The New Approach to Financial Regulation: Is it Relevant for Developing Countries? (With Applications to Latin America) LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ February 2011 Motivation • A lesson from the global financial crisis was that the existing framework for financial regulation was (to say the least) inadequate and ineffective • While a number of proposals are being advanced, consensus is moving towards a “Macroprudential Approach” • A key goal of Macroprudential regulation is to minimize the macro costs (i.e. output losses) of financial crises. In a nutshell avoid asset price bubbles and limit credit crunches In Principle, the Approach is Extremely Relevant for Emerging Markets and Other Developing countries. Credit Booms: Seven-Year Event Window (Deviation from HP trend Real Credit Per-Capita) Source: Mendoza and Terrones (2008) Based on 49 episodes in the period 1960-2006 The existing literature shows that credit booms (and busts) in emerging economies are larger than in industrial countries. (in the chart, at the peak of the booms, the average expansion in real credit per capita was almost 30 percent above trend in emerging economies—twice what is observed in industrial countries. In Principle, the Approach is Extremely Relevant for Emerging Markets and Developing Countries Also: Output losses and credit crunches are more severe after lending booms that end up in crisis, and these costs are larger in developing countries (Calderon and Serven, 2010) My Questions IN PRACTICE: 1. Are the proposals under the macroprudential approach (including Basel III) relevant for developing countries? 2. Should the basic concepts of “capital” and “liquidity” requirements be applied throughout countries without regards to the degree of financial development? 3. And (based on 1.and 2.) can the new approach prevent a financial crisis in developing countries? From the Old to the New Approach to Regulation BEFORE THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS Microprudential Regulation + - Based on indicators of current health of individual banks: • • • • • • Capital Liquidity Asset Quality Profitability Quality of Board and Management Sensitivity of Portfolio to Market Risks Macro Variables (sometimes) - For stress tests on individual banks and sometimes on aggregate financial system: • Economic Growth • Changes in Terms of Trade • Volatility of inflation • International Reserves/Short-term liabilities • The fundamental principle of microprudential regulation (and supervision) is to ensure that risks faced by individual institutions are correctly internalized in order to avoid moral hazard and minimize the costs to taxpayers from implicit deposit insurances • In this framework regulation is constant over time From the Old to the New Approach to Regulation AFTER THE CRISIS Microprudential and Macroprudential Regulation (as complements) • The goal of macroprudential regulation is to minimize the macro costs of dealing with financial crises. In a nutshell: to avoid asset price bubbles and limit credit crunches (in the crisis resolution period) • The essence of macroprudential regulation is that aggregate risk depends on the collective action of financial institutions, which varies over time. Thus, recommendations for macroprudential regulations include: • Time-varying Regulations • System-wide regulations to take into account the cross-sectional distribution of risk From the Old to the New Approach to Regulation • Theoretically, in the international academic community: “We are all macroprudentialists now.” (C. Borio paraphrasing Friedman) • In practice: a number of Emerging Market economies have been macroprudentialists for some time now • Recurrent deep banking crises and the high resolution costs involved explain this development But an important and (yet) unanswered question is: • If macroprudential regulation emphasizes cross-sectional and time differences, shouldn’t consideration also be given to huge differences between market depth and development across countries? • Could it be that some of the recommendations of the new approach are trivial for Emerging Markets while some others are not relevant? The New Approach to Regulation: Major Recommendations on the Table I. HIGHER QUALITY CAPITAL • Under the macroprudential approach, only common equity satisfies the requirement for “high quality” capital. Thus, “Tier 1” capital should be mostly composed of common equity Why? • • • • Under a microprudential view, all that matters is the ratio: capital risk-weighted assets If a bank incurs losses, it needs to restore the ratio, either increasing the numerator or decreasing the denominator Under the macroprudential view, it is important to avoid asset contraction; so capital (the numerator) should be restored (see Hanson, Kashyap and Stein (2010) If part of capital is formed by stocks “senior” to equity, such as “preferred stock”, it will be harder for the bank to raise common equity, since investors know that new equity will be used to “bail out” the position of the more senior preferred investors The New Approach to Regulation: Major Recommendations on the Table I. HIGHER QUALITY CAPITAL Basel III: Calibration of the Capital Framework Calibration of the Capital Framework Capital requirements and buffers (all numbers in percent) Common Equity (after deductions) Tier 1 Capital Total Capital Minimum 4.5 6.0 8.0 Conservation Buffer 2.5 Minimum plus conservation buffer 7.0 8.5 10.5 8.5 - 11 10.5 - 13 Countercyclical buffer range* 0 - 2.5 Total 7 - 9.5 * Common equity or other fully loss absorbing capital Source: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Rules to start being implemented in 2013, with full implementation by 2019 I. Higher Quality Capital: Where does Latin America Stand? Capital Requirements in Latin America - 2010 (to Q2) Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru Minimum Regulatory Capital to Risk Weighted Assets 11 10 - 12 9 10 10 Actual Capital to Risk Weighted Assets 18 13.8 18.1 17 13.5 14.1 10.2 14.3 15 10.5 (in percent, %) Actual Tier 1 Capital to Risk Weighted Assets Source: IMF and National Authorities • Moreover, in most countries 90% of Tier 1 capital is made up of the highest quality of capital: “Paid-in capital” + “Accumulated reserves” (formed by compulsory nondistributed profits” Caution: While a number of LA countries already meet the numerical Basel III standards, there are remaining issues with respect to accounting standards, consolidated supervision, risk-management techniques, etc. that weaken the “economic” value of assets II. Time-Varying Regulatory Requirements • A major criticism of Basel II was its procyclical nature due to constant capital requirements through the business cycle: In bad times bad loans increase capital declines credit contracts to meet requirements less output growth • Also, backward-looking provisioning rules (incurred loss model), that do not recognize the build-up of credit risks in “good times” bring about procyclicality. As with capital requirements, a rise in non-performing loans in “bad times” calls for increased provisioning and a credit contraction • Thus, Basel III includes a “countercyclical buffer” with a range of 0 – 2.5 % of common equity. The buffer will be in effect in periods of excess credit growth and the build up of risk. Basel III also includes a “conservation buffer” capital requirement, above the minimum requirement. Banks can draw on the buffer during periods of stress, but the closer banks capital ratios approach the minimum, the greater the constraints on earnings distribution. • Also, the Financial Stability Forum (2009) recommended the implementation of dynamic provisioning II. Time-Varying Regulatory Requirements in Latin America • While countries in Latin America have not yet implemented countercyclical capital requirements, several countries (Bolivia, Colombia, Peru and Uruguay) already have dynamic provisioning in place (which could play an equivalent role, given that loans are the most important asset in Latin American banking systems • In Colombia, the implementation of dynamic provisioning on consumer loans in 2008 helped to reduce the excessively rapid expansion of credit. Annual credit growth, which reached 27% by 2006, declined to 13% by 2008 • In Peru, where dynamic provisioning responds to changes in GDP growth, the rule was activated in September 2010, when the average annualized rate of growth of GDP over the previous 30 months reached 5.86% While there is not sufficient analysis, this regulatory tool seems appropriate for Emerging Markets. However, it is subject to some of the accounting problems mentioned before. III. Prompt Corrective Action that Requires Increases in the Value of Capital, not the Ratio • Prompt Corrective Action (PCA) is an important (and extremely valuable) component of microprudential regulation • A typical characteristic of PCA is early supervisory intervention (through sanctions and increased monitoring) for banks whose capital ratios fall below the minimum requirement • The contribution of macroprudential regulation is that the improvement in capital ratios should be done through increases in the value of capital (again, to contain sharp credit squeezes) III. Prompt Corrective Action that Requires Increases in the Value of Capital, not the Ratio – Latin America is Heading in the Right Direction • A number of Latin American countries include PCA in their banking regulations AND meet the macroprudential criteria • Example: Peru’s Banking Law o When dealing with the requirements that a bank under PCA needs to meet, to exit the early stages of intervention, the law reads: “La Empresa debe demonstrar, … una mejora de su posicion, la que necesariamente debe incluir aportes nuevos de capital en efectivo.” “The firm needs to demonstrate, … an improvement in its position which by necessity has to include new contributions of cash to increase capital” IV. Emphasis on “High-Quality Liquidity” and “Stable Sources of Funding” • To take into account “contagion effects”, the macroprudential approach recommends large holdings of assets that are not prone to fire-sales (that is, don’t lose liquidity) in “bad states of the world” (that is, in a crisis, when funding becomes scarce and costly) • The concern is that in a crisis, financial firms might be forced to quickly liquidate assets at fire-sale prices, thereby imposing costs on other institutions holding those same assets and on collateral values. If the linkages are strong enough, asset deflation and a credit squeeze would follow IV. Emphasis on “High-Quality Liquidity” and “Stable Sources of Funding” • Thus, the Basel Committee has recommended both a: 1. Liquidity Coverage Ratio: stock of high-quality liquid assets > 100% Net cash outflows over a 30 day period under an acute stress scenario 2. Net Stable Funding Ratio: available amount of stable funding > 100% required amount of stable funding • Regardless of the formula details and computations, there are two key issues that are highly relevant for Emerging Markets o o What is “high-quality liquidity” in Emerging Markets? What is “stable funding” (and therefore, stable deposits) in Emerging Markets? IV. “High-Quality Liquidity” and “Stable Sources of Funding” in Emerging Markets • The issue of “adequate liquidity” is well-known in Emerging Markets (both in the private and public sectors) • Experience shows that banking crises have often been accompanied by currency crises: a “run on banks” has often been associated with a “run on the currency” as investors anticipate that large depreciation and/or inflation will drastically reduce the real value of their locallydenominated wealth • Even well-structured deposit insurance can not deal with the loss of the real value of locally-denominated assets in a crisis For countries, such as those in Emerging Markets, that: A) Do not issue hard currency, and, B) Have highly open capital accounts, “High-quality liquid assets” and “stable sources of funding” are very limited (The absence of a bank-run in the US and the credibility of its deposit insurance system, are largely associated with the dollar (still) being the world’s reserve currency and, thus, the “top-quality” liquid asset) IV. “High-Quality Liquidity” and “Stable Sources of Funding” in Emerging Markets • Among the “high-quality liquid assets” recommended by the Basel Committee, I attach high value to “claims on or guaranteed by the IMF, BIS and other multilateral organizations”, as they can provide the “hard-currency” insurance needed during crisis episodes • In this regard, government debt, even if issued in domestic currency, is often not a “high-quality” liquid asset in many countries, as they lack deep markets (in some countries, pension funds provide a stable source of demand for government paper, but this is due to insufficient options for investment) • Among stable sources of funding, I favor: o An estimation of the minimum amount of deposits needed for transaction purposes (payment system) o Tier-1 Capital (to the extent that appropriate accounting standards and consolidated supervision are in place) V. Treatment of Systemically Important Financial Institutions • The macroprudential approach focuses on avoiding the collapse of markets, not necessarily institutions o Example: the entire market for asset-backed securities (based on credit cards, student loans, etc.) collapsed after the Lehman event. This implied a huge contraction in consumer credit supply • In this regard, macroprudentialists recommend addressing vulnerabilities in the financial system as a whole and not just those of the largest firms • A key recommendation is to set similar capital requirements for a given type of credit exposure, regardless of who ultimately holds the exposure (Hanson et al, 2010). Thus, if a loan is securitized into a security with tranches, all holders of tranches (hedge funds, brokerdealers, institutional investors, etc.) need to hold capital (post a margin) against that tranche • This would prevent regulatory arbitrage VI. Examples of Systemic non-bank Financial Activities in Latin America (IMF, 2009) • In Jamaica, life insurance companies that offered deposit-like instruments faced acute liquidity problems in the mid-1990s. The problems spread to affiliated commercial banks and ended in a huge financial crisis • In 2008, non-financial firms in Brazil and Mexico took large speculative positions in derivatives in the expectation of local currency appreciation. When these currencies sharply depreciated at the end of 2008, the firms incurred losses and the central banks had to intervene heavily in their respective foreign exchange markets • Although financial conglomerates operate in many Latin American countries, consolidated supervision is often weak. This means that the interconnections among all the affiliates might not be fully understood • Investment funds in Brazil and finance companies (SOFOLES) in Mexico are large and lightly regulated. Mutual funds in Bolivia experienced runs in 2002, which affected their affiliated commercial banks In this regard, Latin America and most Emerging Markets have a long way to go Systemic Risk from Foreign Banks in Latin America • Many of the 30 global financial institutions informally identified as “systemically important” have operations in Latin America: Percentage of Banking System Assets Held by Systemically Important Financial Institutions (%) Argentina Brazil Chile Colombia Mexico Peru 22.8 15.3 30.8 16.8 69 27.5 Source: Economist Intelligence Unit and Financial Times • A recent study (Izquierdo, Galindo, Rojas-Suarez, 2010) shows that in the presence of an external shock, foreign banks contract credit growth more than domestic banks. The exception is Spanish banks who behave like local banks since they fund themselves with local deposits • Enhancing of cross-border supervision arrangements and collaboration through supervisory colleges is highly recommended. Coordination for crisis resolution processes also needs to be considered A Final Remark to be Emphasized • Macroprudential regulation cannot be effective without “The Basics” of regulation, such as: o Adequate Accounting Frameworks o Qualified Supervisors o Independent Judicial Systems o Political will to implement Norms and Regulations