerly known in each period the the groups that The data commenced is - one the business and financial center of the one company runs as many as 20 neighborhood branches in city. The chit fund company offers a for potential participants to is this in all states. Madras) from September 1992 to September 1994 as year before and one year after the policy shock. Chennai South Indian regional economy, and South Indian menu of groups, with different durations borrowers and lenders. In this application, privately records account for average much 20% roughly earlier is the chit fund essentially brings together a "corporate subscriber". These subscribers, participants, are financial companies than the "individual subscribers." This we net borrowers, and all earlier, easy to single out borrowers, since the organizing is it whether a participant of chit values (pot sizes) choose from. Individual participants join independently, and once a group formed, the auction occurs every month. As noted company and will therefore treat the is who tend who to win the auction on consistent with the view that they are corporate subscribers as borrowers and the individual subscribers as lenders in the empirical analysis. Later in Section 3 we lenders), which is will present a simple model of the chit fund with two types (borrowers and solved in two stages. In the by choosing from a menu first stage, chit fund participants endogenously of funds of different durations, offered by the chit fund organizer. match The first stage equihbrium strategy determines the proportion of borrowers and lenders in the different funds that are offered. In the second stage, the auction is executed in which the pattern of equilibrium bids determines the expected payoff, for a given proportion of borrowers and lenders. Based on the equilibrium expected payoff of the auction, the proportion of borrowers acts Walrasian "price" in this institution, adjusting to leave types of chit funds in equilibrium. as a each agent indifferent between the various Without a participation price for each auction to guide them, individuals use the composition of borrowers and lenders in each type of group to arrive at the decentralized equilibrium. This endogenous matching and in addition, it is a novel contribution to the auction literature^, provides the following main predictions: First, the proportion of borrowers, as a result of the equilibrium matching, will vary systematically with the duration of the group. Second, the change in the proportion of borrowers following the policy experiment will depend on the extent to which bids were capped by the This is precisely 30% what we observe in the duration of the group in the ceiling. in the data in Section 4. The proportion of borrowers is dechning unconstrained equilibrium (prior to the bid-cap), across the range of pot values. The proportion of borrowers also increases disproportionately after the policy experiment in the long duration groups, which were capped most severely, as predicted by the theory. Remember that participants join independently, and so do not observe any signals about the attractiveness of ^Endogenous matching has recently received more attention. In an interesting paper, Ackerberg and Botticini (2002) analyze the impact of matching on contracts. long or short duration funds ex ante. Their matching decisions are merely based on their beliefs about other participants' decisions, and it is thus quite remarkable that participants respond so sharply to the change in the economic environment in this non-market institution. We chit complete the empirical analysis in Section 5 by studying the change the structure of the in fund institution over time. The model predicts a re-sorting of borrowers and lenders into groups 30% of different durations as a consequence of the One ceiling. implication of this re-sorting is that the proportion of short duration groups will also shift in response to the policy experiment. Indeed, we will see a the imposition of the dramatic increase in the proportion of these groups immediately following 30% and some overshooting And even though ceiling. initially, this there does appear to be some shaking out new equilibrium, with non-market institution settles into its a significantly higher fraction of short duration groups, in about two years. striking endorsement for the view that non-market institutions can be very responsive to changes in the economic environment that they operate The paper concludes This result provides in Section 6 with in. some additional comments on the long-term institutional response to the policy experiment and a brief discussion on the regulation of non-market institutions. The 2 Institutional Setting This section begins with a brief discussion on the prevalence and the importance of Roscas throughout the world. We pay particular attention to variation time, since this tells us something about the commercial chit fund, which events leading lies 2.1 The is up to the imposition in the structmre of this institution over its flexibility. Subsequently we describe the organization of the focus of this paper, in some detail. Finally, of the 30% ceiling, space and which is we dociunent the the exogenous policy experiment that at the heart of the empirical analysis. The Prevalence and the Importance generally accepted definition of a Rosea formed upon a core of participants who agree is to of Roscas provided by Ardener (1964:201): make An association regular contributions to a fund which is given, in whole or in part, to each contributor in rotation. Institutions matching this description are found in urban and rural areas throughout the developing world (Geertz 1962 and Ardener 1964 provide comprehensive surveys), and even among migrant groups instance, describes Roscas organized by in West Indian immigrants throughout sub-Saharan Africa report that 50-80% of adult and credit groups, which include Roscas (Bouman 1995). participate in Roscas (hut) in a typical year (Levenson setting for this study, one million subscribers registered chit funds in 1993 advanced economies (Bonnet 1981, (8% in the U.S.). Numerous men and women for studies from participate in savings In Taiwan, at least and Besley 1996). And 20% in of households Tamil Nadu, the of the adult urban population) were entered in (Vaidyanathan and Sriram 2000). Apart from their popularity, Roscas also play an important world. Credit granted through Roscas {tontine) in in the country (Schrieder and Cuevas 1992) and role in local Cameroon was about 27% in Ethiopia, we noted of the credit available in South in the previous section that credit credit in the South Indian states of of all loan requirements the 1968-73 Development Plan estimated the annual savings volume through Roscas {ekubs) to be 8-10% of hms provided 20-25% economies throughout the GDP (Begashaw 1978). In Asia, Vietnam during 1965-75 (Bouman 1995), and provided by registered chit funds was 12.5-25% of bank Tamil Nadu and Kerala. While the Rosea may enjoy a substantial presence throughout the world, the popularity and the structure of the institution does vary across broad geographical areas. In Africa, for example, Roscas are concentrated in the more commercially developed regions of West Africa, and are particularly widespread in Cameroon and Nigeria (Geertz 1962). Similar regional variation well, and both informal and registered Kerala, Tamil Nadu and Andhra No calculated, interest is chit funds are concentrated in the three Pradesh. and bidding is The is observed in India as South Indian states of structure of the institution also varies geographically. absent, throughout Africa (Geertz 1962). In contrast, East Asian Roscas often use complex procedures to distribute the dividend, and both random and bidding Roscas are widely prevalent throughout Asia (Ardener 1964). The structure of the Rosea also depends on whether it is organized in the village or the Roscas tend to be informal, consisting of members with social typically is institutions in more as a The pot is social ties to each other are typically auctioned in each period, financial intermediary, bringing borrowers savings institution in which homogeneous individuals There are two basic explanations anonymous In contrast, urban Roscas are usually which individuals without previous professional organizer. match and brought together by a this variant of the and lenders together, than Rosea as a pure together. for the observed diversity of the essentially anthropological, explanation (due to Geertz 1962) reflects each other. 10-15 individuals form a group (Begashaw 1987, Campbell and Ahn 1962, Fernando 1986), and the pot distributed by drawing lots in each period. functions ties to Rural city. is Rosea institution. The first, that the structure of the institution the underlying culture of the participants. Thus urban Roscas differ from rural Roscas because individuals in the city are more "commercially" continue to dominate in the village. Changes oriented, whereas norms in the institution over of cooperative behavior time then reflect changes in underlying individual values and preferences. In contrast, the second, classical economic explanation for the observed diversity in the Roscas is that the structure of the institution responds to exogenous changes in the economic environment, while individual preferences remain stable. In this paper, we provide direct support for the second view by analyzing the institutional response to an exogenous economic shock, under the plausible assumption that endowments and preferences remain stable over the short two-year period that we consider. in the population The Organization 2.2 While traditional commercial chit funds fund chit is Commercial Chit Fund of the have been widely prevalent South Indian villages in a relatively recent phenomenon. for centuries, the Ardener (1964) places the emergence of commercially organized 'Chit Fund Groups' at the beginning of the twentieth century, mostly in Chennai, and to some extent in Travancore and Cochin. But these commercial chit funds appear to have been quite fund company rare, in even as late as the 1970s. Anderson (1962) tells us that the registered chit first Hyderabad, the capital of Andhra Pradesh and another important center fund activity today - the S.N. Chit Fund Co. - was founded in 1951. Similarly, the for chit company that provided us with the data (Shriram Chits and Investments Pvt. Ltd.), one of the oldest and most established companies in Chennai, was founded in 1974. From our discussions with the founders of the company, there were only a handful of commercial chit fund companies in Chennai prior to that date. The Indian financial system was nationalized in the early 1970s, after which only specially des- Non-Bank Financial Companies (NBFCs) were permitted ignated aries, in competition with the government banks. Companies that operate were criteria first laid to function as financial intermedi- One such NBFC was the commercial chit fund.^ number as registered chit funds have to satisfy a of specific criteria. These out in Section 2(2) of the Madras Chit Fimds Act, 1961, which regulated the institution in the state of Tamil Nadu. Subsequently they were adopted in their entirety in the Miscellaneous Non-Banking Companies Directions, 1973, issued by the Reserve ultimately in Section 2(b) of the central Chit Fund Act, "Chit" means a transaction whether called chit fund, its foreman them and [the Bank of India, and 1982, which applies to the entire country: chit, kuri, or by any other name, by which company] enters into an agreement with a number of subscribers that every one of shall subscribe a certain sum or a certain quantity of grain by installments for a definite period that each subscriber in his turn as determined by lot or by auction or by tender or in such other manner as may be provided for in the agreement shall be entitled to a prize amount. Notice that this legal definition of a chit fund matches closely with Ardener's (1964) general definition of a Rosea that we provided earlier. As long as the chit fund is organized precisely along the lines laid out above, the company can operate as a financial intermediary, regxilated by the Registrar of Chit Funds in each state, rather than by the Reserve Chit fund companies organize their subscribers into groups. month to auction the pot. contributes per month, and reflects the number of A group its duration members in is characterized by the (in of India. Members amount of of a group meet once a money that each months). Since the group meets each month, the group. ^According to the Reserve Bank's definition, Bank NBFCs subscriber its In our data, obtained from one chit fund duration company include equipment leasing companies, hire purchcise financing companies, loan companies, investment companies, mutual benefit financial companies {nidhis), miscellaneous non- banking companies (chit funds), residuary non-banking companies, and housing finance companies. ^ month ranges from Rs.250 over the 1993-94 period, the contribution per rate was roughly Rs.25 to the dollar at that time). to Rs.25,000 (the exchange The duration ranges from 20 months to 100 months. The subscriber thus has a menu of groups to choose from. Our chit fund company runs 20 neighborhood branches, spread throughout the have no social ties Chennai. Individual subscribers city of with other members of their group. Individuals join independently, and a group complete when the number of subscribers who have signed on, company will typically Funds applies to the Registrar of Chit commence throughout at that point to company coordinates the year, the campaigns around Pongal, the Tamil is New Year commence the chit. The While groups participation by organizing enrollment and the Divali (Ayudha Puja) in April, October. 78,000 subscribers joined 2,000 groups equal to the posted duration. is festival in our chit fund company, in Chennai city alone, in in 1993-94. Since participants have no social ties to each other, the social sanctions that prevent default in the traditional Rosea have no bite in the commercial chit funds. for defaults in this case. The company must assume Most subscribers provide three guarantors, who are respected members the community, and according to the branch manager's discretion, a subscriber to pledge property or other assets when he wins company arrears. Default rates are very low - less 5% than of the group, organizes the English auction on for its services, subsequently receives As noted 5% in is The company our data. first presumably one way we discovered in be required a list is facilitates the formation responsible for defaults. pot without competitive bidding, and of the chit value (the value of the pot) in each they win the auction. Their promoters are most also take him to court to realize the premises each month, and its "finance companies," in the data. These companies fund, and this will typically the company receives the in the previous section, may of the pot. In the event that a subscriber nevertheless reneges on his institutional responsibility, the As compensation responsibility number month. of corporate subscribers, listed as no guarantors and provide no security when likely socially connected to the organizers of the chit which high default rates can be avoided while maintaining a sufficiently high imphcit interest rate to encourage depositors. For the purpose of the statistical analysis that follows, the presence of the finance companies allows us to conveniently partition each group into borrowers and lenders. Consistent with this view subscribers bid higher and win the pot on average corporate subscribers account for approximately feature of the empirical analysis will be to see the imposition of the 30% This compensation scheme much 20% of we earlier all will see later that the corporate than the private subscribers. The the participants, and one important how the proportion of these subscribers responded to ceifing in 1993. is precisely laid subsequently adopted without modification down in Section 13 of the in Section 21 of the central Madras Chit Funds Chit Funds Act, 1982. Act, 1961, and was ^ The 2.3 Policy Experiment Government and particularly the Reserve Bank of regulators, growth of the India, were quick to take note of the and other NBFCs, following the nationalization chit funds of the banking system. Sev- committees were appointed to study the working of these companies, prominent among them eral being the Bhabatosh Datta Commission (1971) and the James Raj Commission (1975). These committees that while felt many NBFCs frequently resorted to unfair methods, and therefore needed to be regulated, prohibiting them entirely would adversely limited access to bank economy that had affect certain sectors of the credit, or chose not to deposit their money with case of the commercial chit fund companies, these study groups the banks. For the particular recommended a Model to be Bill, enacted as a Central Act of Parliament, to ensure uniform regulation throughout the country. They recommended that the administration also The Government The 1982. of India acted central chit fund act of the legislation should be left to the state governments. on these recommendations and passed the Chit Fund Act in was modelled to a large extent on the Miscellaneous Non-Banking Companies Directions, an interim regulatory document issued by the Reserve Bank in 1973, which in turn was modelled closely on the Madras Chit Funds Act of 1961, which regulated the institution in the state of Tamil Nadu. Implementation of the Act was The 1982 Act departed most notably from state. The left to the Registrar of Chit Funds in each the 1961 Act by imposing a 30% ceiling on the bids. stated reason for the ceiling was to protect the depositors from defaults that would occur when the bids were pushed too high - this would be the standard story with adverse selection or moral hazard, in which only risky investors participate or only risky projects are chosen are high. But it is interest rates very likely that the interest rates were also capped to restrict competition from the fund companies, since chit when it was well understood that the higher interest rates that these companies could provide was perhaps their principal comparative advantage over the banks. Not surprisingly the were chit initially successful, and the Madras High Court granted a stay order provisions of the 1982 Chit work its way through the Supreme Court in fund companies went to court over the imposition of the Funds Act, including the 30% coinrts, and We will As its it is it reasonable to treat the 30% ceiling imposed in fund company prior to 1961 from commercial banks compete with the monetary system and [therefore] there chit level, always difficult to predict and the numerous appeals that were is commencement is its completion. September 1993, a the Shah Commission report (1992:20), prepared for the Reserve Bank, put The Funds However, the case did ultimately legal backlog, in the Indian judicial system, differential as a motivating factor for transfers of deposits NBFCs 1984 on a number of would only have added to the uncertainty surrounding the timing of thus find They numerous appeals the stay order was vacated by the September 1993. Given the enormous when a case will come up for hearing filed in this case after ceiling.® in ceiling. to it: full eleven The importance of interest NBFCs zs well recognized ... The need to regulate them. required to deposit a fixed proportion of the value of the pot with the Registrar of Chit of the group as security. The required deposit level was increased in the 1982 Act over which was another issue that the chit fund companies took to court. 10 j'ears after the passing of the 1982 Chit Funds Act, as an unpredicted pohry shock. analysis will compare the formation 1993, Over a longer period of time, of chit fund groups, one year before we A 3 its after empirical September study the speed at which the institution was able to will also respond to the policy shock, and settle into and one year The new equilibrium. Simple Model of Chit Fund Auctions We now proceed to formalize the formation of groups and the pattern of bids in the chit fund auctions. In this simple model, there are two types of participants: high types and low types. High types have superior investment opportunities, and because in equilibrium they collect the pot earlier on average than the low types, we will often refer to two stages. The them as the borrowers. The low types are the lenders. the matching stage. Each agent chooses to participate solve the model in a chit fund of a certain duration, based on the expected future payoff from that chit fund. in first stage is We The second stage determines the payoff from the auction. Given a menu of payoff. We chit funds, the participant chooses that will see that fund that maximizes her expected future the proportion of high types acts as a price in this institution, adjusting to leave each agent indifferent between the various types of chit funds in equihbrium. For example, exogenous shock increases the payoffs that the high types receive in one type of if an chit fund, relative to the other funds that are available, then this will generate an inflow of high types into that chit fund (which lowers the payoffs that they receive) until indifference is restored once again. Section 3.1 describes the population and preferences, the matching technology and the auction technology. We solve the model backwards, starting in Section 3.2 with the pattern of bids in the second stage auction, and the payoffs that the participants receive. derives the first stage sorting equilibrium. The Subsequently, Section 3.3 analysis concludes in Section 3.4 by studying the proportion of high types, in groups of different durations, responds to the exogenous on bids that was put in place in September 1993. This 30% how ceiling will later allow' us to empirically identify the presence of underlying endogenous matching. Population, Preferences, and the Auction Technology 3.1 3.1.1 Population and Preferences Let there be a continuum of infinitely lived chit fund participants. Each participant observable type 7,7 e is fj, -^ 7, 7 , f where 7 > 7 and where the proportion of high types and the proportion of low types is 1 — fi. Participants of type 7 access to a deterministic investment opportunity with a retxurn agents derives from the return on the investment opportunity. returns from investment, we will often refer to 1 who manage + 7. The is indexed by an in the population to find finance have heterogeneity amongst Though both types can derive positive the high types 7 as borrowers and the low types 11 This follows from the fact that the high types 7 as lenders. and are therefore for funding, G Time [0, 1). is organizer of the chit fund offers a chit fund auction menu Thus, each chit fund group is W (7, A'^, p, v) participate in is decision. So the is W is determined as the equilibrium endogenously deter- menu only announces second stage subgame. in the as to maximize in W {'y,N,p,v) subject each chit fund equals proportion in the total population). For any interior solution, the proportion p acts as a make agents indifferent between different types of chit funds on the menu. will specify As a a p for each auction N,v. chit fund {N,p,v) , p is taken as given in the second stage. determines the expected payoff for each type W{'y, N, p, v). In Now each period = ( the auction technology 1, ..., A'^, all group contribute a rupee amount v to the fund, and at the same time, at each sealed bid auction is conducted in which the highest bid wins. Each auction only once, so that participants in the auction are have not won the auction and pays the highest t [0, 1]. The Auction Technology Given a N p fund organizer's chit and therefore choose N,v from the menu such an equilibrium matching 3.1.3 — course, the group p e in instantaneous and without frictions. All agents simultaneously decide which fund to balancing force to in a Of market clearing condition (that the aggregate number of high types initial result, and the proportion of high types the normalized expected payoff to an agent of type 7 from participation a chit auction {N,p,v), where Matching v, Each N, the contribution that of participants in the group characterized by a triple {N,p,v). mined by each individual's participation N, V. Denote of groups for potential participants to choose from. number characterized by the is each participant must make each period the constant discount factor discrete. The to the common and at a All participants are The Matching Technology 3.1.2 in have a higher willingness to pay early in the chit fund auction. maximizers who discount the future risk neutral utility 6 move willing to will participants, The set yet. bid. i.e. The winner The those up of the model is those A^ fund —i+ not is a first price member can win 1 chit receives the period's contribution of all bid paid by the winner who have all chit t participants the fund members who A'' participants Nv distributed equally amongst the remaining won the auction yet. consistent with the actual organization of the chit fund auction in that there are no restrictions on the information concerning past bids, or the identity of past winners. However, the model departs bidding as a well known guaranteed first in two ways from the actual chit fund auction. First, we model the price sealed bid auction instead of the English auction used in practice. It is that with private independent values and risk neutral bidders, revenue equivalence for both static auctions.^ In fact, the English auction Second, and the second A^ participants in the group, including the all is most price auction are strategically equivalent for static independent private 12 While the assumption recent winner, share the winning bid equally each period in practice. model does not change the nature of the auction, the advantage it we simplifies the expression for the continuation payoff that model analytically It is of the setup we have chosen Nv (1 + 7) + is player, in addition to her type The introduction ctj. out tie-breaking bids when there e - and as a 7 receives an result at - of the i.i.d. very small and approaches is signal b = (61,62, ..., 0. i.i.d. signal at in each period, 67V) indicates continuation payoff (conditional on not having ]/( = We solve matching We 6. won will use the short will consider equilibria where bt = (bt^kt) the bids all participants {^,b;N,p.v) denote the expected the auction in the past) at time hand notation to indicate Vt = t for player 7, Vt (7, 6; N ,p, v) the model backwards starting in the second stage. For the determination of the equihbrium in the Proposition first stage, 1 For all We t turns out that it we only need to derive the difference AVi = Vf — V^ therefore have the following result: N < AVi{N,p) = 8P^.-'AVn = and AVat A^i; [7 The proof is - 7I reported in the Appendix. In order to get the intuition for this result, we derive the = V'/v investing. in period A'u(l-f 7) Because t < pN v and a given proportion of high types p is the payoff in the last period, which in equilibrium, bids types remaining in period the bid 64. t. We 0. (i.e. can write the high type's as When With complementary is is 1/ [pN — t + 1) , where the individual wins, the payoff probability, the high type loses value auctions. Further, revenue equivalence is strategic equivalence, also between the English also equal to the return from by the high types always dominate those by the low types, the probability of winning for a high type less A'^, high types in the group) for the case where £ approaches expected payoff where (1) = Nv A 7- equilibrium continuation value of a given auction pN by Stage: Strategic Bidding (and in particular AVi). with in V((7,6;A^,p,i.). The Second 3.2 profile we the strategy profile of let Vj , type 7 for for technical convenience. It rules Denote the pair in a given chit fund. In a given chit fund auction (TV, p, u) and given a strategy is only one high type. Therefore, is each of the types. Then the vector and that tractable. assumed that each t is derive for each type and makes the with at uniformly distributed over [— £,e]. As a result, the valuation of the investment period in the pN - + t is first price auctions. 13 the number of high the return on investment Vyv and gets the discounted expected guaranteed between the second and and 1 is first price auctions, and because of payoff in the next period plus her share of the bid remaining players who have not won we show that In the appendix, to bid bt = — f^/v jjl.'[li that bt distributed equally amongst the is ~ t yet. for t = 1, — ...,pN 1, the equilibrium strategy of the high types ^^t+i)- The intuition behind this are competing with high types. N As a is that in is those periods, high types all bidding makes a player indifferent between winning result, the the auction today, and losing and getting the discounted continuation payoff and the share of the bid: yN — bt = ^^t+i + W^i- This implies that for = i 1, — ...,pN 1, the equilibrium expected payoff is given by Vt who For the low types, = VN-bt = + j^bt. lose for sure in the early periods, the Vt We 6Vt+i = ^Zt+i corresponding payoff AVi = In period t expressed as + jj^h. can now calculate AVt immediately from the equihbrium payoffs above: AVt recursively, is = 6AVt+i. Solving S^'^-'^AVpN. = pN, there is only one high type left, can win the auction for sure by offering e above the bid of the low type the symmetric support of at)- Therefore, for small are equihbrium bids. and she now competes with The low types bid up e, in period t = pN, all the low types. She (recall that e bt = bt = is ^_~*^ the bound of {V_fj — 6y_t^i) to the point where they are indifferent between winning the auction and losing. This implies Vt = VN-h Vt = SVt+^ Differencing the equations above, at t + j;^bt = VN-bt. = pN, AVpN = SP^~^AVj\f, giving us the result in Proposition AV/v. We = can therefore conclude that AVi 1. Before turning to the determination of the matching equilibrium in the first stage, we normalize the expected payoff from participation in the auction to account for the fact that different funds have different durations. For each type 7, the normalized payoff from participation in the chit fund is equal to Hence we can define AW{N,p) = W{N,p)-WiN,p) = I'yy^ = (2) J/;v Next, two comparative statics properties of the expected equilibrium payoff are derived. basic property of ^ Of course, p is AW is that it is first decreasing in p.^^ not a continuous variable for a finite the remainder of the discussion we will treat p (and is The N) easily verified that the properties of the derivatives N and given that p is the fraction of high types. However, for as continuous variables. This is without can be replicated using differences. 14 loss of generahty as it Lemma 1. Consider a fund and any N,6,v,^,'y. Then chit dAW{N.p) dp Proof. First, —— =" observe that d^ — .^ -r dp <0 Then ji dp l-S-"-' it immediatelj" follows from equation that (1) dAW 5p^-'^AVn dp 1-6^ N\n6 = AWN\n6<0 < since In 6 The 0. intuition for this result As p fairly straightforward. is between the increases, competition high types increases, pushing up the high types' bids in the early periods. Higher bids imply a higher revenue for the This makes the auction low types as the gains are distributed amongst the losers. relatively less attractive to the high types and more attractive to the low types, AW(N,p) i.e. decreases. The second basic property of AH'' Lemma Consider a 2. chit that is AW' is N decreasing in for sufficiently exists a 6* fund and any N,6,v^^,'). Then there low values of such that for 8 < 6. 6* dAW{N,p) dN Proof. Again, from equations dAW = Observe that as is positive for condition for 6 ^j^ < result, there exists The 3.3 We now a. is 6* 1, (1) it ^ -jjqit and as • pN + such that 1 < 0, 6 approaches < since ln8 for all 8 ^ 0. N8^' goes to In s] — oo. Thus, even A < 6*, 0, e~^ which impHes 6 < ^^^ < e if -377- sufficient [0, 1]. As a 0. Endogenous Matching is characterized by the number of participants belief about the proportion of high types p that belief must be consistent with utility alternative chit fund groups will Suppose that a menu A',, 6-pN + l){l- 8^) + must be negative for 6 sufficiently small (close to zero). that In^ > e"p^ = [(In proceed to describe the process by which participants sort themselves into chit fund groups. Each group fund follows that 6^^-^ . oi 8, First Stage: and vA", approaches some values (2) A'^, the chit fund value will decide to join the maximizing behavior. A fund A^, v. is In equilibrium, this W of each group. oifered to potential participants. there will be associated an equilibrium belief p(7Vi) denoted by 15 and the (common) potential participant choosing between compare the normalized continuation value of chit funds {N,p)^ v, p,. An Then for each chit endogenous matching . equilibrium requires every participant to choose that chit fund that maximizes the function W(7,Af,,pj) . different types of chit funds are to coexist, then the utihty If requires A^ £ argmax/v W solution to this problem is (7, A',p(j'V)) In the case of a . and implies interior^^, immediately that if AW {N,p) normalized value maximization symmetric equilibrium with two types, a W {j,N,,p,) = W {^,Nj,p,) ,y^,\/i^ It follows normahzed value condition (3) will also is satisfied for (3) J. both 7 and 7, then the difference in the be equalized across the chit funds: AW{N^,p^) = AW{Nj,p,),\fij^j. (4) In addition, a condition must be satisfied that requires the beliefs pi in each chit fund be consistent with the proportion n of high types in the entire population. Consider the case of two types 7, 7 with fractions p..! be rii. —n Then the out of a total of n participants. Let the measure of groups of type total We can now is J2i under n. endogenous matching equilibrium in the next Propo- the equilibrium proportion of high types efficient sorting, N = ^iNi state the characterization of the systematically related to Proposition i measure of participants sition. It says that is in equilibrium consistency condition requires i where the i exists a 6* such that for 5 Proof. From Lemma < 6* 2, it in each fund For the remainder of the discussion, we use the notation Pi . (Endogenous Matching) Consider any two 2 p [N) chit funds i,j with Ni endogenous matching equiUbrium follows that for 6 < satisfies p, > < = p {Ni) Nj. Then there pj. 6* AW {N,p) > AW {Nj,p) ,yp Ni since < Nj. Then, evaluated at p = p,, this implies AW{N^,p^)>AW{N,,p,) In equilibrium, AW {Ni,pi) — AW {Nj,pj) from equation AI^ Consider same first utility as join the fund. the case where = 0. Then > that AW (iV„p,) there are no gains from trade to the low types under autarky), while the high types do benefit from funds where p On the other hand, from the low types are better always p {N,,p,) (4), so off). A similar Lemma 1, = 0. (i.e. As a they results, will receive the high types will the high types are relatively worse off as more high types enter (and argument apphes to the case where p exists. 16 = 1, and as a result, an interior solution Lemma This implies, from The 1, intuition for this result duration groups, for a given to equalize The 3.4 The law will > p-,, which estabhshes the proof. We know very simple. is Thus p must be p. from Lemma 2 that /\W greater in short is Lemma larger in the short duration groups, from 1, AW across groups of different duration. Change Policy Experiment and the came that now proceed September 1993 caps the into force in Endogenous Matching in Vjids at 30% Nv. of the auction value to study the effect of this restriction on the sorting equilibrium. on the sorting equilibrium are distinguished: the entry of capping Of that p, effect Two We different effects and the substitution effect. course, empirically only the total (entry plus substitution) effect can be observed, but the theory allows us to derive separate predictions for each of those effects. We begin by showing that W and decrease The VV.. first for a given p and the effect of capping the bids in 1993 TV, implication of this change fi of high types increases after capping the bids. among We the low types. As a result, the call this the entry the sorting equilibrium of an increase in the proportion of high types p,, this effect capping the bids is in select types tend to move into the capped funds. We sorting equilibrium of changing [U^) = W capped groups, where Then /SW^ = W {h'^) h'^ — and 2. the substitution call this W^{h'^) = W^ ) while 'W_{jf). We N show [\W^ and let in —^ the effect on the kept fixed. and low types the following Lemma h^ < in the ht^t. that the difference in continuation the high bids be constrained (b^ < 6^ < AlK 6i), then: 1. N-bi _ = > VJ^Tn 777 W > W ; = ~ Vi 1-6^' is l-,5^ the low types given the high bid "^ effect, AW > AW. W= Now is larger than in an unconstrained chit fund is w for p as the continuation payoffs for high Proof. In the unconstrained equilibrium, the payoff to the high types and effect: denotes the vector of constrained equilibrium bids in these groups, Fix p and will into the unconstrained funds while the high W (increasing W and decreasing W values in a constrained chit fund Lemma 3. W^ < W; 3. we funds, all chit funds groups also leads both types to substitute between different chit funds: now move W all chit (mechanically) larger in the short duration funds. Apart from the entry payoffs change, and as a result, the low types Denote the effect on effect: while keeping unconstrained. While the entry effect increases the proportion of borrowers in show that to increase that more high types decide to participate is in all auctions, with a corresponding decline in participation ratio is i_tAf \^y.2 + in the Tv^^i ^ by the period's constraint. It Ki 1 1-6'" 1 - 5V, + d'" constrained ^6, -1 l\ L < '} W first period — t>ecause the low types are not constrained and y_2 ' is now immediately (b^ follows that 17 b^ <bi), AW^ > AW. ^^' is Likewise, not affected . By capping must make them better The Entry 3.4.1 We now 3 we the bids, are exogenously reducing the competition off relative to {/\W the low types increases), for a given all attractive to the high types (for a given What will be the p and types, even before a particular auction shows that when bids are capped, any auction becomes we expect an the high types, which N on Sorting Effect focus on the entry behavior of In particular, among p and N). This less attractive to will affect an increase in /i chosen. Lemma the low types and more the entry decision of increase in the fraction of high types effect of is all participants. ii.^^ on the sorting equilibrium, assuming that all funds continue to be unconstrained? Consider the sorting equilibrium with two types of chit funds offered Ni,N2, where A'^i < A^2- Let pi = p{Ni) and p2 = p{N2) and let the superscripts equilibrium values associated with the entry and substitution effect respectively. E,S denote the Then the following Proposition follows. Proposition 3 (Entry Effect) If n increases (i.e. > ji while keeping all chit funds unconstrained, ii) then the fraction of high types increases more in the short duration chit fund duration chit fund N2: Proof. If pf — Pi > P2 Ni than in the long ^ P2- pi,P2 are equilibriiun values, then the equilibrium conditions W (pi) = W {p2) and W{pi) = W{p2) imply AW{pi) = AW{p2) which, after taking logs of both sides and rearranging, implies PiNi - P2N2 + C= (6) where \N2l~5^' We now show that more than p2- ^^Think of F(c). Then all as a result of an increase Consider any increase in fi to in sorting equilibrium will imply that pi increases /i, n^ > participation in chit funds c* satisfies is This generates a corresponding increase jjl. beneficial as long as IV W— c' = 0. in pi, increases, c* will increase and as a decreases. It immediately follows that n — c > 0. Obviously, there will be a fraction F(c') high Similarly for the low types, so that F(c-) W ,5 types having a private cost c of entering an auction, with c distributed according to the cdf F{c) and types participating where If In J + F(c-) result so will F{c'). will increeise. 18 The opposite is true, i.e. that F_(c*) decreases, if W . P2 to pf pfi while the equilibrium , for pf and po continues to require pf ^1 - pf A^2 + This implies in turn, from equation C= 0. that (6), (pf-Pi)A^i-(pf -P2)Af2 = Since N-[ < N2, The Substitution 3.4.2 Effect Next consider the substitution expected payoff how a change before, is pf - follows immediately that it in effect . pi > pf — 0. p2- on Sorting on the sorting equilibrium, as a consequence of the change each of the funds. Keeping the fraction of high types ^ constant, we in the payofTs in we assume that there capped now in consider chit funds affects the sorting of types into different funds. are two types of funds, N^ and A^^, where fund A^^ is the As capped while Ni unconstrained. Proposition 4 (Substitution Nj while keeping W,W_ Effect) If for Nt and ^i W increases and W_ decreases is the other hand, Nj > W,Wf < pf — Pi < p^ — W_) for less in the Pj unconstrained, MV^ip.) = On W unchanged, then the fraction of high types increases unconstrained chit fund than in the constrained chit fund: Proof. Since N, {i.e. is constrained, and W AW'-(p,). > W,W_ < W_ which implies MV^iPj) > AW{pj). Equilibrium prior to the capping requires that AW{p,) = AW{pj), which implies from the equations above that AM/^(pO < AW^ipj). Now equilibrium after the capping requires, AW^ipf) = AW^ip^), so Pi,Pj must shift to restore equilibrium. Since consistency condition, equation (-5), tells fj, is fbced us that Pi,pj 19 and there are only two types must of groups, the shift in opposite directions. This follows immediately from the observation that ^ is a weighted average oi pi,pj before the capping and pf p^ , after the capping. From Lemma 1, —^ —< 0, pi must decrease and pj must increase to restore equihbrium after the capping: pf -Pi <Pj -Pirn We know for a given from p and Lemma A'^. 3 that the capping exogenously increases groups to restore equahty in The change entry effect in ii. To is simply a mechanical change From Proposition short duration groups; pf — 1, pi > in the sorting it is to show that the substitution 3 the entry effect increases the proportion of high types P2 ~ P2- From Proposition — pi more in 4 the substitution effect increases the < p^ — Pj. We will later verify empirically the long duration funds that are capped, so the entry and the substitution effects work in opposite directions. increases equihbrium as a consequence of the match endogenously, we need proportion of high types more in capped groups; pf that that p must increase more in the constrained AW across different types of groups. establish that participants effect is present. Lemma This imphes, from AW in the constrained groups, more in the Thus, if we were to empirically estabhsh that the proportion of high types capped (long duration) groups, then this would tell us unambiguously that participants actively re-sort following the policy experiment. 4 Testing the Theory We now proceed to test the implications of the model. We begin with a description of the various data sources used in the empirical analysis in Section 4.1. Chit fund groups are subsequently partitioned into aggregate chit value-duration categories in Section 4.2, while individual participants are classified as low and high types in Section 4.3, which allows us to implement the empirical tests. Section 4.4 studies the sorting equihbrium prior to the experiment (Proposition 2), Section 4.5 studies the pattern of bids before and after the experiment, and Section 4.6 studies the change in sorting from 1993 to 1994 (implied by Proposition 3 and Proposition 4). The main p increases much more sharply in this particular setting) that the sorting effect is of high types result of this section is that the proportion capped groups, which implies unambiguously (in present and hence that participants are matching endogenously. 4.1 We The Data use three sources of data in this paper. First, in all the gi-oups operated October 1, we obtained a complete record of all winning bids by Shriram Chits and Investments Pvt. Ltd. that commenced between 1992 and September 30, 1994 in the city of Chennai. 20 The sample period covers exactly one year before and one year refer to the years 1 to after the imposition of the 1993 and 1994 henceforth in the paper, September 30 period and just just before South India, and Shriram Chits, which city in Nadu, has 30% cap on September we after the capping. is participated in the chit fund groups that Our second source of data provides be referring to the October Chennai is the largest commercial the largest chit fund company in the state of Tamil headquarters, and 20 neighborhood branches, its will actually When we 30, 1993. commenced in the in the city income information In total. 78.000 individuals city. during the sample period. for a limited number of subscribers in the sample. While the winning bids and the group characteristics are computerized and readily available, can only be obtained from the application forms which are this additional subscriber information the time of entry. These application forms are subsequently stacked filled in at branch located office, all over the obtain income information on all We city. picked a random sample their participants, in collecting this additional commenced and thus there We selected. regressions And in 1994, is 25% some concern that finally, statistics; our third source of data is it is to the analysis that we each and then attempted to of the full sample). We this appear to have this restricted will sample may not be randomly only be used in a few exploratory not required for the bulk of the analysis. an aggregate break down of groups, based on the pot auctioned in each month and the duration, in information for individuals belonging to groups that should emphasize, however, that income data and to report some basic back rooms from the respective branches. Ultimately, information was collected for 21,906 subscribers (roughly been more successful of groups in in size of the each year over the 1992-2001 period. Extensions report later in Section 5 will use these aggregate data to study changes in the structure (duration) of the groups over time. Classification of 4.2 Groups Each branch posts a menu of available groups by the chit value (the total amount at each point in time, to be auctioned each participant chooses the group-type that is where each group month) and the duration appropriate for her, based on its (in commence company after the necessary permission offers number months). Each fills, it is and the allowed from the Registrar of Chit Funds has been obtained. The a wide range of chit value-duration combinations, and the analysis will be to classify the groups, along both the chit value smaller characterized characteristics composition of types that she expects to match with in equilibrium. Once a group to is first step in the empirical and duration dimensions, into a of aggregate categories. While new groups form throughout the year, the company helps coordinate the formation of these groups by organizing two major subscription campaigns each year April and the Ayudha Puja by offering entering follows, it is gifts (Divali festival) in October. when the - during the Tamil The company New Year in also encourages participation individual joins a group. For the purpose of the discussion that important to note that the value of these 21 gifts is based on the chit value, rather than The company seems the individual's monthly contribution. make the to away a constant individuals save to achieve a target, instead of simply putting income each month. The amount that she expects the company's lead, groups in we individual's participation decision to deposit, rather than the fraction of their thus seen to be based on the total is payment that she makes each month. Following will use the chit value, rather than the monthly contribution, to classify the discussion that follows. Chit values range from Rs. 10,000 to over Rs. 100,000 in our data. savings target, which The implicit assumption that is measured by her choice of chit value, The level of the individual's must naturally be based on her income. probability that a subscriber will choose a low (high) chit value will most likely be declining The (increasing) with income. empirical relationship between the choice of chit value and income thus allows us to conveniently partition groups along the chit value dimension. Table 1 and presents multinomial logit The Rs.30,000 chit value is linear probability estimates of the chit value regression. treated as the base category in the multinomial logit regression in Panel A, while separate regressions are estimated for each chit value to obtain the linear probability estimates in Panel B. Even though 16 chit values are observed in the data, we restrict attention to six values in Table 1 , which together account for over 90% of Insert Table As expected, the as her income individual increases. and Rs. 100,000 She 1 here. significantly less likely to choose the lowest Rs. 10,000 chit value is is, the observations in our sample. all however, significantly more chit values as her income grows. These likely to choose the highest Rs.50,000 results are obtained with both the multino- mial logit model and the linear probability model. For the intermediate Rs. 15, 000- Rs.30,000 values, the chit value-income relationship is not as clear cut. It would thus seem natural to Rs. 10,000 groups as low value, the Rs.l5,000-Rs.30,000 groups as and Rs. 100,000 groups as high The medium and high value chits. is ambiguous is The trajectory company made There is a clear visual distinction between sharply negative for the Rs. 10,000 chit value, Once more, the for the intermediate values. We follow the company's will see that is 1. reversed for the Rs.50,000 and Rs. 100,000 values. Insert Figure we and the Rs.50,000 patterns just described are easy to visualize with the nonparametric kernel regressions, which while the direction of the trend pattern value, the value. correspond to the hnear probability estimates, in Figure the low, medium classify here. lead once again, to partition groups along the duration dimension. Later the long duration (large efforts to 1 N) groups were affected most the 30% ceiling. The organizing reduce this effect by changing the design of the auction, as of October 2000. These changes were restricted to groups with durations 40 22 months or longer, which are classified by company the as "long duration groups." We will use the same duration classification in the empirical analysis. Table 2 describes the different groups that commenced over the 1993-94 period, and shows the broad classification by chit value and duration that we have adopted. As before, we to the six major chit values. There are seven months, associated with these diflferent restrict attention durations, ranging from 20 months to 100 This leaves us with 42 distinct chit value-month six chit values. combinations, which are aggregated into six combinations using the Low, Medium, High classification on the chit value dimension, there are a number number large and the Short, Long classification on the duration dimension. While of "gaps" in Table 2, notice that this classification leaves us with a sufficiently of groups in each aggregate category. Insert Table 2 here. Classification of Paiticipants 4.3 When we classify groups into and the target savings available over time is six level, lock broad categories we are relying on the idea that income constraints, The only the individual into a particular chit value. whether to join a long or short duration group, which will allow us to the sorting and the bidding regressions separately within each category. But this the individual's participation decision change up in is is estimate not appropriate based instead on her monthly contribution. Given the if likely duration over time, individuals with the same endowments and preferences would then end in different chit values before We is choice that and after the 30% ceiling. consequently proceed to verify that the characteristics of participants, within each chit value category, remained the in that case same over the 1993-94 period. The only change in the economic environment would be brought about by the 30% bid cap, which allows us to isolate the effect of the exogenous institution-specific shock on the matching equihbrium. Looking down the distribution in Table 3, Panel A, separately similar in 1993 and 1994 for low, medium, and high chit values, we see that incomes are remarkably at all quantile levels, except at the very top of the indicates that the underlying income distribution of participants income distribution. This was unchanged and that the choice of chit values was unaffected by the capping of the bids in 1994.^^ Insert Table 3 here. The stability of the income distribution in Table 3, Panel A, for all chit support the use of the chit value to partition groups. But as an additional that all values, would seem to we will also verify test, our regression results are robust to an alternative classification scheme, in which groups are partitioned into low, medium, high monthly '^We ignore the knife-edge case in which changes contributions, with the cut-offs set at Rs.500 in the income distribution and changes just cancel each other. 23 and Rs.lOOO in the choice of chit value per month. While not reported here, these cut-offs are constructed using the same approach described earher in Table The 1 and Figure up discussion We short two-year period that need to number to this point has allowed us to partition the groups into a small aggregate categories. still 1. of have also verified that the income distribution was unchanged over the we consider, allowing us to isolate the effect of the classify participants as 30% cap. However, we low types and high types. Recall that high types receive a higher return on their outside investments and so will bid higher and win earlier in equilibrium. this institution is we can that As noted in the Introduction, a particularly convenient feature of identify ex ante borrowers; there that flags "finance companies." As seen in Table approximately 20% of all 3, a separate is field in the records Panel B, these corporate subscribers account the observations in our data. The appear to be trusted by the chit fund organizers, and most for proprietors of these select companies likely have social ties to them. While the individual subscribers must provide information on their income, assets, and occupation to the chit fund organizers, and also furnish the names and addresses of three guarantors, the corporate subscribers face none of these requirements. The money collected from the auction is invested elsewhere by these companies, who clearly have access to superior investment opportunities than the individual subscribers To who are for the most part salaried employees. verify that this classification of types, based we compare the timing timing variable is of winning bids defined as the month on ex ante characteristics, for corporate in The companies, zero otherwise. regression, so the constant and individual subscribers The corporate linear probability term measures the average timing corporate subscriber variable megisures would expect high types to win early, how much and indeed appropriate, in Table 4. The which the individual wins the auction divided by the total duration of the group, and so ranges from zero to one. for finance is model subscriber variable equals one is used to estimate the Timing for the individual subscribers, while the companies win on average. earlier the finance as expected the corporate subscriber coefficient absolute magnitude and very precisely estimated. The same 1993 and 1994, for low, medium, and high value groups. result We will is is We large in obtained, without exception, in consequently treat the corporate subscribers as high types and the individual subscribers as low types in the empirical analysis that follows. The proportion of high types p, which helps us study changes in the sorting equilibrium, can then be computed accordingly. Insert Table 4 here. 4.4 We Sorting Before the Experiment noted p{N) and in Proposition 2 that the equilibrium relationship between the proportion of high types the duration of the group A^ depends on the discount factor a 6* such that for 6 < 6* an increase in A'^ lowers p{N). 24 S. In particular, there exists The preliminary sorting regression uses data from 1993 only, prior to the policy shock, with a dummy corporate subscriber participant is 5, dependent variable. This variable takes on the value of one one of the finance companies, zero otherwise. The single regressor dummy, which Table as the takes on a value of one the a short duration the group runs for less than 40 months, zero otherwise. if Panel A, begins by partitioning groups into low, medium, and high chit values, and then estimating the sorting regression separately B is if in each aggregate category. Subsequently, Panel repeats this exercise with an alternative classification of groups by monthly contribution. Short duration groups have a greater proportion of corporate subscribers, without exception, in Panel and Panel B. Notice also that the coefficient Medium, and across from Low, to on the short duration dummy A grows larger as we move particularly to High chit values. Insert Table 5 here. Table 5, Panel C, continues with the exercise reported above, reporting regressions for each of the six disaggregate chit values discussed earlier in Table and Table 2 (with the exception of the 1 Rs. 15,000 chit value which has no long duration groups). Looking across columns in Panel that the coefficient on the short duration as we move The dummy is always positive, and that negative p — will subsequently N relationship that we systematically observe in Table 5 for the presence of study changes in p over time, at different values of of the 30% cap on 4.5 Bids Before and After the Experiment and durations), before and really the bids over time. is consistent with such endogenous matching, A'^, following the imposition groups with different characteristics (chit values is The What we normalized bid. This bid value into five equal time periods, of these time periods in after the policy experiment. to provide us with a normalized bid amount. is increasing steadily the bids. This section studies the pattern of bids over time follows, see across from low chit values to high chit values.-'^ endogenous matching. To provide additional support we it is C we and a dummy is is bid in Rupees is divided by the chit value refer to as the "bid" in all the discussion that capped at 0.3 in 1994. The group is divided included for each period in the bid regression. Each interacted with a 1994 year-dummy, to capture the change in the pattern of The uninteracted Period unconstrained 1993 bids, prior to the 1-Period 5 estimates in Table 6 thus describe the pattern of 30% cap. Separate regressions are estimated for long and short duration groups, within each aggregate chit value. ""One outlying group-type Table 5, and later in - Rs. 30,000 chits running for 60 months - is dropped from the regressions reported Table 7 where we study changes in sorting over time. The coefficient on the short duration actually reverses sign in Table -5, Column the sorting that we report in Table 7 is 3 when in dummy the outlying groups are included. Note, however, that the change in completely unaffected by the inclusion or the omi-ssion of these outlying groups. 25 Insert Table 6 here. Concentrating on the strained 1993 bidding pattern, (particularly in the early rows of Table first five we months) 6, Period 1 Period - which describe the uncon- 5, see that higher bids are generated in the long duration groups in each chit value. This pattern is not at all surprising. bids reflect the fact that the interest rate implicitly faced by borrowers and lenders over a longer period in the long duration groups. Therefore, even is the same in both groups, we would duration groups. This point will be interest rate and the still made clear in section 5.2, compounded initial periods for long where we analytically derive the implicit and short duration groups. same duration, we chit values with the higher the implicit annual interest rate expect to see higher bids in the difference in initial bids between long Looking next across if is The see that the normalized bids are increasing in the chit value, particularly for the long duration groups. at all surprising,' since the subscribers (particularly the low types) Once again, this pattern must be compensated not is for tying up a large amount of capital with the chit fund. The preceding in 1994. description of the unconstrained bids us what change we would expect to see Bids must adjust to the 0.30 cap that was imposed in 1994, and this in rows 6-10 of Table 6, which describe the change which highhght bids above 0.3 (Rows tells 6-10). in each case. The in Within a is chit value, the To help is change see down to 0.3 always greater in the long duration groups, precisely is initial bids when unconstrained. And controlling for increasing with chit value (especially for the long duration groups). we present nonparametric visualize the changes just described, regression, separately for low, medium, and high chit values, tion groups within each chit value, in Figures 2-4. bids in 1993 are capped what we the bids. Focus on the bold-face coefficients, that the change in the bid just brings the 1994 bid because the long duration groups have higher duration, the change exactly 1993 (Rows 1-5) and the corresponding change in these bids in 1994 point to note first in is more than short duration groups, severely in 1994. kernel estimates of the bid and separately for short and long As noted above, groups with higher unconstrained Thus long duration groups are capped more in each chit value. drura- For the same duration, it is severely easy to see across the Figures that the capping increases with chit value. Insert Figures 2-4 here. Looking across Figures 2-4 notice that the 1994 bids always lie below the 1993 the bids leads to an increase in the proportion of high types (from Proposition subsequently verify). And 4, bids. Capping which we will while the 1994 bids in the early periods would certainly have been below the corresponding 1993 levels in capped funds, the 1994 bid schedule could in principle have crossed to the right of the 1993 schedule level, 0.3) in the if the new equilibrium was number of high types (bidding at or below the constrained sufficiently large. 26 But we see instead that the 1994 bids start to drop below the constrained the 1993 bids reach that level in (0.3) level long before Notice also that the 1993 and 1994 bids coincide in the later periods The explanation for this observation and only low types remain to compete (0.3) must be the same chit fund Changes 4.6 We now study in below the constrained level Equilibrium in the Sorting the change in the proportion of high types p as a consequence of the policy experiment, in p effect (Proposition 3) predicts a greater increase the short duration groups following the capping, while the substitution effect (Proposition 4) predicts a gieater increase in groups that are capped. capping We saw in Table particularly severe in the long duration groups, although is duration groups with more increase in the long To study changes Table values and durations. in all chit fall ^'^ 1993 and 1994. in groups with different characteristics. The entry shoi't bids the Figures. the auction, then the continuation payoff in a given in in Once the very simple. is all medium and high duration groups in sorting we if and Figures we do 2-4, that the see mild capping in the we would expect p to company dummy on the 1994 year dummy in chit values Jis well. In general, the substitution effect regress the finance 6, is present. Separate regressions are run for each aggregate chit value, and for long and short duration 7. groups within each value. To verify the robustness of the results to alternative partitions of the data, groups are partitioned by chit value {Nv) in Panel Taking expectations across on the 1994 year dummy all A and by the monthly contribution subscribers in these regressions, it is [v) in Panel B. easy to verify that the coefficient measures the change in p from 1993 to 1994. Insert Table 7 here. The on the 1994 coefficient dummy is significantly larger for the long duration groups, in each of the three aggregate categories in Table 7, Panel A and Panel B. The proportion of high types in long duration groups increases from 0.18 to 0.24 in the low chit value groups, from 0.13 to 0.19 in the medium chit value groups, and from 0.12 to 0.25 in the high chit value groups. The composition of the chit funds clearly changes dramatically, particularly in the long duration groups, from one year to the next. Since the entry and the substitution effects work in opposite directions, the greater increase in p in the capped long duration groups unambiguously identifies the substitution effect, which tells us in turn that participants match endogenously in this institution. Intuitively, we would also expect the duration constant, since the capping what we see, is although the change in p change in more severe is monthly duration chit values, in and short duration in higher categories, in higher chit values. Once again, this holding the is precisely not significantly different across successive categories in a We verified that the same patterns were obtained when of the aggregated long p to be greater we restricted attention to a single categories, within each chit value. For this exercise monthly duration, instead we used the most popular each case; 20 months and 50 months for low chit values, 20 months and 40 months for and 25 months and 50 months for high chit values. 27 medium couple of cases. '^ Overall, the changes in p that respond, as we observe suggest that the sorting equilibrium does should, to exogenous changes in the economic environment. it Extensions to the Model 5 We now proceed beyond the model. First, we study changes in the term structure, measured by the proportion of short duration groups, in this institution. Section 5.1 compares the term structure in 1993 and 1994, where we see a substantial increase the capping of the bids. Second, its new we proportion of short duration groups following in the investigate whether the institution has settled immediately into (post-cap) equilibrium. While the analysis in Section 4 provides unambiguous evidence that the institution has drastically changed in the direction predicted by the theory, comparing behavior at two points in time, and short duration groups have equalized we cannot whether the unobservable normalized payoffs in 1994. of different funds for both years in Section 5.2. We therefore calculate the We find that while implicit different duration funds are roughly equal in 1993, they are not in 1994. The tell, W by in long implicit interest rate interest rates across analysis in Section 5.3 confirms that adjustment was not fully completed in 1994. Using aggregate group level data over a longer 1992-2001 period, we find that the basic shift from the pre-cap to the post-cap equilibrium is completed in about two years. Term Structure Before and After 5.1 The the Experiment empirical results described in the previous section provide strong support for the view that the low types and the high types re-sort themselves following the policy experiment. In the discussion that follows we will study how the term structure in this institution, measured by the proportion of short duration groups, responded in turn to the policy experiment. Continuing with the simple case with two types of groups, of duration condition requires that p\niNi -I- p2'^2-^2 (number) of funds of each type. Denote r] = /^ — ^, ('^i-^i + '^2-^2)1 A'^i where nj, < 71.2 N2, the consistency denote the measure then N2H-P2 NipiAs before we will decompose the impact of the capping Start with the entry effect, which increases Proposition 2 and Table the increase in p. is 12 5. Further, to increase 77, pf — pi /u to fj^ > P2 — P2 . into an entry and a substitution Prior to the capping, pi from Proposition 3. > Thus the fj. > effect. p2 from direct effect of while the indirect effect through the change in p goes in the opposite direction. Turning to the substitution capped more ^ severely. The constant term in effect, fixing p, With two types pf — pi < pf — P2, since the long duration groups are of groups, pi actually declines while p2 increases (to preserve Table 7 measures p in 1993 and so matches the point estimates that we presented in Table 28 5. the constant the decHne in pi If fj). is sufficiently large, relative to the increase in P2, then r/ could increase as a consequence of the substitution effect. But in general, the effect of changes in p on due to the entry and the substitution Starting with Table 8. Panel A, we see that the number of individual subscribers (low types) all types) does increase, in the medium and values, and the decline). It total ambiguous. effects, are declines substantially across decline in participation chit values. among number While participation by the corporate subscribers (high high chit values, this increase never compensates for the the ordinary subscribers. Overall participation declines in all chit of participants declined from 43,267 in 1993 to 34,797 in 1994 (a 20% also evident from these statistics that the overall proportion of high types is ry, 16% substantially over this period (from (^;) increases to 22%), as expected. Insert Table 8 here. Turning to the proportion of short duration groups proportion increases significantly we noted earlier the change in we proceed unambiguously leads to an increase p, which could go in the first three rows, The B is complete. The To reported in Panel A, which 8, verify the robustness of this result, Panel C. Starting with durations in rows 4-7, we see a decline in popularity, once all group durations and After the Experiment fund institution by studying behavior at two points in time is making whether equilibrium conditions are derived in terms of the normalized payoff out of equilibrium by comparing the interest rate that is no exphcit price on the actual bids we can D= jTjiT— G [0, 1] must N still money - interest rate is this - in its change W, which months (the duration t. The in this non-market is institution. But based the monthly interest rate) and participant contributes an of the group). is in or is calculate the interest rate implicit in a given chit fund auction. period way generated in groups of different types. be the monthly interest factor (where r^ denote the funds received period of for we in the data. unobserved by the econometrician. But we can gain a rough sense of whether this institution There less see an increase in popularity over time, almost without results presented this far suggest that the chit tell f-i Panel B, we see that this ni/n2, presumably dominates any effects of driven by underlying changes across new equihbrium, we cannot in increase in the proportion of short duration groups that Implicit Interest Rates Before While the empirical is we Turning to the long duration groups, observed above in Panel to a in + no)) increase in in the opposite direction. again with almost no exceptions. 5.2 The to disaggregate the group durations in Table than 40 months, exception. in all chit values. (t7i/ (ni Let let ct amount v each month over a Hence, the budget constraint for any participant satisfy the condition f2D'-'{ct-v)=0. t=i 29 (7) The net present value of monthly contributions must equal the net present value of funds received. The inflow of funds in any period Cj = in which case she jjbt'- collects c^ We = Nv — br + jjbr, i-e. the total pot minus her bid can now rewrite the budget constraint the auction in period r given by in equation Nv — hr in addition (7) for a participant as: D^-' (Nv - It is she gets her equal share of the bid. In one period, say r, the participant wins the chit fund, to her share of the bid. who wins which a participant does not win the auction in t br) + El?*-^ {^^h - I') = 0. follows immediately from this expression that the budget constraints of different agents only differ in the first term. constraints, i.e. Therefore, agents we can who win calculate the interest factor D from any two agents' budget the bids in two different periods r and r' as \Nv-br' Using the relationship between rm D and the monthly to the corresponding annual rate, In practice and the last we we compute the annual period value, duration, (r' = N) and year in r^ provided earlier, and converting obtain: interest rate using the in each group. ^^ Table interest rate These winning bid in the second period (r interest rates are reported separately = by 2) chit 9. Insert Table 9 here The 1989 Report on Urban Informal interest rate paid by non-banking finance companies, which include chit funds, was 18%. The un- constrained interest rates that 14% to 24%. Credit Markets in India (Dasgupta 1989) tells us that the we compute The same Report tells 1993 match very well with this for statistic, ranging from us that the interest rate paid by nationalized banks on term deposits was 9%, so the popularity of the chit funds is easy to understand. Subsequently the capping brought the interest rates down dramatically, and they range from to 17% in 1994, which is much individual subscribers that closer to the we saw in Table bank 8, rate. Panel A, is The sharp decline in participation by the once more easy to understand. Recall from the discussion in Section 2 that the chit fund organizer collects the and so competitive bidding only commences in treated as a pure borrower, while the individual period 2. who wins The individual who wins in the last period 30 8% is first in pot without bidding, bi = 0, the second period can thus be a pure lender. Notice also, from Table chit value are roughly that interest rates for short and long duration groups within a given 9, comparable. ^^ In contrast, we see that the interest rates on the long duration groups are significantly lower than the corresponding rates same and the calculation of the nnplicit interest rate can and N2 with Ni < A'^i zero: 5/v = 0. Then, from equation (8), we Define the A^2- P{N) = normalized by the chit value (as plotted in Figures 2-4) as is now why also clarify the bids in the long duration chit funds are higher than the initial bids in the short duration funds. Consider any two funds of duration bid the short duration gioups, within the chit value, in 1994. Finally, Table 9 initial in first competitive bid, j^. Recall that the last period's get Nv{l~p{N)) 12 1-(3{N)) N~2 Since rates in funds A^i and A''2 are roughly ecjual in 1993, from Table (l-/3(7Vi))"^>-^ Taking logs follows that ^^2-2. ={l-P{N2)) and collecting terms, ln(l-/?(iV2)) ln(l-/?(iVi)) Since (3{N) e 5.3 9, it [0, 1] < and Ni map N2-2 iVi-2- N2, this imphes that 9{N2) Long Term Changes While we cannot ^ in the > /3(iVi).^^ Term Structure the computed interest rates directly into normalized payoffs W , the wide discrepancy in these interest rates in 1994, for long and short duration groups within the same chit '^The short duration groups tend to generate a computation assumes a constant interest factor why this is unlikely to be the case. The first is D -slightly higher interest rate, but this "tcix" that is be the same and without imposed on the participants by virtue of the fact that the without competitive bidding (this in each period, we is most likely because our that one would expect the interest rate to differ depending on the interest rate term structure. Second, the implied markets are clearly not perfect the is (an hence r) in each period of time. In reality, there are two reasons frictions. In particular, chit fund organizer wins the we first ignore auction a legally stipulated feature of the institution). By setting the discount factor are implicitly assuming that there Eire no such frictions within the group. D to But once we introduce the tax, then the discount factor will vary over time, and the famiUar spread between the borrowing and the lending interest rates will emerge. Each participant in The interest rates that The the spread will be greater in those groups. lie below the corresponding rate in the long Consider a hypothetical example with verified that are (30) we report in Table 9 thus lie somewhere within this spread. a short duration group must bear a greater tax burden, for a given chit value, which implies that = compounded over 0.29. actual lending rate in short diu-ation groups could then equal or even duration groups. A'l = 20 and ^2 = 30 and suppose Long duration funds have higher longer periods. 31 initial that (5 (20) = 0.20, then it is immediately bids because they reflect the fact that interest rates value, suggests very strongly that the chit fund institution is yet to reach the post-cap equilibrium. Additional support for this view can also be obtained from Figure for the in The low chit value groups. 2, which describes the bid pattern bid schedule for the short duration groups is essentially the same 1993 and 1994. In contrast, the 1994 bids are substantially lower than the 1993 bids for the long duration groups in that Figure. Participants who were indifferent between the long and short duration low chit value groups in 1993 evidently would not remain that way in 1994. While the proportion of high types might have adjusted in the right direction to this institutional We move the conclude the empirical analysis by using aggregate group level data to study the change in commenced values. equilibrium, change does not appear to have been completed by 1994. The proportion the composition of groups over a ten-year period 1992-2001. that new institution to the in each year over this period is computed, separately These proportions are plotted, without smoothing, in Figure of short duration groups for low, medium, and high chit 5. Insert Figure 5 here. The proportion and high of short duration groups increases sharply chit values, just as we saw in Table 8. in The proportion this increase continues for of short duration groups in low 1993 to over 0.4 by 1995. The medium medium, for low, one more year, 1994- which the proportion of short duration groups flattens 95, consistent with the discussion above, after out. But from 1993 to 1994, and high chit values begin from about 0.2 chit values increases with a much higher proportion of short duration groups, above 0.5 in 1993, yet this proportion increases even further to 0.7 by 1995. term structure in this institution clearly responds quite dramatically to the change in the The economic environment. There seems to be some overshooting minor oscillations in the Figure, in 1995, but the basic and some shaking out thereafter, judging from the shift from the pre-cap to the post-cap equilibrium completed in two years. The institutional response to this exogenous shock that this is a decentralized equilibrium. which makes the rapid response 6 in this fresh set of individuals joins the chit fund each period, non-market institution even more remarkable. we study - paper provide strong support the chit fund economic environment. will extremely rapid, given Conclusion The results that in this A is is - for the view that the particular non-market institution responds swiftly and appropriately to an exogenous change in the The theory predicts that groups in which bids are capped be associated with a larger increase in more severely the proportion of high types (p) following the policy experiment. This proportion does increase more sharply in long duration groups (and in higher chit values) providing striking endorsement for the view that participants in the chit fund are matching endogenously. 32 An alternative explanation for the observed changes changed as a consequence of the is that the composition of the participants bid-ceiling, or that other economic environment are responsible what we for see. We unobserved exogenous changes have already verified income distribution of the individual subscribers, within aggregate time. It is also not obvious how We in Table 3 that the is very stable over chit values, these alternative arguments would explain the precise change in we observe, along both the duration and the that in the have seen that the participants chit value dimension, in the data. the chit funds responded immediately to the policy shock in by re-sorting themselves. The endogenous institutional view that we take that the structure of the institution p itself in this paper would predict should also respond to the policy shock. And indeed we see that the term structure, measured by the proportion of short duration groups, does respond quite dramatically to the change in the economic environment. specifies that the Further, while the Chit winning bid should be distributed among the members of the group, stipulate that the bid should be distributed equally been adopted historically by the which those subscribers who won the auction for the this is does not it just a convention that has fund companies. Starting from October 2000, Shriram Chits chit introduced the Extra Dividend Scheme (EDS), in normal dividend thereafter, among them; Fund Act all groups with durations 40 months or longer, in in the initial duration of the group. months received only one percent '^'^ of the This effectively increases the amount that these early winners pay out, moving the interest rates in the long duration groups closer to their unconstrained levels. Such changes in the rules of the with numerous alternative schemes, described above. in response to It is game are difficult to implement, and the Company experimented a limited number of groups, before in it settled on the EDS scheme nevertheless very encouraging to see the very structure of the institution change, an exogenous change in the economic environment, within a relatively short period of seven years. It is not obvious that capping the bids generated any efficiency gains in this institution. Default rates were low to begin with, and continued to remain that way rates moved down even some of the (potential) subscribers decline in the overall after the policy experiment. Interest further from the competitive level, and while the banks volume who stopped participating, there of capital entering the system. The was most may have picked up likely a substantial participants in the chit funds did respond to the policy shock by re-sorting themselves, and the company did respond by altering the structure of the institution, but these are only second-best responses. this case most hkely exacerbated the inefficiencies that This restriction on the dividend apphes to those subscribers of 40 months duration, and the fir.st were already present who win in in the financial system. the auction in the 20 months for groups of longer duration. 33 Government intervention first 10 months for groups . Appendix 7 Proposition For 1. all t N < AVi{N,p) = 6p^-^AVn and AVpi {N,p) = Nvlj-j] = Nv A 7. Proof. While Vj is the expected continuation payoff, denote the expected continuation payoff after realization of the private signal at as vt pN There are high types in the group, so remains among the bidders, t = ...,pN 1, — first 1. more than one high type consider periods in which The payoff to the high type with signal a] can then be written as Vt = Pr > max {V'}} {Vn + {Vt a\ - Vt) + [\ - Pr {^j > max {C}}) (^^Vt+i = (^w — Consider a (type-contingent) symmetric bidding function ^f = i^-N N^-~t+i " ^Y-t+i) + / ("^f) (where / {a\) is 6^ j^^^i j^^ max {V'}) + ^V^t+i ) + / an increasing function that approaches (o"f) and as e - the bound of the symmetric support of at - goes to zero). We are interested in the h = N^t+i i^N ~ ^^t+i) is when e = 0) is + <^ 6^ we verify whether an equilibrium strategy. The expected payoff Vt for £ (which = is 0, bidding equal to vt = Pr{6;>max{6r}}(y;v-^^/^^(F;v-5F,+ i)) Vt where Pr case where e goes to zero, so (1 - Pr > max Ibt + bidding - say bt strictly lower: Vn - weakly dominated. \\ {bl = > max {1;'}}) {sVt,, + [^j^t+i - Note that there is no incentive to deviate either way. Over- d - implies winning the auction with certainty; however the expected jfz^^ [Vn - 6Vt+ij - d < pf^t+i (^^ It is is + [N - t) utility is SVt+i), and underbidding is easy to verify that this bidding strategy leaves the high types indifferent between winning and losing the current auction: Vt Similarly, there J^^j/^, (^- - ^^*+0) no incentive to deviate Vt = 6Vt+i + for the — Vn —bt = 5Vt+i jfzi^t- low type, whose payoff j^bt = 6yM + j^_\^-^ iVN-svt+i)34 + is Now In period t = AVi calculating = pN, — Vt is y_f straightforward: only one high type Now is left. bution shift (see Maskin and Riley (2000, proposition Maskin and Riley ^ Q-pN (2000): ^ = jr^i The low type bpN- highest draw g_pj^ — e will higher than hpiM zero, is ctJ bpisi < e is AVi = a high bid auction with a distri- Consider the following bids as derived ^ = jf^^, if (liw in " 6VpN + i) + the low type gets the she have the same bid). As a result, the high type always wins the auction She has no incentive to deviate provided e Bidding lower is is sufficiently small. weakly dominated, while bidding implies a payoff = ^-N + ^( - ^pN the other hand, bidding the equilibrium bid Since the auction 4.3). Solving recursively, (SAVi+i- - 6VpN+i)+^ and incentive to deviate either. V-pN On = never bid higher than the high type (only will for sure at the lowest price possible. The low type has no (Z/v AVt and £ > approaches 0, there bpj^. is As a assures a payoff h^ no incentive to deviate. Now for e (and as a result a) approaching the payoffs VpN are equal to VpN result, (i.e. the expected payoff). It easy to verify that this bidding strategy leaves the low type indifferent between winning and losing the current auction, giving us As a result, AVpiv = - VpN = VpN = ^VpN+l + AVJv- Vj^ From the bpiM j^ -rjJSl ^T^ fact that =y-N - bpN- AVi = S'^^'^AVpN. it now follows that AVj = F^-iAV/v = 8^^-^NA-^. Note that - all for any subsequent period the high types have already Vt t = pA^+l, ...,iV, thebids won and no = 8Vt+i (fore = 0) are6j longer bid - and as a result + j;^—bt = VN-bt 35 = jJl^Ii {Y_;^ — iSV^j+i) References [1] ACKERBERG, DANIEL A., AND Maristella BoTTiClNl, 2002. "Endogenous Matching and the Empirical Determinants of Contract Form", Journal of Political Economy. Vol. 110, No. 3, 564-591. [2] [3] Anderson, Robert T.. 1966. "Rotating Credit Associations in India", and Cultural Change, 14,: Ardener, Shirley. 1964. Economic Development 334-339. "The comparative Study of Rotating credit Associations", Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland, 94(2): 201-229. [4] Banerjee, Abhijit V., Timothy Besley, and Timothy W. Guinnane. bor's Keeper: The Design of a Credit Cooperative with 1994. "Thy Neigh- Theory and a Test". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(2): 491-515. [5] Banerjee Abhijit V., Dilip "Inequality, Control Rights Political [6] Economy. [7] 1978. "The Economic Role Savings and Development 4: 249-263. and credit Associations.", American Economic Review, vol.83 BONNETT, Audrey W.. Bouman, Economic Studies 61: 701-719. F.J. a.. 1995. "Rotating and Accumulating Savings and credit Associations: Dasgupta, New a., 1962. "Kyes and Mujins Korea". Economic Development and Cultural Change Nayar, C.P.S. and Associates. 1989. Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance Fernando, Edgar. A De- vol.23, no. 3: 371-384. Campbell, Colin D. and Chang Shick Ahn. India [13] no. 4: 792-810. Analysis of Rotating Credit Associations Washington: University Press of America, Inc. diaries in south [12] of Rotating Sav- 1981. Institutional Adaptation of West Indian Immigrants to America: velopment Perspective", World Development [11] and Credit Institutions Besley, Timothy, Stephen Coate, and Glenn Loury, "Rotating Savings and Credit An [10] Maharashtra". Journal of of Traditional Savings Associations, Credit Markets and Efficiency", Review of [9] in Besley, Timothy, Stephen Coate, and Glenn Loury, "The Economics ings [8] and Rent Seeking: Sugar Cooperatives Vol. 109, No.l. Begashaw, Girma. in Ethiopia", Mookherjee, Kaivan Munshi, and Debraj Ray. 2001. and - Financial Interme- 11: 55-68. Urban Informal Credit Markets in Policy. 1986. "Informal credit and Savings Organizations in Sri Lanka: System", Savings and Development 3:253-263. 36 The Cheetu [14] Geertz, Clifford. 1962. "The rotating credit Association: Economic Development and Cultural Change [15] A "Middle Rung" in Development". 10(3): 241-263. Levenson, Alec R. and Timothy Besley. 1996. "The Anatomy of an Informal Financial Market: Rosea Participation in Taiwan". Journal of Development Economics 51: 45-68. [16] Maskin, Eric, and John Riley. 2000. "Asymmetric Auctions", Review of Economic Studies, 67, 413-438. [17] MUNSHI, Kaivan and Jacques Myaux. 2002. "Development An [18] Change: Application to the Fertility Transition". University of Pennsylvania, mimeo. Schrieder, Gertrud R, Carlos E. Cuevas. Cameroon". In Adams, Dale, W. Fitchett, Delbert countn.es. [19] as a Process of Social 1992. "Informal Financial Groups in A., eds. Informal finance in loiu-income Boulder and Oxford: Westview Press. Shah, T. and M. Johnson, 1992. "Informal institutions of financial intermediation: value of Vishis, Chit Funds and self help groups", Institute of Rural Social Management, Anand. mimeo. [20] Townsend, Robert M.. 1994. "Risk and Insurance in Village India". Econometrica 62(3): 539-591. [21] Udry, Christopher. 1994. "Risk and Insurance in a Rural Credit Market: Investigation in Northern Nigeria". The Review of [22] Vaidyanathan, R. and K. Sriram, of 2000. Economic Studies The Non-Banking Management, Bangalore, mimeo. 37 An Empirical 61(3): 495-526. Financial Sector. Indian Institute — Figure 0.7 1 ; Choice of Ciiit Value i 0.6 10 • \ : \ 0.5 0) ; N ; \ : ni > o O) 0.4 c 10 o o ° X 0.3 X X ~"^^ ^ 25^ 50 -^.^^ 15 re xi o i_ CL ':--.-.-;.~;-:~:^..^. 0.2 : ^ -^^^^^ 0.1 100 ____^ —— y- ---^^ ' ^ 15 "^ 30 1 4 6 Income (thousands of 8 Rs.): bw=2.5 10 12 Figure 2: Bids 0.4 Long 19 93 0.35 Low Chit Values 1 \v Long 19 94 0.3 ^ n £u - 1 v. "S, N 0.25 Short 1994 NX o Io \ X \^ - V-.-i, 0.2 \\ X X \ X \^ X Short CO 1 993 \^ X K "XX 0.15 - ^ Vx. X 0.1 " ^ - -"-~~-~-l — __ 1 0.05 1 0.1 0.2 0.3 1 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 Timing (proportion of group duration): bw=0.075 0.8 0.9 Figure 3: Bids 0.5 1 1 - Medium 1 1 Chit Values 1 1 1 0.45 0.4 \^ Short 1993 .0.35 0) > 0.3 _ ___I^^ Short 1994 c o o0.25 Q. O ^\^ ^"''^^-cV'-^ \^Long -~-<^ 1993 ': \. ^^^ 1994""^ Long T3 S 0.2 ^v : ^\ ; 0.15 0.1 \ - ' 0\^ 0.05 i 0.1 i 0.2 i 0.3 0.4 1 1 1 0.5 0.6 0.7 Timing (proportion of group duration): bw=0.075 "^-^-J "^^^ 0.8 0.9 - Figure 4: Bids 0.7 1 - High Chit Values 1 0.6 --X ; 0.5 ra io.4 o - Short 1993 Long 1 99 3 2 lo3 o Short 1994 ~~^-.„^^ . Long 199 CO 0.2 \^ ^^^C^;_v ^-^ 0.1 0\ ^^"^^-^ \ ^"^^ ^..___ 1 0.1 1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 Timing (proportion of group duration): bw=0.075 0.8 0.9 Figure 5: Proportion of Sliort Duration Groups 0.8 1 1 y 0.7 ,.- 1 '.^ / / (A / 0.6 a. / o Medium m / \ 0.5 - \ \ o N : / z:^^^^- o0.4 o eo o -/ - ; 'J" / — - .^.^^^ _ ; // / / 0.3 - // // // Higli // // 0.2 Low 1992 1993 1994 1995 i i i 0.1 1997 1996 Year 1998 1999 2000 2001 Table Dependent 1: Chit Value-Income Relationship chit value variable: Chit value (thousands of Rs): A. Multinomial logit 10 15 25 30 50 100 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) model Income -0.156 0.009 0.030 0.058 0.071 (0.010) (0.012) (0.009) (0.008) (0.009) 1.574 -0.528 0.147 -0.040 -1.345 (0.041) (0.051) (0.041) (0.040) (0.050) Constant B. Linear probability model Income -0.003 -0.0001 0.00006 -0.0003 0.001 0.003 (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0003) (0.0001) 0.409 0.083 0.175 0.137 0.158 0.038 (0.004) (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) Constant Note: chit value is the product of the Chit value and income are measured Muhinomial logit model Linear probability model Number of observations is is monthly contribution and the duration. in thousands of Rs. estimated with chit value=30 as the base \ alue. estimated independently for each chit value. in all regressions is 20,885. Standard errors in parentheses. Table 2: Group Level Descriptive Statistics Breakdown of total groups m each chit value (%) Chit value (thousands ofRs): 10 15 25 30 50 100 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Duration LOW 20 months HIGH 17.75 3.41 1.72 4.42 3.59 11.30 8.40 - 25.77 -- 23.08 10.43 30 months -- 96.59 -- 30.94 -- 11.30 40 months 73.56 - 71.82 5.52 12.31 41.74 0.28 ~ 0.69 -- 61.03 13.91 60 months - ~ - 59.12 -- 1.74 100 months — — — — — 9.57 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 1059 381 291 181 195 115 SHORT 25 months LONG 50 months Total Total MEDIUM number of groups Note: Chit value is the product of the monthly contribution and the the Number of participants Groups is number of participants in the group. equal to the duration of the group in months. are divided into three aggregate chit values (low, medium, high) and two aggregate durations (short, long). Table 3: Individual Level Descriptive Statistics Low Chit value: Medium High 9Q3 1994 1993 1994 1993 1994 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 2.90 2.98 3.66 3.66 4.84 7,59 (2.70) (3.06) (4.79) (3.00) (9.12) (35.94) 0.01 quantile 0.65 0.65 0.90 0.90 1.00 1.00 0.05 quantile 1.00 1.00 L25 1.19 1.50 1.50 0.10 quantile 1.14 1.12 L52 1.55 1.86 1.94 0.25 quantile 1.63 1.70 2.23 2.24 2.58 2.71 0.50 quantile 2.47 2.50 3.00 3.03 3.55 3.83 0.75 quantile 3.50 3.50 4.10 4.33 5.00 5.25 0.90 quantile 4.90 5.00 5.79 6.00 7.35 8.00 0.95 quantile 5.99 6.25 7.48 7.40 10.00 10.00 0.99 quantile 9.24 10.00 12.45 12.50 33.33 60 00 0.17 0.23 0.15 0.20 0.12 0.24 Year: 1 A. Income Distribution (individual subscribers) Mean (standard deviation) B. Proportion of corporate subscribers Note: Income Aggregate is measured chit value: Low in thousands of Rs. if chit value=IOOOO, Medium if 10000<chit value<50000. High if chit value>=50000. Table Dependent Timing variable: Low Chit value: Medium 1994 1993 Year: Corporate subscriber Number of observations Note: Timing is Low measured if chit as the Standard errors in parentheses. 1994 1993 1994 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -0.124 -0.105 -0.144 -0.151 -0.118 (0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.006) (0.010) (0.008) 0.535 0.543 0.530 0.543 0.529 0.541 (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) 21,400 14,635 14,300 13,411 7,555 6,750 winning month divided by the value=10000. Corporate subscriber equals one 1993 High -0.124 Constant Chit value: Timing of Winning Bids 4: if Medium if total duration of the group. 10000<chit value<50000. High finance company, zero otherwise. if chit value>=50000. Table Dependent 5: Preliminar>' Sorting Regressions (1993) Corporate subscriber variable: (1) (2) Low A. Coarse Partition of chit value (Nv) (4) Medium (5) High 0.012 0.016 0.095 (0.008) (0.007) (0.012) Short duration 0.177 0.130 0.115 (0.003) (0.005) (0.004) 20,806 10,723 7,394 Low Medium High Constant Number of observations (3) B. Coarse partition of contribution (v) 0.022 0.023 0.061 (0.012) (0.007) (0.008) Short duration 0.176 0.129 0.115 (0.003) (0.005) (0.004) Number of observations 19,398 10,727 8,798 C. Fine partition of chit value (Nv) 10,000 Constant Short duration dummy measured 50,000 0.034 0.056 0.085 0.150 (0.013) (0.026) (0.015) (0.026) 0.180 0.130 0.090 0.087 0.149 (0.003) (0.006) (0.022) (0.005) (0.009) 17725 4696 784 3683 2063 m Rs. Low if chit value= 10000, Medium if chit value 10000-50000, High if chit value>=50000. Contribution: Low if contribution<500/month. Medium if contribution 500-1000, High if contribution>1000. Chit value: Corporate subscriber equals one if finance company, zero otherwise. Short duration equals one if the group Regressions use 1993 data only. Standard errors in parentheses. is 100,000 0.009 Number of observations is 30,000 (0.008) Constant Note: Chit value and Contribution 25.000 of less than 40 months duration. Table Dependent Bid variable: Low Chit value: Medium Long Short Duration: (1) Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Period 5 Period Period 1 * 1994 dummy 2* 1994 dummy Periods * 1994 Period 4 * 1994 Periods * 1994 dummy dummy dummy is Chit value: if chit Each group is 0.345 0.466 0.357 0.527 (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.002) 0.202 0.310 0.262 0.371 0.263 0.418 (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) 0.137 0.220 0.173 0.275 0.173 0.304 (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) 0.090 0.117 0.101 0.181 O.IIO 0.197 (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) 0.062 0.065 0.064 0.076 0.064 0.085 (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) 0.002 -0.074 -0.051 -0.169 -0.064 -0.224 (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.005) (0.003) 0.008 -0.039 -0.004 -0.084 -0.001 -0.123 (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) -0.003 -0.001 -0.006 -0.017 0.005 -0.031 (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) -0.013 -0.005 -0.006 -0.002 -0.003 -0.009 (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) (0.004) (0.003) -0.010 -0.009 -0.010 -0.009 -0.006 -0.014 (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.004) (0.003) 5470 29543 13204 13732 2286 11697 Medium if chit than 40 months. divided into 5 equal periods: Period in parentheses. (6) 0.368 chit value. value 10000-50000, High Long 1- if chit value>=50000. duration groups last for 40 months or more. Period coefficients highlight bids greater than 0.3 in Standard errors (5) (0.001) value=10000. last for less (4) (3) Long Short 0.258 measured as the bid amount divided by the Low Short duration groups Bold face (2) High Long Short (0.002) Number of observations Note; Bid Bid Regressions 6: 5, Rows covering 1-5 its entire duration in sequence. and the change in those bids in Rows 6-10. Table Dependent 7: Sorting Regressions (1993 versus 1994) Corporate subscriber variable: Low Chit value/Contribution: Medium Long Short Duration: (1) A. Partition bv 1 994 (3) (2) High Long Short Long Short (4) (5) (6) chit value (Nv") dummy Constant Number of observations 0.004 0.066 0.030 0.063 0.045 0.133 (0.011) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) (0.019) (0.007) 0.189 0.177 0.145 0.130 0.210 0.115 (0.008) (0.003) (0.005) (0.005) (0.015) (0.005) 5,470 29,543 13,204 7,832 2,280 11,697 B. Partition by contribution (v) 1994 dummy Constant Number of obsep.'ations Note: Corporate subscriber equals one if -0.010 0.066 0.023 0.063 0.044 0.133 (0.017) (0.005) (0.006) (0.008) (0.011) (0.007) 0.198 0.176 0.152 0.129 0.176 0.115 (0.012) (0.003) (0.005) (0.006) (0.009) (0.005) 2.088 29.788 13,344 7.587 5.522 11.697 finance company, zero otherwise. Low if chit value= 10000, Medium if chit value 10000-50000. High if chit value>=50000. Contribution: Low if contnbution<500/month. Medium if contribution 500-1000, High if contribution>1000. Chit value: Short duration groups last for less Standard errors in parentheses. than 40 months. Long duration groups last for 40 months or more. Table 8: Change Term in Structure and Participation Low Chit value; Medium High 1993 1994 1993 1994 1993 1994 (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Private subscribers 7,688 11,331 12,133 10,772 6,637 5,108 Corporate subscribers 3,713 3,304 2,167 2,639 929 1,643 Year: Panel Panel Panel A B C : : : Subscriber participation Proportion of short duration groups Distribution of group durations 0.217 0.318 0.573 0.656 0.217 0.359 (0.017) (0.023) (0.025) (0.024) (0.033) (0.037) 14.65 21.26 2.05 4,69 6.83 4.79 7.07 10.51 8.70 8.85 11.80 22.75 (%) Duration: 20 months SHORT 25 months 30 months — - 46.55 52.08 3.11 8.38 40 months 78.11 67.99 27.11 22.40 16.77 20.96 0.17 0.23 LONG 50 months 60 months .. 100 months — ~ — 100 100 Total Note: Chit value: Low Short duration groups if chit value=10000. last for less Medium than 40 months. if chit Long 44.10 32.34 11.18 10.18 — — 6.21 0.60 100 100 100 100 value 10000-50000, High A reports number of participants in each chit value in each year. Panel B measures proportion of short if chit value>=50000. duration groups in each chit value in each year using group level data. Proportion of short duration groups in 1994 C — 11.98 duration groups last for 40 months or more. Panel Panel 1.79 13.81 is significantly higher, at the 5 percent level, for all values. reports distribution of group durations in each chit value in each year (measured as percentage of all groups). Standard errors in parentheses. Table Low Chit value: Interest rate 1994 Note: Short duration groups Low Long Short (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) 16.48 14.15 18.92 18.17 24.18 20,88 (0.36) (0.12) (0.32) (0.63) (1.02) (0.56) 17.00 9.95 14.52 8.77 16.58 8.38 (0.42) (0.04) (0.15) (0.16) (0.37) (0.13) (6) if chit last for less value=10000. than 40 months. Medium if chit Long duration groups value 10000-50000, High last for if chit 40 months or more. value>=50000. interest rate (in percentage) with standard errors in parentheses. Interest rates are All High Long Short (%) 1993 Mean Rates Medium Long Short Duration: Chit value: 9: Implicit Interest means computed for short at the group level. and long duration are different at the 5% significance level except Columns 3-4 (1993). 3837 038 Date Due MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02618 4579 i!il!lil!«lilili!iii[iflill!l!i;jj;i. iiiiiBiiii >iiiiii^: iiii; ;!l|l'i(!'lll:i|!:l; =liilt aiiiiift