Bargaining Power in the Natural Gas Market: Long Term Contracts and Investment in Alternative Supply 8,148 words Wei Zhang (ANR 897837) Master Thesis, MSc. In International Economics and Finance Supervisor: dr. ir. Bert Willems September, 2010 1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 3 2 Literature Review: .................................................................................................... 4 2.1 Long term contract ............................................................................................ 4 2.2 Bargaining power .............................................................................................. 5 2.3 Renewable Energy ............................................................................................ 7 3 The Model .................................................................................................................. 9 3.1 Technology of gas ............................................................................................. 9 3.2 Players ............................................................................................................. 10 3.3 Timing of the game and the action they take .................................................. 11 3.4 The best choice of investment: from a view of a social planner in a perfectly competitive market................................................................................................ 12 3.5 Scenario........................................................................................................... 13 4 Solving Models ........................................................................................................ 13 4.1 Scenario one: No long term contract .............................................................. 13 4.1.1 The short term gas trading stage ........................................................... 13 4.1.2 The investment stage ............................................................................. 15 4.1.3 Summing up .......................................................................................... 16 4.2 Scenario two: Long term contract reached ..................................................... 17 4.2.1 The short term gas trading stage ........................................................... 17 4.2.2 Investment Stage ................................................................................... 19 4.2.3 Negotiating Stage .................................................................................. 20 4.2.4 Summing up .......................................................................................... 21 4.3 the elasticity ............................................................................................. 22 5 Numerical Example ................................................................................................ 22 6 Conclusion ............................................................................................................... 24 Reference..................................................................................................................... 26 2 1 Introduction Gas has been an important source in the European Union because it is used in several economic sectors. Almost 60% of the gas required in the European Union is imported since the gas produced in European countries can not satisfy the need of industries. The consumption of gas comes from two aspects: long term contract and spot market. The most popular form of long term contracts is a take-or-pay contract. This kind of long term contract usually concludes two parts: the first one is a ―Take or pay‖ clause which means the buyer will pay for a certain volume of gas per year, whether the buyer actually uses or not; the second one is to index the price of gas to some relative energy substitute or basket of substitutes such as oil derivatives. Since the consumption of gas has been increasing considerably in recent years, the discussion about the long term contract price making has been popular for a long time. Because the gas market is not competitive, the buyer power and the seller power are considered and discussed a lot in many literatures about long term contract pricing making in the gas market. The seller power is caused by the lack of competition among main exporters—Russia has 40 percent of the total import, Norway 23 percent and Algeria 17 percent. Essentially, the reason for seller power is uneven natural distribution of gas resources in the world. Meanwhile, the buyer power is argued to be mainly by big importing companies. However, the establishment of the Gas Exporting Countries Forum further strengthens the seller power since one of the Gas Exporting Countries Forum is to ―identify and promote measures and processes necessary to ensure that Member Countries derive the most value from their gas resources, taking into consideration the nature of gas as a non-renewable source of energy‖¹. Renewable energy sources are introduced by the European Union not only for environmental protection reasons (the use of gas can worsen the problem of global warming) but also to balance the increasing seller power On the other hand, spot market plays a more and more important role in European Union gas supply. Started in the mid 1990s, short term trading developed rapidly when the UK gas market was deregulated in 1998. A gas trading hub is established in ___________________________ ¹See website of the Gas Exporting Countries Forum: http://www.gecforum.org/ 3 Zeebrugge in Belgium. Gas trade is also developing in other locations like Aachen-Eynatten and Lampertheim in Germany, or Zelzate, between Belgium and the Netherlands. There is a lot of literature about the long term contract price making. Neuhoff and Hirschhausen (2005) argued that long term contract can decrease the price of gas. Kupper (2010) made a two stages model to support that substitutions of gas can be used to lower the gas price on the spot market. However, how substitutions affect long term contract price in gas market remains unknown. This paper has two aims: (1) combining the long term price making model with the three stages model to see how the optional choice in renewable energy can affect the price and quantity of long term gas contracts and of short term gas market; (2) is the choice of investment in renewable energy the reason for the different elasticity between the short term market and long term market? This paper is structured in the following way: chapter 2 reviews previous literature about long term contracts in the gas market and strategic investment of renewable energy; chapter 3 introduces the set up of the models; in chapter 4 we will solve the models; chapter 5 shows the numerical results; the final chapter is the conclusion. 2 Literature Review: 2.1 Long term contract There is a lot of literature discussing different factors of long term contracts. The European Commission (2006) points out that long-term supply contracts are used as obstacles by incumbents of the gas market (both producers and importers) to make it difficult for new entrants to access gas on the upstream markets. Following this view, the European Commission concludes that the long term contracts slows down the market integration. The European Commission also argues that when linked to the oil derivatives price the long term contract prices do not reflect the changes in the supply and demand of gas market. This situation becomes worse when the indexation in long term contracts is linked to variables calculated with trailing averages. Hubbard and Weiner (1991) conclude that efficiency can be achieved if the price indexation provisions are taken since it links prices with changing demand conditions. Parsons(1986) shows that the gas prices will move in the same parallel way with substitute’s prices under the 4 assumption of a perfect competitive market. However, Golombek and Hoel (1987) point out that a negative relation should exist between the oil price and the gas price for an efficient contract when the gas importing country or the gas exporting country is risk averse and none of them is a risk lover. When mentioned the take-or-pay clause of the long term contract, the European Commission argues that the need for the seller to buy and sell on gas trading hubs is limited by the take or pay obligations. The European Commission further points out that this limitation causes low liquidity, and hence increases the risks of trading by reducing the chances of finding an acceptable counter-party when a trader needs to close a position. However, many papers give positive comments for take-or-pay obligations. Masten (1988) concludes that the price is set by equalizing the expected marginal revenue and marginal cost under take-or-pay provisions. Crocker Masten (1985) and Mulherin and (1986) show a negative relation between the take-or-pay requirements and the number of pipelines serving a field and a positive relation between the take-or-pay requirements and the number of independent sellers located in a field by empirical evidence, which is used to support the cost of transaction hypothesis. Valencia Marin (2009) compares the efficiency of four situations: no contract, the complete contract, the take or pay contract and a forward contract. By comparing the social welfare and the utility of the buyers and sellers, she draws the conclusion that the complete contract has the highest expected utility for the seller. Creti Bertand Villeneuve (2003) show that the European Union position on long term contracting mixes up contract duration and flexibility by analyzing the role of take-or-pay clauses and price indexation rules. They also discuss the theoretical and empirical research linked to American experience and whether regulation distorts optimal contract duration. 2.2 Bargaining power Galbraith (1952) introduced the concept of ―countervailing power‖ which stands for the counterbalance power of large buyers in concentrated downstream markets against the supplier power. Following his theory, several authors evaluate the ability of large buyers to lower the product price, mainly focusing on the size of buyers, the mode of competition and the number of retailers. In a model presented by Snyder (1996), one buyer can gain advantage over the sellers 5 by purchasing all of unfilled orders at once. Besides, the author concluded that the growth of buyer will affect the profits of all buyers in the market. For example, all buyers are benefiting from lower prices if a buyer grows through a merger with unchanged market size, meanwhile all buyers pay higher prices if a buyer grows through addition. Von Ungern-Sternberg (1996) uses a two-stage game model to study the predictions of the theory of countervailing power. In the first stage, one single producer bargains with N retailers about the whole sole price. Nash bargaining solution is achieved in the first stage. The author concludes that if the producer’s bargaining power increases or his outside option improves the equilibrium wholesale price rises. In the second stage, the retailers compete with each other and the price is achieved either under Cournot competition or perfect competition among retailers. Von Ungern-Sternberg (1996) shows that retailers can benefit from lower price if the number of retailers decreases in case of perfect competition, which proves the hypothesis of countervailing power. However, when the number of retailers decreases in Cournot competition, the result shows that the lower intensity of competition has negative effects which is always outweigh the positive effects of countervailing power. Dobson and Waterson (1997) introduce a two stage complete information game to show the effects of increased retail concentration on consumer prices and welfare. In first stage, an input supplier negotiates transfer price with each retailers. In the second stage, the retailers set prices to consumers by competing with each other. The result shows that the substitutability of the retailers’ services plays an important role for the profit of supplier. If the retailers’ service is very close substitutes, higher competition among retailers can decrease the price and the profit of suppliers while social welfare increases. However, the supplier could protect its profit by dealing only one retailer at one time. Ruffle (2000) points out that when two sellers simultaneously choose a price and a quantity for buyers to choose which one to purchase, the buyers also have the ability to make sellers lower the prices. By forgoing profitable purchases as part of long-term strategies, the buyers gain market power. Six years later, Ruffle and Engle-Warwick (2006) further researched the ability of a small number of buyers to influence the pricing of a monopolist by doing experiments. The result shows that a smaller number of buyers can make the price lower in the market since the monopolist seller is afraid of provoking costly withholding. 6 Inderst and Wey (2000) point out that retailers have more incentive to get bargaining power by merger with increasing unit costs, meanwhile suppliers have more incentive to merger if goods are substitutes. This result comes from the assumption that demand is independent at all retailers by using Nash bargaining solution. Inderst (2005) concludes that the size of the buyer can cause different results for price with different number of sellers. If there is only one seller, a large buyer gets low purchasing price per unit while small buyers pay lower price if there are many sellers under the assumption that the sellers have strictly convex costs. Neuhoff and Hirschhausen (2005) argued that long term contracts can benefit both producers and consumers. The main idea is that through the model based on the assumption that the long-run demand elasticity is significantly lower than the short-run elasticity, they showed both strategic producers and consumers benefit from the lower prices and larger market volume. They started the models of long term and short term demand with the assumption that short term demand had different elasticity with long term demand. They used a two stages model: the producers are oligopoly and they decided on the quantity of long term then short term supply was also decided by taking the long term supply out of the whole supply while the consumers decided the investment in long term equipment and the expected demand. The core part of the model is that the authors added a ―r‖ on demand slope to show that short term demand is more price responsive. Based on the rule that the producers would maximize their profit, they showed the result that if the elasticity was significantly different between long term demand and short term demand (the demand slope scaled factor exceeded 4.8), both the consumers and the producers would benefit from the long term contracts since the consumers benefit from lower price and the producers benefit from large demand of gas. There is one thing to be discussed in the paper of Neuhoff and Hirschhausen (2005): they only showed the result that both consumers and producers would benefit from long term contracts, if there was different elasticity between short term demand and long term demand, but they didn’t explain where the different elasticity comes from. Why in the short term market is the demand more price sensitive? It could be the other choices which leads this different elasticity in different gas market. 2.3 Renewable Energy The Commission of the European Communities published an article in 2007 to 7 introduce the long term vision for renewable energy sources in the EU. The paper first shows the recent situation of EU renewable energy, and explains the different achievements in different regimes. The paper also introduces a possible way to achieve an increased role for renewable energy sources. The paper states some principles including a framework based on long term mandatory targets, increased flexibility in target setting across sectors and so on. Moreover, the paper gave a brief overview of the impact assessment of the renewable energies. It is very clear that the renewable energy sources contribute a lot to solving the climate change problem since renewable energies cause low even zero greenhouse gas emissions. Besides, the security of energy supply can be strengthen by increasing the renewable energy penetration of the total energy supply. The reason is renewable energy can increase the share of domestically produced energy, diversify the fuel mix, diversify the sources of energy imports and increase the proportion of energy obtained from politically stable regions. Mentioning the cost and competitiveness factor, this paper gave a general view that the significant difference among renewable sources leads to the distortion in favour of non renewable energy sources although the cost of renewable energy sources decreased over the last 20 years. The international prices of conventional energy sources like oil together with finance mix, the technology choices made and the degree of competition in renewable sectors will affect the result whether the target can be achieved. Kupper (2010) discusses whether the decision of European Union to become a low carbon economy by investing in renewable energy, could also be a strategic solution of decreasing seller power and protecting the European economy from deeply relying on the energy imports. He introduces a two stages model that starts with simple situation. He assumed that only one producer and one supplier shared the profit that the producer got from price-taking consumers. The importer could make product from two technologies: no-capacity-limited gas which was imported after paying a sunk investment cost and capacity-limited energy with investment cost. With complete information, the first stage of the model is the investment stage and the second stage is bargaining stage. Started with linear cost function and demand function, the author introduced Shapley value to solve the problem of players sharing the joint payoff in bargaining stage and distinguished the case that the marginal cost of gas is bigger than the new technology from the case that marginal cost of gas is smaller than the new technology in the 8 investment stage. The result shows that unused local capacity can lower the gas price as a threatening role since under linear cost assumption the local technology turns to be either fully used or not sued at all. The author then used non-linear cost function assumption that the supply cost of gas is convex instead of the linear cost function assumption in the beginning. The results remain the same with the situation of the linear cost function which is although some capacity remains unused it still makes the gas prices decrease and the importer and exporter share the surplus equally. The author also used numerical illustration to show different effects of different alternative technologies used by importers. In the numerical illustration, it turns out that importers had the largest gains by investing nuclear. Taking the government which aims to improve the social welfare of the importing county in to account, the author showed that through tax and subsidy instrument the government can affect the decision of the importer which is showed by numerical illustration later. The author further described the situation of more importers. Except the investment is likely to be suboptimal, the result that investing in new technology will reduce the gas price remains the same. There are some questions to be discussed for the paper of Kupper (2010). First of all, the assumption that the investment cost of gas was sunk underestimates the incentive of importer to invest in new technology. Secondly one exporter assumption is restrictive as there are three main exporter countries. Even in the future the market power of the exporters will be strengthen through the establishment of the Gas Exporting Countries Forum, there is still limited competition among export countries. Finally, this paper focuses on the effect of investment in new technology on short term market. But how the investment in new technology affects the long term contracts price remains unknown. The choice of investing in renewable energy could just be a strategic threaten for increasing the buyer bargaining power in the negotiation stage. After getting a reasonably lower price for long term gas contracts, the importer might finally not invest in any local technology. 3 The Model 3.1 Technology of gas In the early 1950s, natural gas was seen as a by-product of the exploitation of oil. The use of gas was limited and the transportation and the storage costs were high in the 9 beginning. The situation had not been changed until the technology of liquefied natural gas (LNG) was invented. The GIIGNL introduces the technology of LNG in their paper which shows that the LNG Process Chain includes the Extraction, Processing, Liquefaction, Transport, Storage, Regasification and Distribution to consumers of LNG. Extraction of natural gas produces feed gas then cleaning feed gas by separating and removing various extraneous compounds is done during the processing of LNG. The next step, liquefaction of the natural gas, is achieved by refrigeration down to approximately -162℃. After transporting the LNG over long distances by sea in ships or over shorter distances by trucks, natural gas is sent out to consumers through a pipeline distribution network. The LNG Process chain is proved to be very safe and is widely used in the world. But the absence of exclusive LNG trading hubs given the high costs of storing LNG limits the development of LNG market. 3.2 Players We propose a simplified model of bilateral negotiation in which two players are considered: a domestic firm that imports gas to produce electricity and a foreign exporter who exports gas. In the model, the domestic firm which is referred as producer and the foreign exporter will behave with the market power since there is only one exporter and one importer. But in the beginning we will also consider the situation of no market power. The price and investment decision will be discussed in a perfect competition market from a social planner’s view. In our model, we assume that the electricity generating company is a monopolist in the domestic market. To produce electricity, the domestic producer can use two technologies: one based on gas imported from the exporter both in short term and long term, the other using a fuel either locally available or geographically unconcentrated. The latter technology can refer to renewable energy. We will call the technology the producer can invest in ―local‖ technology throughout the whole paper. The total demand of gas for the domestic firm comes from two parts--short term demand and long term demand or only the short term demand in case that there is no long term gas contract reached. There is only one exporter in our model since current foreign gas supply to the European Union is concentrated and the concentration is even more given the truth that a further more concentrated organization will be established. The exporter 10 supplies the gas both under long term contract a longer term contract or long term contracts and in short term market in a short term market or the short term market. 3.3 Timing of the game and the action they take We begin by considering the interaction between the producer and the exporter and do not consider any environmental damage. We also assume that the information is complete hence there are no problems of uncertainty and asymmetric information. There are three stages in the model: The first stage is the negotiating stage. In this stage, the producer will negotiate the quantity and price he needs for same as before long term gas contract. The second stage is the investment stage, in this stage the producer will decide whether to invest in the new technology and how much to invest if he decides to build new capacities. The third stage is the short term gas trading stage. In this stage the producer will buy the quantity he needs from the short term gas market. We will start from the third stage of the game. Then back to the second, then back to the first stage. There are three situations that the quantity the producer needs, denotes by Q, comes from: If there is no long term gas contract reached in the negotiating stage, all quantity comes from the local technology he invests, denotes by QS , and from short term market trading, denotes by QST ; If there is a long term gas contract reached in the first stage and the producer decides to invest in local technology, the quantity comes from the local technology he invests, from short term market trading and from the long term gas contract, denoted by QLT ; It’s also possible that the producer decides not to invest in local technology, then the quantity only comes from long term gas contracts and from short term market trading. In a formula, it can be expressed as Q QST QLT QS . If the producer invests in new capacity to produce local energy, he will have a total cost k per unit of capacity which includes all costs per unit of capacity such as fixed cost and marginal cost. Let's assume the exporter faces a linear demand function with a demand intercept A and demand slope b, which can be expressed as follows: Q A b*P (4.1) P denotes price in general. The cost function of the exporter is linear and expressed with the following expression: 11 Ce c *Q (4.2) Here the per unit cost c includes the extraction and the transportation cost. We see the capital cost of importing gas is sunk since the producer has capacities based on the gas technology already installed. The quantity that the producer can supply is given by the following expression: Qs *P Here denotes the capacity the producer supplies after he invests. This function (4.3) describes the quantity the producer supplies based on the price of the market. It shows that the higher price is in the market, the higher quantity the producer will produce by new technology. To build the new local technology, the producer needs to invest k per capacity. Since the whole capacity would be Cs , the total cost CS would be: *k (4.4) First we will see how much the social planner will invest in local technology in a perfectly competitive market. 3.4 The best choice of investment: from a view of a social planner in a perfectly competitive market In a perfectly competitive market, the price is equal to the marginal cost of gas that the producer imports, which means P=c. A social planner will decide how much to invest in local technology. After Putting P=c into expression (4.3), we get the new expression of quantity supplied by local technology: Qs *c (4.5) The social planner will try to maximize the social welfare—here is only the profit of producer: MAX ( * c2 2 k* ) We get the corner solution of (4.6), which is as long as c 2 (4.6) 2k the social planner will invest the local technology and the quantity the producer use will fully come from the local technology. Keep this result in mind, later we will see the different result when 12 there exists market power. 3.5 Scenario There are two scenario in our model, the first one is that there is no long term gas contract reached in the negotiating stage. We first will see the short term gas trading decision about the price and quantity of gas. Then we will move to the investment stage to see the investment decision. The second scenario shows the situation that there is a long term gas contract reached in the negotiating stage. There are different decisions of the short term gas market and investment in local technology affected by the quantity of the long term gas contract. We will also see decisions of long term gas contract about the price and quantity. 4 Solving Models We start from the scenario one. 4.1 Scenario one: No long term contract In this situation, there is no long term gas contract reached in the first stage. The producer has already invested in substitutions in the second stage and can provide other energy sources to produce electricity by themselves. But the producer still needs to buy gas in the short term market and the producer is price taker in the short term gas trading stage. 4.1.1 The short term gas trading stage The fact that there is no long term contract means the total demand Q comes from the short term market and the new local technology. Hence, the exporter only faces the short term demand, which is described as follows: QST Q Qs A b * PST * PST Simplifying this expression, we get: QST A (b ) * PST (4.7) Since we assume there is only one exporter, the exporter is monopolist. Thus the exporter will maximize his profit to determine the gas quantity and price in the short term market. The profit of the exporter is: 13 PST * QST e c * QST (4.8) Maximize the profit of the exporter by differentiating QST : PST * QST QST e QST PST c 0 (4.9) Calculating the result of (4.9), we can get the exporter-maximum-profit quantity which is expressed by a function of A c * (b ) QST 2 2 in the short term gas market: (4.10) Substituting the expression (4.10) in the short term demand function (4.7), we get the short term gas market price expressed by a function of PST A 2(b : c 2 ) (4.11) As we can observe from the expressions of short term gas quantity and price, the investment item plays an important role in short term gas quantity and price. The bigger the value of is, the smaller gas quantity the producer needs in the short term market and the lower the gas price in short term market. The result is reasonable in the real world. It is obvious that in reality if the producer invests more in local technology and can supply more by himself, then the producer will need less in the short term market and also the price will reduce. We can see it from the figure 1 from a supply-demand aspect: Figure 1 P D S D P* *0 0 P Q Q* Q 14 When the demand is less, the price and the quantity both will become smaller. Therefore, the more local technology can supply the energy to the producer, the lower the price the producer can get. However, the producer must balance this low price with the increased investment cost. This is showed below. 4.1.2 The investment stage The previous stage shows that the producer gets a better price if he invests in local technology. However, this result is costly. The producer must decide how much to invest in local technology to maximize his profit. In this stage, we will discuss the investment decision made by producer. Since the producer has already known that there is no long term gas contract in the first stage, he decides to invest in new local technology. To determine the investment of the producer, we must calculate his profit. The profit of producer comes from two parts: The first part is the surplus from the energy of local technology the producer invests, which can be described as follows: 1 s1 PQs 2 (4.12) Substituting the expression(4.3) into (4.12), we can get the first part??? producer surplus can be rewritten as follows: s1 Qs2 2 s1 ( * PST ) 2 2 2 * PST2 (4.13) The second part is the surplus from the gas of short term market trading the producer buys. We calculate it as follows: s2 Q2 2b (4.14) Substituting the expression(4.1) into (4.14), we can get the first part producer surplus can be rewritten as follows: s2 ( A b * PST ) 2 2b (4.15) 15 The total profit the producer can get is the sum of these two parts: s s1 s2 C s (4.16) The producer will try to maximize his profit, which is the total surplus in this case, to determine the his investment in new technology. This is described as follows: s 0 By differentiating the quantity item of each expression of producer surplus, we get the following expression: s PST2 2 * PST * P ST PST b * PST * PST k 0 (4.17) Substituting the expression (4.11) into (4.17) then simplifying it, we get the optimal choice of investment in new local technology for the producer: 3 A2 8k c 2 b (4.18) As shown in (4.18), the investment has a positive relation with c--the per unit cost of importing gas. It also fits the reality very well because when the per unit cost of importing gas is higher, the producer has more incentive to invest the new technology. The cost of building a new local technology has a negative effect on the capacity. If the cost of building a new local generation is higher, the investment in new local technology would be lower. We can also see that the investment has a negative relation with the price elasticity item b. The bigger the elasticity is, the smaller the investment is. It is obvious that if the demand is very sensitive to the price, the producer will lower his investment. Besides, we can see that as long as c 2 8k , the producer will invest in local technology. Compared to the result of the first choice from a social planner's view, we can see that even the space c 2 2k , the producer will still invest in the local technology for bargaining power. On the contrary, the producer will not invest in local technology if space c 2 8k while the social planner will still invest in local technology under this situation. This is caused by the sellers market power. As we know we assume that there is no long term gas contract reached in the first stage. So there is no need to discuss the negotiation stage. 4.1.3 Summing up In this Scenario there is no long term gas contract reached in the negotiation stage, the 16 producer decides to invest local new technology and supply part of the energy himself. We should notice that during the time that the new technology is built, the producer is still getting the gas from the long term gas contract he signed before because the duration of the long term contract is usually fifteen years or more. As we can see from the result, the optimal investment choice for the producer to build the new local technology is affected by the per unit gas cost, cost of building a new generation and the demand elasticity. If the demand is very sensitive to the price, then the producer will invest less because the uncertainty of demand. Also if the per unit cost of gas is high, the producer has more incentive to invest to reduce his energy cost. The high investment cost will lower the incentive to invest in a new local technology. Then in the short term gas market, the exporter will charge a lower price if the producer can supply more energy himself and the quantity the exporter sold in the market also decrease with increasing energy made by local new technology. In the end, compared to the investment decision made by the social planner in a perfectly competitive market, market power distorts the investment decision not only because the buyer wants to gain bargaining power but also because the market power owned by the seller. 4.2 Scenario two: Long term contract reached In this situation, the long term gas contract is signed in the first stage. The producer also invested in substitutes in the second stage and can provide other energy sources to produce electricity by themselves. Moreover the producer needs to buy gas in the short term market and the producer is price taker in the short term gas trading stage. 4.2.1 The short term gas trading stage The exporter faces the same linear demand function (4.1) and has the same linear cost function (4.2). The producer also has the same supply function for new energy resource as (4.3). Since there is a long term contract reached in the first stage, the total demand Q now is met from three parts: long term gas contract, short term market and the new local technology. In this stage, we take the quantity and price of gas in long term gas contract as given since the producer and the exporter have already settled them down by negotiating in the first stage. Now the demand the exporter faces in short term gas market is : 17 QST Q Qs QLT A b * PST * PST QLT Simplifying this expression we get: QST A (b ) * PST QLT (4.19) The exporter will maximize his profit to determine the gas quantity and price in short term market. The profit of exporter now is: PST * QST e PLT * QLT c * (QST QLT ) (4.20) Maximizze the profit of the exporter by differentiating QST , we can get: e QST e QST 0 A QLT b 2QST c 0 (4.21) Calculating (4.21), we can get the exporter-maximum-profit quantity in the short term gas market which is expressed by a function of contract QLT : A QLT QST 2 c * (b 2 and the quantity of long term gas ) (4.22) Substituting the expression (4.22) in the short term demand function (4.19), we get the short term gas market price expressed by a function of PST A QLT 2(b ) c 2 and QLT : (4.23) As shown in (4.22), the quantity for the exporter to make the optimal profit in the short term market is affected by the quantity of the long term gas contract and the investment in the new local technology. The more quantity supplied by the long term gas contract, the less quantity will be in short term gas market. Meanwhile, the more investment the producer invests in local technology, the smaller the quantity will be in short term gas market. The equation (4.23) shows that the price of the short term gas market has a negative relation with the quantity supplied by the long term gas contract and the investment in new local technology. It is very usual that based on demand-supply theory, the lower demand will cause lower equilibrium quantity and price. Referring to this case, the 18 quantity supplied by the long term gas contract and by new local technology will cause a lower demand hence leads to a lower equilibrium quantity and price in the short term market. 4.2.2 Investment Stage The previous stage shows that the producer gets a better price in the short term gas market if he invests in local technology and signs a long term gas contract. However, the producer still needs to decide how much to invest in local technology to maximize his profit. The cost function of the producer remains the same with (4.4) To determine the investment of producer, we must calculate his profit. The profit of the producer still comes from two parts: The first parts remains the same with the situation that there is no long term contract reached in the first stage, which is equation (4.13); the second part is from the gas he buys from both long term contract and short term gas trading, but still can be described as function (4.15), notice that the price here has a different expression from situation1. Therefore, the total profit can still be described as (4.16) Maximizing the total profit of producer by differentiating the quantity item we can get: s s 0 PST2 2 * PST * P ST PST b * PST * PST k 0 (4.24) Substituting the expression (4.23) into (4.24) then simplifying it, we get the optimal choice of investment in new local technology for a producer which can be expressed as follows: 3( A QLT ) 2 8k c 2 b (4.25) As we can see from expression (4.25), the investment is affected by the quantity supplied by the long term gas contract, the per unit cost of gas and the elasticity. The more quantity the producer gets from long term gas contract, the less he will invest in new local technology. Meanwhile, the effect of per unit cost of gas, of investment cost and of the elasticity on investment in new local technology remains 19 the same with Scenario one. Substituting (4.24) into (4.22), we can get the new expression of PST : PST 1 8k c 2 * 2 3 c 2 (4.26) As shown in (4.26), the investment cost k and the per unit cost of gas have a positive effect on the short time gas price. The higher investment cost k makes the short term gas price higher since the higher investment cost decreases the investment in substitutions hence increases the demand of gas in the short term market. Besides, it is obvious that the higher per unit cost of gas can lead to a higher gas price in the short term market. Substituting (4.25) into (4.22), we can get the new expression of QST : QST (1 c * 3 8k c 2 )* A QLT 2 (4.26) As can be shown in (4.26), the investment cost k has a positive relation with short term gas quantity while the quantity of the long term gas contract and the per unit cost of gas have a negative effect on the short term gas quantity. 4.2.3 Negotiating Stage In the investment stage, we get the expression of optimal investment in substitutes for the producer. Now we turn to the negotiating stage which is also the first stage of the whole game. We assume that it is a perfect arbitrage situation. Under this assumption, the producer is an arbitrager who will sign the long term contract when the gas price of the long term contract is equal to the price of the short term market. Otherwise, the producer will only buy gas from the lower price situation—either only from short term gas market or from long term gas contract. In this situation, the long term gas price is: PLT PST A QLT 2(b ) c 2 1 8k c 2 * 2 3 c 2 (4.27) Now we turn to the decision of the exporter for gas quantity of long term contract. The exporter will try to maximize his profit, which is: e P ST *QST PLT * QLT c * (QST QLT ) (4.28) Substituting (4.26) and (4.27) into (4.22), we can get the new expression: 20 e 1 8k c 2 ( * 2 3 c * ((1 c * c 3 A QLT ) * (1 c * )* 2 2 8k c 2 3 8k c 2 )* A QLT 2 1 8k c 2 ( * 2 3 c ) * QLT 2 QLT ) Simplifying the function above, we get the expression as follows: e A 8k c 2 *( 4 3 c) * (1 c * 3 8k c ) 2 QLT 8k c 2 *( 4 3 c) * (1 c * 3 8k c 2 ) (4.29) We can see from (4.29), to maximize the profit the exporter should supply the quantity of gas as much as the producer needs under the long term gas contract. 4.2.4 Summing up In this scenario, we consider the situation that there is a long term gas contract reached in the negotiating stage. Compared to the result we get in case that there is no long term gas contract reached in negotiating stage, the quantity of gas traded in the short term market is not only affected by the investment in local new technology but also affected by the quantity of long term gas contract. The quantity supplied by long term gas contract has a negative relation with the quantity traded in short term gas market. More investment in local technology also reduces the quantity trade in the short term gas market. Moreover, the price of the short term gas market is affected by the gas quantity of the long term contract and the investment in local technology in a similar way with the quantity of short term gas market is. When moving to the investment decision, we can find that the investment decision is negatively affected by the quantity of the long term gas contract while the way that it is affected by the per unit cost of gas and the elasticity remains the same with the scenario one. After rewriting the expressions of the short term gas price and quantity by putting the expression of investment term into the expressions of short term gas price and quantity, we get the results that the short term gas quantity is negatively affected by the long term gas quantity while the short term gas price has nothing to do with long term gas quantity. Whether the results holds up for all situations or just for the linear gas demand and cost function, we do not really know. We will discuss it in the future. Besides, the investment cost k has a positive effects on both the short term gas price and quantity while the per unit cost of gas c has contrary effects on the short term gas 21 price and quantity. 4.3 the elasticity Now we turn to the effect of different investment item on the elasticity of price. Rewriting the function (4.25), we get: b 3( A QLT ) 2 8k c 2 (4.30) From (4.30), we see that without investment item , the elasticity is bigger than it is with . It shows that with the choice of investment in new technology, the price is less sensitive in long term. The result explains why the long demand elasticity is lower than the short term demand in gas market in the paper of Neuhoff and Hirschhausen (2005). Above we see how investment in new technology and long term gas contract affects the price and the demand in gas market, but it is not clear how much the investment in local technology and long term gas contract affect others (c. price, total social welfare) excluding other external factors (c. elasticity, cost) . To see the relation between quantity of long term gas contract and other factors more clearly and straightforward, we now turn to numerical examples. 5 Numerical Example Figure 2 From Figure 2, we see that fixing A=100, b=0.9, c=10, k=100 both the welfare of the importer and the welfare of exporter are increasing as the gas quantity bought under 22 long term gas contract becomes bigger. The total social welfare hence increases as well. This shows that gas trading under long term gas contracts leads to more social efficiency. Both exporter and importer benefit from long term gas contract. We observe that after a certain point ( the investment in local technology becomes zero) the profit of export decreases. The possible reason for this decrease is that a lower price leads to a lower profit. There is enough gas supplied by the long term gas contract so that there is no need for investing in local technology anymore. When there is no investment in local technology, the price is affected by the demand in the short term gas market. Less demand in the short term gas market as a big part of gas is supplied by the long term gas contract leads to a lower price and hence the profit of the exporter decreases. Eventually, the price reaches the lowest point which equals to the marginal cost and the profit of the exporter is zero. Figure 3 Figure 3 shows the movement of total demand, local supply and the supply of the exporter as the gas bought through long term gas contracts increases. The local supply decreases while the supply of exporter increases. In the end, all the demand is supplied by the exporter. The demand remains the same until there is no investment in local technology. The reason is when there is no investment in local technology the price decreases until the price reaches its lowest point. This price decrease leads the demand increase until the price is steady again. 23 Figure 4 Figure 4 shows the influence in investment in local technology and short term gas price by the increase of long term gas quantity. The investment in local technology decreases then becomes zero as the gas supplied by the long term gas contract increases. The short term gas price remains the same until the investment in local technology becomes zero. The decrease of price stops when the price reaches its lowest point which equals to the cost of the gas. Combining all the numerical results above, we can see that it’s better for the producer to get all gas supply from long term gas contract instead of investing in local technology. 6 Conclusion As we all know, gas is an important natural resource used in many sectors. Concerning that gas is a non-renewable and unevenly distributed resource, market power plays an important role in gas market. As shown in this paper, compared the investment decision in local technology which is as long as c 2 2k the social planner will invest the local technology and the quantity the producer use will fully come from the local technology in perfect competitive market, the producer will invest in local technology as long as c 2 8k due to the seller market power. From the different decision constraints, we can see the market power leads to inefficiency of the decision on investment in local technology. By stating a three stage game model, we see that the correlations among investment in local technology, short term gas price and 24 quantity and long term gas and quantity in the situation that there is market power in gas market since we assume there is only one producer and one exporter. As is shown in the model, investment in local technology has a negative relation with short term gas price, which means with investment in local technology the producer gains bargaining power so that the price becomes lower. Similarly, the investment in local technology will reduce the quantity of gas trade in short term market. It is obvious that if producer gets more supply by himself the demand in short term gas market decreases. When moved to the optimal choice of investment in local technology, we can see it is affected by the per unit gas cost, cost of building a new generation, the quantity of long term gas contracts and the demand elasticity. By fixing the per unit gas cost, the cost of building a new generation and the demand elasticity, we can see how the quantity of long term gas contracts affect the investment in local technology in numerical examples. Although after rewriting the expressions of short term gas price and quantity by putting the expression of investment term into the expressions of short term gas price and quantity, we get the results that the short term gas quantity is negatively affected by long term gas quantity while the short term gas price has nothing to do with long term gas quantity, we can not conclude that it is in general situation since we have linear demand function and linear cost function assumption. Finally, the numerical examples show that the producer can make optimal profit by buying all gas he needs from long term gas contracts. 25 Reference European Commission, DG Competition Report on Energy Sector Inquiry, SEC (2006) 1724 (Brussels, 10 January 2007), LNG Information Paper No. 2 –The LNG Process Chain. The international group of liquefied Natural Gas Importers, 2009 Neuhoff K. von Hirschhausen C.,2005 Long Term vs. Short Term Contracts: A European Perspective on Natural gas. Discussion Paper Gerd Küpper ,2010, Contributions to European Energy Policy Hubbard, R and Weiner R., 1991. Efficient Contracting and Market Power: Evidence from the US Natural Gas Industry, Journal of Law and Economics, 34, 25-67. Parsons, J., 1986: Flexibility and price terms in contract negotiations in European natural gas markets. In Center for Energy Policy Research ed. International Natural Gas Trade Project Report. MIT pp. 6-1 - 6-25 Golombek, R. and Hoel, M., 1987. The Relationship Between the price of Natural Gas and Crude Oil: Some Aspects of Efficient contracts. In, R. Golombek, M. Hoel and J. Vislie, eds. Natural Gas Markets and Contracts. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers B.V., pp. 221–37. Crocker, K. and Masten, S., 1985. Efficient Adaptation in Long-term Contracts: Take-or-Pay Provisions for Natural Gas, American Economic Review, 75, 1083-1093. Mulherin, H., 1986. Complexity in Long-term Contracts: An Analysis of Natural Gas Contractual Provisions. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 2, 105-117. Valencia Marin, 2009, Efficiency of Take of Pay Clauses in Long Term Gas Contracts Anna Creti and Bertrand Villeneuve, 2003, Long-term Contracts and Take-or-pay Clauses in Natural Gas Market Galbraith, J. K. (1952). American Capitalism: The Concept of Countervailing Power. Houghton Mifflin. Snyder, C. M. (1996). ―A dynamic theory of countervailing power‖. RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 27, No 4: 747 – 769. 26 von Ungern-Sternberg, T. 1996. „Countervailing power revisited.” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14: 507-520. Dobson, P. W., and M. Waterson. 1997. „Countervailing power and consumer prices.‖ The Economic Journal, 107(441): 418-430 Ruffle, B. J. (2000). ―Some factors affecting demand withholding in posted-offer markets”. Economic Theory, Vol. 16, No 3: 529 – 544. Ruffle, B. J. (2005). Buyer Countervailing Power: A Survey of the Theory and Experimental Evidence. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev. Department of Economics. Inderst, R. and C. Wey (2000). Market Structure, Bargaining and Technology Choice. Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin (WZB), Research Unit: Competition and Innovation. CIG Working Paper FS IV 00-12. Inderst, R. (2005). Large-Buyer Discount or Large-Buyer Premium? Working paper available in http://www.wiwi.uni-frankfurt.de/profs/inderst/Theory/theory_englisch.htm. Last visited on 27 July 2009. European Commission. 2007a. ―Renewable energy road map: renewable energies in the 21st century: building a more sustainable future.‖ COM(2006) 848 final. 27 28