REVISED Draft for Comments only Please don’t quote without permission from the authors EFFECTS OF A FREE TRADE AREA OF THE AMERICAS: EVALUATION BASED ON A DYNAMIC GLOBAL GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL1 Madanmohan Ghosh Carolyn Mac Leod Strategic Investment Analysis Micro-Economic Policy Analysis Branch Industry Canada, Government of Canada Abstract In this paper we evaluate the effects of a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) on Canada and other major players using a dynamic general equilibrium multi-sector, multi-region model of global trade. The model is calibrated to GTAP version 5 Database benchmarked to 1997. We analyse the implications of a FTAA in which an arrangement like NAFTA is extended to rest of the FTAA members. This is done both under competitive and imperfect market structures. We show that the magnitudes of the effects of the FTAA differ under different market structure. Our results suggest that there are modest gains in terms of welfare, defined as Hicksian equivalent variation (EV), from the FTAA to the existing NAFTA members. However, the rest of the FTAA members lose in the short run due to the adverse terms of trade effect. Mexico, followed by Canada, is the biggest gainer. Instead of removing the differences in tariffs instantly, phasing out tariffs over 10 years minimizes the short-term welfare losses for Mercosur and Latin America. Key words: FTAA, Dynamic general equilibrium, imperfect competition. JEL classification No: C61, C68 Address for correspondence: Micro-Economic Policy Analysis Branch, Industry Canada, 235 Queen Street, C.D. Howe Building, Ottawa, Ontario, K1A 0H5, Phone: 1-613-995-6939, 1-613-565-3698, Fax: 1-613-991-1261, E-Mail: ghosh.madanmohan@ic.gc.ca, macleod.carolyn@ic.gc.ca. We are grateful to Lavoie Claude, Marcel Mérette and Mokhtar Souissi for their model code on which we build. We thank Ram Acharya, Jean Mercenier, Someshwar Rao and John Whalley for discussions and comments. Views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of Industry Canada. 1 1 1. Introduction In their Miami Summit in December 1994, the heads of state of the 34 (notable exception of Cuba) Western Hemisphere democracies agreed to construct a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) 2, negotiations for which are expected to be complete by 2005. The FTAA would be the world’s largest free market with a combined gross domestic product (GDP) of $13 trillion and 800 million consumers. The FTAA aims at progressively eliminating the barriers to trade and investment3. In this paper we analyze the potential effect of the FTAA on output, employment, trade flows, investment and economic welfare in Canada, the United States (USA) and other major regions using a dynamic multi-region, multi-sector general equilibrium model of global trade. Particular attention has been placed on regions important to Canadian trade and investment4. The import-substitution model of development, followed since the Second World War in the Latin American countries (LACs), collapsed during the 1980’s. Although, in the 1970’s, they enjoyed robust GDP growth, the decade of the 1980’s, often referred to as the "lost decade," was dreadful in economic terms for Latin America. The main reason for LAC’s poor economic performance during this time was that substantial resources had to be devoted to servicing the foreign debt, leaving little room for import growth or national investment. Structural adjustments and economic policy reforms in trade, as well as, macro-economic policy thus became inevitable (Little et al. (1993) and Alam et al. (1993)). 2 The list of countries in the agreements are Antigua and Barbuda, Argentina, Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Bolivia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Grenada, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, St. Kitts and Nevis, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, Trinidad and Tobago, United States, Uruguay and Venezuela. 3 See http://www.ftaa-alca.org/alca_e.asp for the Miami Summit's Declaration of Principles and Plan of Action for details. 4 A region may either be a single country or a composite region consisting of many countries, such as the European Union. See Appendix 1 for an overview of population, per capita GNP, and trade between Canada and FTAA countries. 2 Trade policy reform in the 1980s, for the LACs involved a shift from import substituting to outward oriented trade regimes. Chile led the change, followed by most of the countries of the hemisphere. Average tariff rates, in general, were reduced substantially and many countries simplified their tariff structures. These brought about an increase in the degree of openness, measured as the ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP, from a pre-reform level of 49% to a post-reform 58% (1991) for the LAC’s on average (Alam and Rajapatiran (1993, Diao and Somwaru (2001)). Reforms also prompted the LACs to adopt General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) consistent rules and to become members of the GATT, now World Trade Organization (WTO). Trade and macroeconomic reforms in the 1990’s to date in the LAC’s have resulted in recovered economic growth to more than 3% a year on average. Parallel to unilateral tariff reductions and macroeconomic stabilization policies, regional integration has become a vital part to Latin America’s economic performance5. Economic integration arrangements are now flourishing in the hemisphere. Import barriers have come down and emphasis has been put on attracting investment and promoting exports. MERCOSUR, the second largest regional trade arrangement in the Western Hemisphere, was established in 1991 by the Treaty of Assunción, signed by Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay. It eliminated most trade barriers among its members and established a common external tariff (CET) for most agricultural products by 1995, with longer transitions for a few sensitive products (Diao, Sowaru 2001). The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) between Canada, the USA and Mexico in 1994 was another initiative in the Hemisphere aimed at virtual elimination of trade barriers. Apart from these there are a multitude of trade arrangements that have been initiated or 5 For a discussions on why countries seek regional trade arrangements, See Ghosh (2002) and Whalley (1998). 3 re-activated during the last decade. About 40 of them are currently operating and perhaps a dozen are under negotiation (U.S.D.A, 1998)6. The FTAA is a more comprehensive and broader agreement. One key aspect of this agreement is the elimination of tariffs on both industrial and agricultural products. It is expected that elimination of tariffs would yield important welfare gains in the member countries. Despite extensive unilateral liberalizations and tariff cuts negotiated during the Uruguay round, most developing countries in the FTTA still apply relatively high tariffs. For example, the average tariff rate in Latin America on imports of agricultural products is almost 3 times that imposed by Canada7. Trade contributes significantly to the growth of output and real income in Canada, as well as in other countries. Estimates reveal that, between 1990 and 1999, increases in net exports directly accounted for 15% of economic growth in Canada8. Indirect effects, via increased specialization, technological spillovers and productivity growth, are some of the key elements of economic growth in the modern world9. The FTAA is formed to facilitate this process. So far as Canada is concerned, the importance of the American market increased dramatically while the share of exports, both to Europe and Asia-Pacific, declined. The share of exports to Latin America remained more or less constant with a tendency to fall in the late 1990’s. In this paper we use a dynamic, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model of global trade to analyze the implications of the FTAA for output, trade, investment and welfare in Canada and other regions. Computable general equilibrium models are widely used, in part, because they are very useful tools for analyzing the effects of trade policy changes. A change in 6 See Page (2000) for a review and a brief history of various regional trade arrangements covering the European Union, CACM, the Andean Group, the Group of Three, CARICOM, MERCOSUR, NAFTA, FTAA, SACU, SADC, AEC, ASEAN, SAARC, ANZCERTA, and APEC. 7 See Schott (2001) for a review of the progress made since the 1994 Summit of the Americas in laying the groundwork for a FTAA and the challenges facing the FTAA talks if countries are to conclude the negotiations by the summit-mandated deadline of January 2005. 8 The Trade and Investment Monitor, Fall-Winter, 1999-2000, MEPA, Industry Canada. 9 For a review, please see Ghosh (2002A). 4 trade policy, such as a change in tariff rates, alters the relative prices facing consumers and producers. The change in prices cause a chain of reactions in each country involving adjustments in production and trade, not only in sectors directly affected by changes in protection, but also in industries indirectly related. Computable general equilibrium models capture these interdependencies within and between economies by combining real world data with rigorous assumptions about key behavioural parameters. The behaviour of economic agents is modeled using utility/profit maximizing principles where price mechanisms play the role of resource allocation. To understand the potential impact of the FTAA on Canada and other regions we devise a negotiating scenario. In which we assume that (a) Canada and the USA reduce tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their tariffs on Mexican products if not already the same or lower, (b) Mexico reduces tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their current tariff on imports from the USA if not already the same or lower, (c) the Latin American members of FTAA reduce their tariffs on imports from Canada and USA to the same level as current Mexican tariffs on imports from Canada and USA if not already the same or lower, and (d) Intra-NAFTA tariffs remain unchanged. Depending upon when these objectives are achieved we formulate two cases, Case 1 - all the above are instantly implemented and Case 2 – commitment to tariff reductions are phased out over 9 years. We run these two simulations using both the static and dynamic versions of the model. Simulations using the dynamic model are performed under two market environments, in one where all sectors are perfectly competitive and the other where there is a mix of perfectly and imperfectly competitive sectors. First, we find that Canada, along with the USA and Mexico, experiences modest gains in terms of welfare from the FTAA in all simulations. Second, in the short run all other regions lose due to adverse terms of trade (TOT) effects. Sensitivity analyses suggest that the smaller members of the FTAA also gain from the FTAA if the elasticity demand for goods is higher in 5 bigger regions. Third, while intra-NAFTA trade falls marginally, there are substantial increases in trade between NAFTA member countries and rest of FTAA countries. Fourth, the effects of tariff reductions are larger when market structure is incorporated in the model. In general, effects from models that incorporate market structure are bigger by 20-30% not only in terms of welfare but also with respect to other key variables of the model. This is because tariff reductions in noncompetitive market conditions enhance competition, reduce market power of the monopolistic firms and force them to improve efficiency. In subsequent sections, the model and data will be explained in further detail. Then, a discussion of the results will follow, ending with a presentation of sensitivity analyses and concluding remarks. 6 2. A Dynamic Multi-Sector, Multi-Region Model of World Trade We use a multi-sector, multi-region, intertemporal CGE model of world trade10. It is an enlarged version of the prototype model developed by Lavoie, Mérette and Souissi (2001). In many ways, this model draws upon the contributions of dynamic CGE modeling by Mercenier (1995). There are two types of agents in the model, households and firms. Both the households, as well as, the firms exhibit forward-looking behaviour with certainty. The modeling of behavior suggests that a regional trade arrangement would affect responses to savings, investment, capital accumulation and, international lending and borrowing activities. The households have access to world capital markets where they can lend or borrow at a constant rate of interest. There is no explicit representation of government as an optimizing agent in the model. The government’s role, in this model, is to collect tariff revenues that are transferred to the household in a lumpsum manner. In the following sub-sections, a non-technical description of the model is provided. Interested readers can consult Appendices 2-4 for a detailed algebraic structure of the model. The households We assume that in each region a representative, infinitely lived household owns all primary factors and financial assets including the equity of the firms11. While the endowment of labour is assumed fixed and supplied inelastically to the firms, the supply of capital is augmented through investment in each region. The representative household receives income from the supply of labour and capital to the firms, dividends from the firms and lump-sum transfers from the government. The households derive utility from the consumption of a basket of goods and services in every period; it does not value leisure. The objective of the representative household in each 10 This an Arrow-Debreu model with complete markets and no money. Since our objective is to examine the efficiency rather than the distributive impact of the FTAA, a single, rather than a multi-household formulation, is used. 11 7 region is to maximize an intertemporally additive utility function discounted by a constant rate of time preference subject to an intertemporal budget constraint and capital accumulation equation12. The solution to this problem is derived as first order conditions of optimization that gives an optimal time path of consumption13. This equation expresses the consumption growth rate as a function of the discount rate, which is equal to the world rate of interest, and the growth rate of the price of aggregate consumption. Combining this equation with the budget constraint and the transversality condition, the level of consumption in each period can be determined. Once the level of consumption is determined the level of investment in each period can be determined from the budget constraint and capital accumulation equation. Aggregate spending on consumption in each period is then distributed over commodities that are either produced domestically or imported14. The details about expenditure allocations in each period are laid out in Figure 1. In each period, households follow a multi-stage budgeting procedure with respect to the allocation of aggregate expenditure across commodities (Level 1 in Figure 1). First, composite demand for each individual commodity is derived from a Cobb-Douglas demand function (Level 2). The composite bundle consists of an Armington (1969) preference specification for the competitive sector and of an Ethier (1982) preference specification (with product differentiation at the firm level) for the non-competitive sectors. In the perfectly competitive case, therefore, each good competes with foreign goods while, in the imperfectly competition case, goods from each firm compete, not only with other firms in the same country, but also with other firms in other regions of the model. Once composite consumption expenditure of individual commodities is determined, households determine how much to buy from each of the domestic and foreign firms by using CES demand functions (Level 3). 12 See Equations (1) – (7) in Appendix 2. In the actual implementation of the model we assume, however, that these adjustment costs are zero due to lack of data. 13 See Equation (8) in Appendix 2. 14 See Equations (9) – (11) in Appendix 2. 8 Figure 1 The Structure of the FTAA Model Households Firms Level 1 Composite Consumption Savings Level 2 Competitive (sector s ) Noncompetitive (sector ss) Level 3 Level 3 Sector s Region 1 Sector s Region 2 Sector s Region i Sector ss Firm 1 Region 1 Sector ss Firm 1 Region 2 Sector ss Firm 2 Region 1 Sector ss Firm 2 Region 2 Sector ss Firm n Region i 9 Along the lines followed by Abel (1980) and Hayashi (1982), investment expenditures include acquisition costs as well as adjustment costs. Adjustment costs are assumed to be quadratic in investment and depreciation15. The long-run rate of return to investment net of adjustment cost and depreciation is equalized across regions in the model since households are permitted to borrow and lend internationally at the exogenously given world rate of interest. The aggregate spending on investment in each period is distributed over commodities that are either produced domestically or imported similar way as aggregate consumption in each period described above16. Firms Firms in the model behave similarly to the households, as laid out in Figure 2. Instead of maximizing utility, the firm’s objective is to maximize profits. In each region, there are both competitive and non-competitive sectors. In the competitive industries, firms operate with constant returns to scale technology (Cobb-Douglas) and are price takers both in the product, as well as, in the factor markets. Labour and capital are assumed to be homogeneous and mobile across sectors within national boundaries, but immobile internationally. This implies that the wage-rental rates are the same across sectors within a region, but they could differ across regions17. Composite intermediate inputs are CES functions of commodities differentiated by industries and regions and by firms under imperfect competition. The firms choose the optimal levels of labour, capital and intermediate inputs to maximize output, which is constrained by the cost of the inputs used. The solution to this problem is derived as a first order condition of maximization from which optimal quantities of each factor and commodities are derived18. 15 See the last term, right hand side of Equation (2) in Appendix 2. See Equations (12) - (14) in Appendix 2. 17 We, however, assume that capital is firm specific in the first period. Therefore, rental rates are not equalized in the first period. 18 See Equations (15) – (21) in Appendix 2. 16 10 Figure 2: Firms Output Cobb-Douglas Function Labour Capital Composite intermediate inputs Same as the composite consumption case in the schematic representation of the household decisions in Figure 1 11 In most applied general equilibrium works it is assumed that markets are perfectly competitive. However, it is often argued that in reality markets are imperfectly competitive and firms exhibit market power in many industries. To overcome this criticism we assume that some of the industrial sectors in the model exhibit an imperfectly competitive market structure. This is modeled such that firms in these industries produce differentiated output and incur fixed costs in the production of their respective goods. The fixed costs are represented as wage and rental payments toward a fixed number of workers and capital that are maintained by the firms irrespective the level of output produced. The two types of strategic behaviour modeled are noncooperative Bertrand and Cournot. In the Bertrand case, the firm chooses the price at which it will sell and lets the market determine the resulting quantity. It is the opposite in the Cournot case. Firms choose the quantity and let the market determine the unit price19. Equilibrium Intra-temporal equilibrium requires that three conditions must hold in each time period20. First, in each region, demand for primary factors equals their supply. Second, total global demand for each sectoral good equals to total supply and third, the sum of global lending and borrowing, which is aggregate household savings, equals zero. Inter-temporal equilibria are further constrained by the requirement that in the steady-state (i) profits of the non-competitive firm are zero due to entry and exit of firms, (ii) investment just covers the depreciation and adjustment cost so that the stock of capital remains constant and finally, (iii) accumulation of foreign asset must be constant implying that the future trade deficits must be covered by interest earnings on foreign assets held21. 19 See Equations (15) – (26) for details about the analytics of the firms’ behaviour in Appendix 2. See Equation (25) in particular for the resulting prices charged by the Bertrand and Cournot firms. 20 See Equations (28) – (33) in the Appendix 2. 21 See Equations (3) and (7) in Appendix 2. 12 Tariff and trade policy simulations in the model The tariff creates a wedge between the prices paid by domestic users of imported commodities and the prices the exporters charge (or receive) gross of transportation cost22. A tariff reduction, therefore, implies a fall in the domestic price of imported goods. This means, everything being equal, there will be a substitution away from domestic to imported goods due to tariff reductions. This results in a fall in demand for domestic goods and hence a downward pressure on the price of domestic goods. This implies that the immediate impact would be a contraction in output in the sectors that are heavily protected. But since domestically produced goods are also sold internationally and other parties simultaneously reduce tariffs on imports of domestic goods elsewhere internationally, the net effect would depend on the relative strengths of these effects and finally on the relative efficiency of producing sectors in partner countries. We abstract from the ‘rules of origin’ issues in this paper. 22 Transportation costs in shipping goods between regions is assumed to take the form of Samuelson’s “iceberg”. While importing from one region to another, each unit of goods shipped loses a fraction (τ < 1) by the time it arrives at its destination. Both the value of this faction and tariff rates are provided exogenously to the model. 13 3. Data, Parameters and Calibration of the Model The principal data source, including the values for the elasticities of substitution between imports and domestic goods, is the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) version 5 Data Base23. This database reflects value added, output, trade flows and tariff rates for 1997. The market power value for Canada, the USA and the European Union (EU) used in the calibration are taken from OECD estimates24. The value of the Herfindahl index used in calibrating the number of firms for Canada and the USA comes from Statistics Canada. Estimates for the values of these parameters are not available for other regions in the model. We, therefore, use the same values of market power for all regions in the model. Some sensitivity tests are performed for these values in order to examine the robustness of the findings25. The GTAP data available for 65 aggregated countries/regions and 54 aggregated industrial sectors are further aggregated into 7 regions and 8 sectors (Appendix 5). Since the focus of the study is studying the impact of the FTAA from the Canadian perspective, the hemispheric region is disaggregated into regions that are particularly important for Canada. These are Canada, the USA, Mexico, Mercosur and the rest of Latin America, Europe and the rest of the world (ROW). In this paper, we refer to Latin America as that which excludes the countries of Mercosur. There are 8 production sectors, namely, (1) agriculture, (2) food processing, (3) resource-intensive industries, (4) textiles, (5) manufacturing, (6) automotive, (7) machinery and electronics and (8) services. Each of these sectors produces a single composite commodity. Value added by labour and capital in each sector, output, exports, imports, intermediate inputs, consumption and investment by countries are derived from the GTAP database for computing a benchmark steady-state equilibrium of the model. 23 Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) Database, maintained at the Purdue University is a multi-country database compiled from national sources of each country and also other international sources of data. 24 Martins and Scarpetta (1999). 25 However, we do not include those in this version due to space constraint. 14 Services, closely followed by manufacturing dominate in all the regions in terms of its share in value added (Table 1). There is a clear delineation between the developed and less developed regions as per the technology sector. Technology, as a share of value added, ranks lower in Latin American countries than in North America and Europe. The contribution of agricultural, food and textile sectors in aggregate value added are relatively higher in the ROW, Mexico, Mercosur and Latin America compared to other regions. Interestingly, the share of the automobile sector in total value added in Mexico is close to that of Canada. What seems to differentiate between Mersosur and Latin America is the resources sector. Resources makes up 7.5% of total value added in Latin America while it only makes up 2% in Mersosur. Table 1 Sectoral Shares (%) in Value Added Industries Agriculture CAN 2.0 USA 1.2 MEX 8.3 MER 9.9 LAT 13.0 EUR 2.2 ROW 6.2 Resources Food Textiles Manufacturing Technology Automotive Services Total 4.4 2.6 1.1 11.9 4.0 2.6 71.4 100.0 0.9 2.2 0.9 8.4 5.4 1.9 79.0 100.0 6.4 5.4 3.4 11.7 5.6 2.7 56.5 100.0 2.0 5.3 4.2 13.5 3.6 1.9 59.7 100.0 7.5 6.7 3.6 12.0 2.0 1.2 58.4 100.0 1.1 3.2 1.3 15.0 5.2 2.1 74.4 100.0 4.7 3.5 2.3 16.0 5.9 1.9 64.9 100.0 Source: Computed from GTAP version 5 data base In Appendix 6 we report on the shares of intermediate inputs and the two primary factors in gross output. The share of intermediates is large in all sectors except agriculture, resources and services. In agriculture, however, there are large differences in the shares of factor uses by region. For example, the share of intermediates in gross output of agriculture was over 60 % in Canada and the U.S.A where it is about 1/3rd for all of Latin America. In Table 2 we report on the regional composition of aggregate exports and imports. The USA and the EU are the top export destinations for all the regions in this model. Seventy-two percent of Canada’s exports are destined for the USA, while 61 % of Canada’s imports are from the USA. The rest of the FTAA members absorb only 2 to 3 % of Canada’s exports. It should 15 be noted, as well, that while 40% of Latin America’s exports go to the USA, only 18% of Mercosur’s exports are destined for the USA. A similar pattern can be observed for imports. Table 2 Regional Shares (%) in Total Exports and Imports CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW TOTAL CAN Exp Imp 72 61 1 2 1 1 1 1 11 17 15 18 100 100 USA Exp Imp 16 16 8 8 3 1 5 4 29 25 40 45 100 100 MEX Exp Imp 3 1 75 66 2 1 5 2 8 15 8 14 100 100 MER Exp Imp 2 2 18 25 2 2 14 6 30 37 35 28 100 100 LAT Exp Imp 3 2 40 33 2 5 6 8 27 24 23 28 100 100 EUR Exp Imp 3 3 24 25 1 1 4 2 3 3 65 66 100 100 ROW Exp Imp 3 3 38 30 1 1 2 2 3 2 53 62 100 100 Source: GTAP Data Base The average, trade-weighted bilateral tariff rates reported in Table 3 do not include equivalents for non-tariff barriers (NTBs). Although documentation on NTB's is available at the UNCTAD, tariff equivalents of these barriers are not readily available. It appears that Canada had the lowest average tariff rate (1.9%) followed by the USA (2.3%) and the EU (4%). Average tariff rates in Latin America are the highest (10%) among all the regions in this model. Table 3 Trade weighted average tariff rates (%) (importing country in first column) CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW CAN 0.8 0.5 5.6 4.1 3.3 4.2 USA 0.4 0.5 5.0 6.3 1.9 3.2 MEX 8.6 1.8 10.0 9.3 6.4 8.4 MER 6.7 10.0 14.5 6.6 9.8 9.0 LAT 11.2 10.9 10.3 11.4 7.8 10.2 EUR 3.1 2.6 3.2 9.4 7.0 4.2 ROW 11.7 7.9 5.1 17.6 7.8 7.8 - Average 1.93 2.34 3.76 9.45 9.99 3.97 8.17 Source: GTAP Data Base It is evident that tariff rates facing Canadian exports in the USA and Mexico, and vise versa, are already low due to the North American Free Trade Agreements (NAFTA). But the tariff rates imposed by other regions are substantially higher. The tariff rates in Mercosur and Latin America are higher than those in Canada and the USA. This suggests that the proposed FTAA would imply a bigger change in the economies of Latin American countries. 16 In Table 4, we report on each region’s average, trade-weighted tariff rates by commodity. Although average bilateral tariff rates across regions are low, in the range of 0.5% to 18% (reported in Table 3), there is wide dispersion among the average tariff rates across commodities. Agriculture and food have the highest tariff rates, ranging from 4% to 42%, followed by textiles and manufacturing. If across the board tariff reductions are pursued, it is expected that these two sectors would be the most affected. Table 4 Average Trade weighted tariff rates by commodities by regions in the Model CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW AGRI 3.8 11.1 17.3 7.9 10.5 10.9 41.8 RESO 0.0 0.3 3.9 3.6 6.6 0.1 2.3 FOOD 28.9 11.1 31.6 17.0 16.9 37.2 37.3 TEXT 10.6 11.2 4.7 18.5 17.7 10.4 14.5 MANU 1.1 2.0 2.5 10.3 9.9 3.5 7.5 TECH 0.6 1.4 2.6 14.0 9.3 3.7 6.1 AUTO 0.7 1.3 2.6 23.1 14.6 5.3 8.8 SERV 2.2 0.2 Source: GTAP Data Base The variance in tariff rates is remarkable if bilateral tariff rates are broken down further (Appendix 7). For example, the USA imposes a tariff of 4.4% on agricultural imports from Canada but a rate of 15% on the imports from the ROW. Similarly, the tariff rate imposed by the ROW on imports of agriculture from Canada is 66%. Mexico imposes a tariff of 34%, on average, against imports of agricultural goods from Canada in contrast to 17% from the USA. Given these discrepancies, it is expected that regions in the model would be affected differently by tariff cuts due to the FTAA. Data on costs of transport of goods between regions are derived from the GTAP database. These are derived as the difference between the cif value of imports at the destination and the fob value of exports at the country of origin. The cost of transportation is passed on to the 17 consumers of the respective goods. These costs lie in the range of 5% to 20% depending upon the commodities and distance between the trading partners26. The basic source for the value of elasticity parameters is the GTAP data base version 5 (see Table 5). These elasticity values lie in between the central tendency values used in Piggot and Whalley (1985) and the extreme values generated by Panagariya et al (2001). According to the literature survey in Piggot and Whalley, central tendency values for these elasticities lie in the neighbourhood of one. Contrary, the elasticity estimates in Panagariya et al. (2001) are as high as 50. The values we use are in the range of 4 and 7. Nevertheless, sensitivity analyses are performed on the elasticity values available from GTAP to verify the robustness of the results. Values for intertemporal elasticities of substitution, rate of time preferences and the world rate of interest used in the model calibration are also reported in Table 5. These numbers are already used in applied general equilibrium modeling work such as Diao et al. (1999). For other parameter values we use the calibration procedure described in Mansur and Whalley (1984), under which the model is first used to solve for parameter values given an initial (or base case) equilibrium represented by the data. Table 5 Central-Case Value of Elasticity of Substitution in Consumption and Some Key Parameter AGRI RESO FOOD TEXT MANU TECH 4.54 5.6 4.71 6.78 4.6 5.6 World rate of interest 12% Rate of time preference 12% Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1.51 Source: GTAP Data Base and authors assumptions. SERV 3.85 26 Studies reveal that after September 11, 2001 the customs procedure has delayed the Canada-USA cross border traffic significantly. A KPMG Survey of Cross-Border Carriers released in August 21, 2002 reveals a 20 % increase in border delays crossing southbound and 12 % northbound since September 11, 2001. The survey results also highlight that border delays pose a significant and real cost to those directly and indirectly linked to transportation in Canada. It is expected that this border delay will adversely affect trade between Canada and USA. Analysis of the cost of border delays is, however, beyond the scope of the present study but is reserved for future study. 18 4. Simulation Results We have used the model and its associated 1997 calibration-based and exogenously specified parameter values to compute a base case, steady-state equilibrium of the model. The transitional dynamics are studied in a discrete time framework for a period of 40 years into 5 time intervals of 0, 4, 9, 17 and 4027. The model is numerically solved both for static and dynamic cases and with perfect and imperfect market structures. While the static version of the model consists of a single period and, therefore, capital endowments of each region are assumed fixed, the dynamic version uses a multi-period set up that takes investment and capital accumulation into account. In light of our experiences with the NAFTA we can assume that although the FTAA calls for complete elimination of tariffs between countries on the American continent, this is not likely to occur in full. NAFTA aimed at complete removal of intra-NAFTA barriers to trade but although reduced substantially over the last ten years, tariffs still persist, particularly on agriculture and food. In order to formulate a more realistic outcome to FTAA, we simulate NAFTA-like tariff reductions. In this scenario, (a) Canada and the USA reduce tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their tariffs on Mexican products if not already the same or lower, (b) Mexico reduces tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their current tariff on imports from the USA if not already the same or lower, (c) the Latin American members of FTAA reduce their tariffs on imports from Canada and the USA to the same level as current Mexican tariffs on imports from Canada and the USA if not already the same or lower, and (d) Intra-NAFTA and other tariffs remain unchanged. From now on, this scenario will be referred to as NAFTA-type tariff reductions within the FTAA. Depending upon the time frame these objectives are achieved two cases are formulated, Case 1 is where all the above are implemented in the first period and Case 2 is where 27 See Mercenier and Michel (1994) for dynamic aggregation methodology. 19 commitment to tariff reductions are phased out over 9 years28. These two simulations are run using both the static and dynamic versions of the model. The dynamic version of the model is solved assuming that all sectors are perfectly competitive, as well as, for cases in which some sectors are imperfectly competitive. The main analyses are, however, based on the results from the dynamic perfectly competitive version of the model. We use the Generalized Algebraic Modeling System (GAMS) optimizing software to solve the model29. Results are reported for both the transitional and the new steady-state equilibria. We also analyse the welfare consequences in terms of the Hicksian equivalent variation (EV) index as used in Devarajan and Go (1998) and, Mercenier and Yeldan (1997)30. Table 6 reports on the welfare effects of the of NAFTA-type tariff reductions within the FTAA for both the cases in the short run (0-9 years), long run (10-40 years) and for the entire period (0-40 years). All the members of NAFTA experience modest gains and other FTAA members lose from FTAA in terms of welfare in both cases - ‘with’ and ‘without’ tariff phasing. The losses are minimized with tariff phasing for both Mercosur and Latin America and for nonmembers, namely Europe and the rest of the World. In the long run, all the regions gain but taking a 40 year time horizon and after appropriate discounting the long run gains are not enough to compensate for the short run losses in welfare for Mercosur and Latin America. There is a overall loss for these regions. However, it may be postulated that, if a longer time horizon is taken, Mercosur and Latin America would gain from the FTAA. Mexico followed by Canada has the highest welfare gain. The welfare gain, interpreted as a percentage increase in the lifetime consumption profile over 40 years for the representative household, in Mexico is 0.1 % as against 0.03 % and 0.02 % for Canada and the USA. Given that Mexico’s exports to Mercosur and Latin America don’t face substantially different tariff rates 28 Appendix 8 displays the resulting cuts in tariff rates across regions as a percentage of the benchmark. This software is originally developed at the World Bank. For a documentation of this software see Brooke et al. (1996). 30 See Equation (34) in Appendix 2 for details. 29 20 than Canada or the USA’s exports, these welfare differences need some explanation. There are two contributing factors to it. First, the NAFTA members’ shares of trade with the Latin American countries vary (Table 2). For example, only 2 % of Canada’s exports are destined for Latin America as against 7 % of Mexican exports. Moreover, there is also variation in terms of the contribution of trade to GDP. For example, the contribution of trade to GDP in Canada and Mexico is larger than that of the USA. Table 6 Welfare Effects of the NAFTA-like tariff Liberalization between NAFTA and Other FTAA members: With and Without Tariff Phasing Short-term (0 – 9 years) Long-term (10-40 years) Overall (0-40 years) CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW No tariff phasing 0.024 0.016 0.089 -0.064 -0.090 -0.005 -0.008 With tariff phasing 0.020 0.015 0.065 -0.076 -0.090 -0.006 -0.008 No tariff phasing 0.047 0.039 0.205 0.089 0.244 0.009 0.006 With tariff phasing 0.005 0.005 0.042 0.228 0.393 0.013 0.014 No tariff phasing 0.028 0.020 0.110 -0.038 -0.032 -0.003 -0.006 With tariff phasing 0.017 0.013 0.061 -0.024 -0.006 -0.002 -0.004 Mercosur and Latin America lose in terms of welfare by 0.04 and 0.03 %, respectively. This can be explained, in most part, by adverse terms of trade effects (Table 7). The average price of exports, for Mercosur and Latin America, falls more sharply than the price of imports due, to a great extent, to relatively higher pre-FTAA tariffs.. Mercosur and Latin American exports increased by 24 and 30 % while their imports increased by only 15 and 19 % respectively (Table 7). Table 7 also reports on the impact of the NAFTA-type tariff cuts among the FTAA members from Case 1 and Case 2 on other aggregate variables. Exports, imports, value added, gross output and consumption increase in all the regions of the model, with the exception of Europe and the ROW. As expected, Mercosur and Latin America experienced the largest increases in both exports and imports. This result is quite obvious as the tariff reductions by these smaller regions of the 21 Table 7 Long run Effect of NAFTA-like Tariff Cuts between NAFTA and Other FTAA Members: Aggregate Output, Value added, Trade, Income, Consumption and Prices* (Dynamic Model) % Change over the Base Case Regions Exports Imports Value added CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 0.98 3.22 5.06 23.62 29.46 -0.24 -0.37 1.31 3.25 5.42 14.67 19.29 -0.10 -0.22 0.34 0.41 1.58 -0.69 3.03 -0.02 -0.04 CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 1.11 3.60 6.00 21.38 28.32 -0.30 -0.46 1.21 2.96 5.04 16.54 19.85 -0.06 -0.18 0.24 0.29 1.36 -0.34 3.09 -0.05 -0.07 Output Consumption Investment Tariff reductions achieved in the first period 0.19 0.14 -0.01 0.10 0.12 0.06 1.27 0.62 0.97 0.89 0.27 1.58 4.78 0.74 5.87 -0.02 0.03 -0.01 -0.04 0.02 -0.03 Gradual tariff reductions** 0.19 0.10 1.31 0.86 4.66 -0.03 -0.04 0.02 0.02 0.12 0.72 1.22 0.04 0.04 -0.02 0.04 1.00 1.55 5.66 -0.01 -0.04 Income Terms of trade Price of cons. Price of invt. 0.33 0.37 1.54 -1.10 1.30 -0.02 -0.04 0.14 0.39 0.49 -1.76 -1.68 -0.01 -0.04 0.26 0.28 0.68 -1.61 -1.50 -0.02 -0.02 0.29 0.30 0.57 -2.11 -2.41 -0.01 -0.02 0.23 0.26 1.31 -0.74 1.36 -0.05 -0.07 0.11 0.33 0.36 -1.39 -1.52 -0.01 -0.03 0.18 0.19 0.48 -1.29 -1.38 -0.04 -0.05 0.20 0.21 0.39 -1.83 -2.33 -0.04 -0.04 Note: * - Canada and USA reduce tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their tariffs on Mexican products if not already the same or lower. Mexico reduces tariffs on imports from Latin American countries to the level of their current tariff on imports from the USA if not already the same or lower. The Latin American members of FTAA reduce their tariffs on imports from Canada and USA to the same level as current Mexican tariffs on imports from Canada and USA if not already the same or lower. Intra-NAFTA tariffs remain unchanged. ** - Phasing out the tariff differences over 9 years; year 1=25% reduction, year 4=25% reduction, year 9=50% reduction. FTAA are substantial, starting from a base rate as high as 37%. The base at which these regions’ level of trade begins is also lower thus implying a higher trade elasticity originating from the CES demand function. (Appendix 7). On the other hand, the level of tariffs in larger regions, such as the USA and Canada, were already low, in the range of 0 and 13%. The expansion of trade experienced by these regions is, therefore, small, in the range of 4 and 5%. The effects of tariff reductions on bilateral trade are reported in Table 8. There is some degree of trade diversion away from existing NAFTA and significant trade creation with rest of the FTAA members. For example, Canada’s exports to the USA fall by 0.14 % and the exports of the USA to Canada fall by 0.11 %. At the same time Canada’s exports to Mercosur and Latin 22 America increased by 30 % and 97 % , respectively31. This is due to the reduction of barriers to trade between NAFTA and rest of FTAA while intra-NAFTA barriers remain unchanged, due to previous free trade agreements between Canada, the USA and Mexico32. Imports of textiles followed by autos, in Canada increases the most, by 5 %. In the USA, imports of agriculture, food and textiles increase the most, in the range of 9 to 16 % (Table 9). For Mercosur and Latin America imports of textiles, manufacturing, technology and autos increased sharply, by as high 95 %. Table 8 Effect of NAFTA-like Tariff Cuts Between NAFTA and Other FTAA Members: On Aggregate Bilateral Trade: Long Term (% change in supply of goods and services by regions over benchmark) CAN USA MEX Export/importing region CAN -0.03 -0.14 3.57 USA 0.41 -0.11 2.42 MEX -0.61 -2.26 0.47 MER 32.31 35.22 114.49 LAT 25.45 54.11 63.06 EUR 1.68 1.44 4.28 ROW 1.50 0.89 3.87 Note: Same region cells represent domestic supply. MER LAT EUR ROW 30.02 57.09 283.35 -0.02 35.20 -11.64 -9.87 96.59 51.57 52.14 69.80 0.95 -10.68 -20.11 -1.43 -1.65 -3.27 8.79 7.06 -0.01 -0.03 -1.46 -1.67 -3.27 8.36 7.66 -0.01 -0.01 Table 9 Effect of NAFTA-like Tariff Cuts Between NAFTA and Other FTAA Members: On Imports by Sector : Long Term (% change over benchmark) CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW AGRI 0.35 10.39 2.95 -5.56 0.95 1.08 -0.21 RESO 1.73 2.71 27.02 0.40 23.26 0.28 1.78 FOOD 0.97 8.95 3.11 -5.42 -2.10 1.57 0.73 TEXT 4.64 16.45 10.56 29.51 92.26 0.21 0.01 MANU 0.94 2.35 6.05 12.82 21.82 0.06 -0.05 TECH 0.50 1.47 2.09 17.64 13.38 -0.51 -0.52 AUTO 2.67 2.20 17.18 94.42 24.83 -0.28 -0.69 SERV 1.16 1.52 4.39 -5.13 0.66 -0.33 -0.32 The impacts on inter-regional trade at a detailed sectoral level are reported in Appendix 9. Imports of agriculture, resources and food from Mercosur and Latin American countries to NAFTA increase at the cost of falling intra-NAFTA trade. Exports of textiles, manufacturing, 31 This is however, from a very low base. Results for exports by nature of use namely, final consumption, intermediate use and investment are also obtained from the model simulation but not reported here. Can be made available on request. 32 23 technology, and autos from NAFTA members to Mercosur and Latin America increased heavily although they started from a low base. Export of automobiles from Mexico to Mercosur increased by several hundred %. These results need to be interpreted carefully. The base level Mexican export of automobiles to Mexico is very low. In CES demand functions, although the base case values of elasticity parameters specified are in the range of 4 to 8, the effective import elasticities are very high due to the their small shares in total demand and the compounding role of cross price elasticities. The overall effect on value added by sector and region is reported in Table 10. As expected, value added in agriculture, resources, food and textiles in Canada contracted partly due to reduction of tariffs on imports from Mercosur and Latin America. The other reason is that the remaining sectors in Canada find increased opportunities in the markets of Mercosur and Latin America due to reduction of tariff barriers. These two effects draw factors of production ,such as labour, from agriculture, resources, food and textiles into manufacturing, technology and autos. This is clearly seen in panel 2, Table 10 under the heading labour demand. Output in manufacturing, technology and autos therefore increases in Canada. Factor allocation and labour and productivity Clear patterns can be observed in terms of changes in factor allocations at the sectoral and regional levels (Table 10). Canada, the USA and Mexico observe movements of labour towards the higher value added sectors, like manufacturing, technology and autos. Mercosur and Latin America experience increases of labour in the agricultural, resource, food and textile sectors. Labour in the textile industry increases by 27% while it falls by 13 % in autos in Latin America. In Mercosur employment in resources increased by more than 3 % while it falls by 4 % in autos. When coupled with changes in value added, productivity improvements become apparent. All regions, except Europe and the ROW, experience productivity increases by the 24 year 40 (Table 11). Trade liberalization in highly protective industries is associated with higher productivity growth. This result makes intuitive sense – withdrawal of barriers to entry in highly protected sectors requires a substantial increase in productivity in order to survive in a more competitive regime. Latin America seems to have experienced the largest productivity improvements in the auto sector, although Latin America is the clear winner in terms of across the board improvements in productivity growth rates. Table 10 Effect of NAFTA-like Tariff Cuts Between NAFTA and Other FTAA Members: Value added, Labour Demand and Labour Productivity (% change over benchmark) Value added Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World Labour demand Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World Labour productivity Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World AGRI RESO FOOD TEXT MANU TECH AUTO SERV -0.83 -1.19 -0.61 2.13 5.22 -0.14 -0.04 -0.52 -0.83 -0.74 4.34 7.88 -0.13 -0.07 -0.32 -0.47 0.21 1.40 4.46 -0.05 -0.04 -3.14 0.25 -2.86 2.63 34.32 -0.44 -0.94 0.14 0.40 1.42 1.12 4.08 -0.05 0.01 0.71 0.82 0.26 -1.52 1.40 -0.09 0.18 4.44 1.34 19.47 -2.80 -8.24 -0.27 -0.69 -0.06 -0.01 0.54 0.69 2.16 0.03 0.02 -0.91 -1.32 -1.18 1.26 1.84 -0.14 -0.03 -0.60 -0.93 -1.58 3.45 3.24 -0.11 -0.05 -0.41 -0.64 -0.63 0.60 0.43 -0.05 -0.03 -3.47 -0.26 -3.68 1.68 27.00 -0.44 -0.92 0.03 0.26 0.39 0.20 -0.49 -0.04 0.02 0.61 0.71 -0.72 -2.70 -3.30 -0.07 0.21 4.32 1.19 18.10 -4.46 -13.25 -0.26 -0.67 -0.12 -0.08 -0.18 0.00 -1.21 0.04 0.04 0.08 0.14 0.58 0.86 3.32 0.00 -0.02 0.08 0.10 0.85 0.87 4.50 -0.02 -0.02 0.09 0.17 0.85 0.80 4.01 0.00 -0.02 0.34 0.51 0.85 0.93 5.76 0.00 -0.01 0.11 0.14 1.02 0.92 4.60 -0.01 -0.02 0.10 0.11 0.99 1.21 4.85 -0.02 -0.03 0.12 0.14 1.16 1.73 5.77 -0.01 -0.02 0.06 0.07 0.72 0.69 3.41 -0.01 -0.02 25 Capital Flows Table 11 reports on the stock of foreign assets on the net over time by regions under the FTAA. Period 1 reflects the position in the benchmark. The sum of borrowing across regions in each period is zero. A negative sign implies the region has a net claim on foreign assets, i.e., lending exceeds borrowing. In the base case, in period 1, Canada had a net claim of US$124 billion worth of foreign assets or current account surplus. Contrarily, Mercosur and Latin America both had current account deficits. Changes in current account balances can be interpreted as capital inflows or outflows. For example, Canada’s current account surplus fell to US$123 billion in period 2 and then to US$122 billion in period 5 (i.e. by theyear 40). This implies a net inflow of capital in Canada compared to benchmark. The USA also experiences a net inflow of capital by the last year. Mexico, Mercosur and Latin America all witness a net outflow of capital. In general, the countries that have the largest drops in tariffs also saw their balance of payments change most drastically. In particular, Latin America experiences a fall in debt from US$160 billion to US$119 billion. This implies capital outflow compared to the benchmark. When coupled with the value of Latin American exports to the value of imports, the capital outflow is apparent. As the total value of exports vis-à-vis the total value of imports increases over time, the claim of Latin America on the other regions increases, implying more and more capital outflow. It is possible that high trade barriers in the pre-FTAA could have augmented the returns to capital. When these barriers come down, so does the return to capital resulting in capital outflows (Table 12). Investment and Capital accumulation As expected, investment in each period, for all of the FTAA members, is higher than the benchmark, whereas it is slightly lower than the benchmark for the non-FTAA regions (Table 12). The growth rate of investment, however, falls overtime until it reaches a steady-state 26 equilibrium. Latin America sees its investment increase the most, by about 12% in the first period and then stabilizes at about 6% higher than the benchmark level. The increase in investment is due to increased efficiency gains due to the removal of tariff distortions and increased market opportunities. Imperfect competition So far our analyses have been based on the assumption that all markets are perfectly competitive. Simulations are also performed for cases in which firms in some sectors, namely manufacturing, possess market power33. The results indicate that effects are as much as 20% to 30% higher (Table 13). These results make intuitive sense. Tariff reductions in non-competitive market conditions enhance competition, reduce market power of the monopolistic firms and force them to improve efficiency. Table 11 Stock of Foreign Assets CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 33 Period 1 -124.4 1495.6 -104.4 236.5 160.0 -982.0 -681.3 Period 2 -123.0 1507.2 -107.3 230.2 133.1 -972.2 -668.0 Period 3 -122.5 1512.3 -109.7 227.3 122.5 -967.8 -662.2 Period 4 -122.3 1514.5 -111.4 226.2 118.9 -966.1 -659.8 Period 5 -122.3 1514.8 -111.7 226.1 118.5 -965.9 -659.5 Here we report results from the Bertrand case only. The work on Cournot is in progress. 27 Table 12 Investment, Capital Accumulation and, Wage and Rental Rates Due to NAFTA type Tariff reductions between NAFTA and other FTAA members1 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Period 5 0.999 1.000 1.021 1.025 1.120 0.999 0.999 1.000 1.001 1.017 1.019 1.076 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.001 1.013 1.016 1.061 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.001 1.010 1.016 1.058 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.001 1.010 1.016 1.059 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 0.999 1.000 1.004 1.009 1.038 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.007 1.014 1.053 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.001 1.009 1.016 1.058 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.001 1.010 1.016 1.059 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.005 1.013 0.990 1.012 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.014 0.991 1.021 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.015 0.991 1.024 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.015 0.992 1.025 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.015 0.992 1.026 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.013 0.992 1.013 1.000 1.000 1.004 1.004 1.010 0.984 0.989 1.000 1.000 1.003 1.003 1.008 0.981 0.980 1.000 1.000 1.003 1.003 1.006 0.979 0.977 1.000 1.000 1.003 1.003 1.006 0.979 0.976 1.000 1.000 Investment Canada United States Mexico MERCOSUR Latin America Europe Rest of the World Capital Stock Canada United States Mexico MERCOSUR Latin America Europe Rest of the World Wage Rate Canada United States Mexico MERCOSUR Latin America Europe Rest of the World Rental Rate Canada United States Mexico MERCOSUR Latin America Europe Rest of the World Note: 1 - Base case level values are normalized to 1. 28 Table 13 Sensitivity of Model Results with respect to Static/Dynamic and competitive/noncompetitive Market Structures due to NAFTA-like Tariff reductions between NAFTA and other FTAA Members on Some Key Variables % Change over the Base Case Regions Exports Imports Value added CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 1.00 3.14 3.85 21.52 22.82 -0.20 -0.29 1.21 2.88 5.09 14.49 18.68 -0.28 -0.38 0.38 0.42 1.17 -1.11 0.68 0.01 0.00 CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 0.98 3.22 5.06 23.62 29.46 -0.24 -0.37 1.31 3.25 5.42 14.67 19.29 -0.10 -0.22 0.34 0.41 1.58 -0.69 3.03 -0.02 -0.04 CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 1.60 3.27 5.97 25.84 32.52 -0.13 -0.47 1.34 0.29 3.77 0.41 5.50 1.58 16.58 -0.56 22.04 4.12 -0.29 -0.05 -0.27 -0.06 Output Consumption Investment Income Terms of Price of trade cons. Perfect competition – Static 0.19 0.08 0.00 0.37 0.08 0.06 0.00 0.39 0.55 0.35 0.00 1.13 0.10 -0.09 0.00 -1.51 1.34 0.05 0.00 -0.98 -0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.02 -0.02 0.00 0.00 Perfect competition - Dynamic 0.19 0.14 -0.01 0.33 0.10 0.12 0.06 0.37 1.27 0.62 0.97 1.54 0.89 0.27 1.58 -1.10 4.78 0.74 5.87 1.30 -0.02 0.03 -0.01 -0.02 -0.04 0.02 -0.03 -0.04 Imperfect competition (Bertrand) - Dynamic 0.25 0.18 -0.16 0.19 0.07 0.16 0.07 0.40 1.39 0.65 0.96 1.50 0.94 0.33 1.70 -0.96 5.50 0.58 8.21 3.11 -0.01 0.04 -0.06 -0.09 -0.05 0.04 -0.05 -0.07 Price of Welfare invt. 0.12 0.31 0.66 -1.51 -0.69 -0.06 -0.08 0.31 0.33 0.92 -1.28 -0.74 0.02 0.01 0.33 0.34 0.78 -1.86 -1.82 0.02 0.02 0.028 0.019 0.119 -0.030 0.017 -0.003 -0.006 0.14 0.39 0.49 -1.76 -1.68 -0.01 -0.04 0.26 0.28 0.68 -1.61 -1.50 -0.02 -0.02 0.29 0.30 0.57 -2.11 -2.41 -0.01 -0.02 0.028 0.020 0.109 -0.038 -0.032 -0.003 -0.006 0.10 0.43 0.42 -1.77 -1.46 -0.05 -0.05 0.21 0.30 0.61 -1.60 -1.37 -0.05 -0.04 0.24 0.025 0.31 0.027 0.51 0.116 -2.11 -0.017 -2.30 0.017 -0.04 -0.006 -0.03 -0.006 Sensitivity analyses The sensitivity of impacts on key variables and welfare from trade liberalization to the values of elasticities are reported in Table 1434. As expected, the higher the elasticity of substitution, the higher is the level of welfare from tariff liberalization as higher elasticity implies greater degree of transmission of price changes35. 34 35 Results at further disaggregated levels are not reported but can be made available on request. See McDaniel, Balistreri (2002) for a discussion on Welfare and Armington trade substitution elasticities. 29 In Table 14, the upper panel reports results from trade liberalization across FTAA regions in the central case specification of the model. The middle panel displays results when the elasticity of substitution for the rich regions (Canada, the USA and Europe) increased by 1/3rd. The third panel results are from cuts in values of the elasticity parameters by 1/3rd. The results are intuitive. One interesting point is that welfare changes in Latin America become positive when the values of elasticity of substitution are increased by 1/3rd for all regions. But it does not do so for Mercosur. Both Latin America and Mercosur benefit from expanding trade with the rest of FTAA members. But they benefit disproportionately as their share of trade with the FTAA members vary quite significantly. While more than 50 % of exports and 48 % of imports of Latin American are from the FTTA, only 36 % of Mercosur’s export is destined for the FTAA and 35 % of imports are from the FTAA. Since tariff rates other than FTAA member regions remain unchanged a bulk of Mercosur trade does not get the benefits of tariff reductions. 30 Table 14 Sensitivity of Model Results of NAFTA-like Tariff reductions between NAFTA and other FTAA Members with respect to Elasticity of Substitution in Preferences on Some Key Variables % Change over the Base Case Regions Exports Imports Value added Output Consumption Investment Income Terms of Price of trade cons. Price of Welfare invt. Perfect competition – Dynamic – central case results CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 0.98 3.22 5.06 23.62 29.46 -0.24 -0.37 1.31 3.25 5.42 14.67 19.29 -0.10 -0.22 0.34 0.19 0.14 -0.01 0.33 0.14 0.41 0.10 0.12 0.06 0.37 0.39 1.58 1.27 0.62 0.97 1.54 0.49 -0.69 0.89 0.27 1.58 -1.10 -1.76 3.03 4.78 0.74 5.87 1.30 -1.68 -0.02 -0.02 0.03 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.04 -0.04 0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.04 Perfect competition – Dynamic – Elasticity values increased by 33 % 0.26 0.28 0.68 -1.61 -1.50 -0.02 -0.02 0.29 0.30 0.57 -2.11 -2.41 -0.01 -0.02 0.028 0.020 0.109 -0.038 -0.032 -0.003 -0.006 CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 1.50 4.59 8.82 36.37 42.36 -0.37 -0.58 1.94 4.54 9.33 22.93 28.65 -0.16 -0.36 0.34 0.26 0.17 -0.04 0.33 0.15 0.41 0.10 0.14 0.04 0.37 0.41 2.15 1.94 0.82 1.37 2.13 0.70 -0.64 1.00 0.33 1.99 -1.10 -2.04 4.37 6.00 0.92 7.28 2.48 -1.49 -0.03 -0.03 0.04 -0.01 -0.03 -0.02 -0.06 -0.05 0.03 -0.04 -0.06 -0.05 Perfect competition – Dynamic – Elasticity values reduced by 33 % 0.27 0.28 0.90 -1.80 -1.26 -0.03 -0.04 0.30 0.31 0.74 -2.37 -2.34 -0.02 -0.03 0.032 0.021 0.157 -0.034 0.041 -0.004 -0.007 CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW 0.58 2.02 2.71 14.12 18.83 -0.13 -0.19 0.82 2.12 3.00 8.47 11.72 -0.03 -0.10 0.25 0.27 0.52 -1.51 -1.83 -0.01 -0.01 0.27 0.28 0.45 -1.95 -2.58 0.00 0.00 0.025 0.018 0.077 -0.040 -0.101 -0.002 -0.004 0.33 0.39 1.18 -0.78 1.64 -0.02 -0.03 0.13 0.10 0.83 0.78 3.65 -0.01 -0.02 0.12 0.10 0.49 0.22 0.56 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.08 0.69 1.25 4.51 -0.01 -0.02 0.32 0.36 1.13 -1.14 0.06 -0.01 -0.02 0.13 0.37 0.35 -1.60 -1.96 0.00 -0.02 31 5. Conclusion In this paper we evaluate the effects of a Free Trade Area of the Americas (FTAA) on Canada and other major players using a dynamic general equilibrium multi-sector, multi-region model of global trade in both under a competitive and non-competitive market environments. We analyze the welfare effects of NAFTA-type FTAA arrangements in which the rest of FTAA members enjoy the same tariffs as currently exist in intra-NAFTA trade. We also analyze the effects on output, trade and investment by sector and region of the model. We find that the magnitudes of the effects of the FTAA differ under various market structures. The effects are larger under the imperfect market environments. Our results suggest that there are modest gains from the existing NAFTA members while the rest of FTAA members tend to lose. Mexico followed, by Canada, is the biggest gainer. Mercosur and Latin America lose due to adverse terms of trade effect. The loss for Mercosur and Latin America are lower if differences in tariff rates between that which exist within NAFTA and the rest of FTAA are phased out rather than eliminated instantly. We also find that trade between NAFTA and rest of FTAA in agriculture, resources, food and textiles increases at the cost of reduced intra-NAFTA trade. In general exports of manufacturing, technology and autos from NAFTA to the rest of FTAA increase and imports of agriculture, resources, food and textiles from the rest of the FTAA into NAFTA increase due to NAFTA-type FTAA arrangements. This suggests that, while existing NAFTA members move towards production of high value added products, the rest of FTAA members produce more of the low value added products. 32 6. References Abel, Andrew B. (1980), “Empirical Investment Equations: An Integrative Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Supplement Spring Vol. 12 (6), pp. 39-91. Alam, A. and S. Rajapatirane (1993), “Trade Policy Reforms in Latin America and the Caribbean During the 1980s,” Working Paper No. 1104, World Bank, Washington D.C. Armington, P.S. (1969), “A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production”, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Vol. 16, pp 159-76. Brooke, A., Kendrick, D., and Meeraus, A. (1996), GAMS: A User Guide, Scientific Press. Brown, Drusilla and Robert M. Stern (1989), “U.S.- Canada Bilateral Tariff Elimination: The Role of Product Differentiation and Market Structure”, in Robert C. Feenstra (ed.) Trade Policies for International Competitiveness, The University of Chicago Press. Devarajan, S. and David Go (1998), “The Simplest Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of an Open Economy”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 20(6), pp 677-714. Diao, Xinshen and Agapi Somwaru (2001), “ A Dynamic Evaluation of the Effects of A Free Trade Area of the Americas: An Intertemporal, Global General Equilibrium Model, Journal of Economic Integration, March, 16(1), pp 21-47. Diao, Xinshen, Terry Roe, and Erinc Yeldan (1999), ''Strategic Policies and Growth: and Applied Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth,'' Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 60, pp 343-380. Etier, Wilfred J. (1982), “National and International Return to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade,” American Economic Review, Vol. 72(3), pp 389-405. Ghosh, Madanmohan (2002), “ The Revival of Regional Trade Arrangements: A GE Evaluation of the Impact on Small Countries”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 24, pp 83-101. Ghosh, Madanmohan (2002A), “R&D Policies and Economic Growth: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Endogenous Growth Model for Canada”, paper presented at the Canadian Economic Association Meetings, May 30-June 2, 2002, Calgary, Canada. GTAP (2001), Global Trade, Assistance, and Production: The GTAP 5 Data Package, Centre for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Hayashi, Fumio (1982), “Tobin's Marginal q and Average q: A Neoclassical Interpretation” Econometrica, Vol. 50 (1), pp. 213-24 Lavoie Claude, Marcel Mérette and Mokhtar Souissi. (2001), A Multi-sector Multi-country Dynamic General Equilibrium Model with Imperfect Competition, Department of Finance Working Paper No. 2001-10. 33 Little, I.M.D., R. Cooper, W. Corden, and S. Pajapatirana (1993), Boom, Crisis, and Adjustment: The Macroeconomic Experience of Developing Countries, World Bank, Oxford University Press, UK. Mansur A.H. and J. Whalley (1984) “Numerical Specification of Applied General Equilibrium Models: Estimation, Calibration and Data” in H.E. Scarf and J.B. Shoven (eds.) Applied General Equilibrium Analysis, Cambridge University Press. Martins, J.O. and Stefano Scarpettea (1999), “The Levels and Cyclical Behaviour of Mark-Ups Across Countries and Market Structures”, Economics Department Working Paper No. 312, OECD, Paris. McDaniel, C.A. and E.J. Balistreri (2002), “A Discussion on Armington Trade Substitution Elasticities”, USITC, No. 2002-01-A, Washington D.C. Mercenier, J and P. Michel (1994), “Discrete Time Finite Horizon Approximation of Infinite Horizon Optimization Problems With Steady-State Invariance”, Econometrica, Vol. 62(3), pp 635-656. Mercenier, J. (1995a), “Can ‘1992’ Reduce Unemployment in Europe? On Welfare and Employment Effects of Europe’s Move to a Single Market”, Journal of Policy Modeling,Vol. 17(1), pp 1-37. Mercenier, J. (1995b), “Nonuniqueness of Solutions in Applied General Equilibrium Models with Scale Economies and Imperfect Competition”, Economic Theory.Vol. 6, pp 161-177. Mercenier, J. and E. Yeldan (1997), “On Turkey’s Trade Policy: Is a Customs Union with Europe Enough?”, European Economic Review,Vol. 41, pp 871-880. Page, Sheila (2000), Regionalism among Developing Countries, New York: St. Martin's Press, London: Macmillan Press, in association with Overseas Development Institute. Panagariya, Arvind, Krishna, Pravin (2002), “On Necessarily Welfare-Enhancing Free Trade Areas”, Journal of International Economics, August 2002, v. 57, iss. 2, pp. 353-67. Panagariya,Arvind, Shah, Shekhar, Mishra, Deepak (2001), “Demand Elasticities in International Trade: Are They Really Low?” Journal of Development Economics, April 2001, v. 64, iss. 2, pp. 313-42. Piggot John and John Whalley (1985), U.K. Tax and Applied General Equilibrium Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schott, Jeffrey J. (2001), Prospects for Free Trade in the Americas, Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (1998), “Regional Trade Agreements and U.S. Agriculture Economic Report 771. Washington D.C. 34 Whalley, John (1998), “Why Do Countries Seek Regional Trade Agreements?” pp. 63-83, in The Regionalization of the World Economy, NBER Project Report series, Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press. 35 Appendix 1: GDP and Trade of the FTAA Member Countries’ Trade with Canada (1997) Population Per Capita Exports Imports (Million) GNPa Total % Total % $USA $USA Total $USA Total (000’s) Export (000’s) Import a 6.8 0.003 0.9 0.000 Antigua and Barbuda 0.067 36 8570 295.5 0.137 168.2 0.085 Argentina 15.6 0.007 5.8 0.003 Bahamas 26.9 0.012 10.0 0.005 Barbados 7.1 0.003 9.2 0.005 Belize 8 950 22.8 0.011 11.3 0.006 Bolivia 164 4720 1222.8 0.568 953.5 0.484 Brazil 30 19290 Canada 15 5020 283.5 0.132 235.4 0.119 Chile 38 2280 341.6 0.159 226.5 0.115 Colombia 4 2640 53.6 0.025 133.8 0.068 Costa Rica 1.3 0.001 1.0 0.001 Dominica 8 1670 60.6 0.028 80.9 0.041 Dominicans Republic 12 1590 62.6 0.029 102.1 0.052 Ecuador 6 1810 15.6 0.007 32.2 0.016 El Salvador 2.4 0.001 0.8 0.000 Grenada 11 1500 59.6 0.028 96.4 0.049 Guatemala 7.7 0.004 146.9 0.075 Guyana 7 330 19.6 0.009 3.1 0.002 Haiti 6 700 12.0 0.006 39.3 0.020 Honduras 3 1560 63.5 0.030 186.1 0.094 Jamaica 95 3680 922.6 0.429 5071.7 2.573 Mexico 5 410 7.9 0.004 7.1 0.004 Nicaragua 3 3080 30.1 0.014 33.0 0.017 Panama 5 2010 8.0 0.004 2.4 0.001 Paraguay 25 2460 225.2 0.105 97.2 0.049 Peru 1.5 0.001 3.2 0.002 St Kitts & Nevis St. Lucia 2.9 0.001 0.1 0.000 St Vincent & the Grenadines 4.7 0.002 18.2 0.009 Suriname 1 4230 74.1 0.034 19.1 0.010 Trinidad and Tobago 268 28740 176160.5 81.822 133201.9 67.564 United States 3 6020 17.3 0.008 48.0 0.024 Uruguay 23 3450 688.8 0.320 702.3 0.356 Venezuela 180724.6 83.942 141647.7 71.848 Sub-Total 34572.8 16.058 55501.4 28.152 Others 215297.4 100.000 197149.1 100.000 Total Source: Column 1 and 2 World Development Report, 1998/99. a Preliminary estimates. Trade data obtained from Statistics Canada and the USA. Census Bureau (U.S. Department of Commerce). a in 2001(est.). 36 Appendix 2: List of Equations in the Model Note: Unless otherwise stated subscripts, i and j stand for regions, s and sd represent industrial sectors and t symbolizes time dimensions of the model. Full abbreviations of the acronyms are provided in Appendices 3 and 4. Households TCi1,−t θ i ∞ ∫ Maximize U i = e −ψ i .t 1 − θi 0 (θ i > 0, ψ i > 0), dt (1) subject to Accumulation of foreign asset/debt – Balance of payment constraint DEBTi ,t +1 − DEBTi ,t = r. DEBTi ,t + INCi ,t − TCi ,t . P _ TCi ,t − TI i ,t . P _ TI i ,t ( 2 − TI i ,t . P _ TI i ,t . ADJ i . TI _ Ri ,t − δ i 2 (2) ) Steady-state condition r. DEBTi ,T + INCi ,T − TCi ,T . P _ TCi ,T − TI i ,T . P _ TCi ,T = 0 T = terminal year ) (3) Equation of motion for aggregate capital stock δi = TI − TK . i t i t , , 2 2 r .(1 + 2. ADJ i . δ i ) + δ i r .(1 + 2. ADJ i . δ i ) + δ i TKi ,t +1 − TKi ,t (4) Arbitrage condition (1 + r ). P _ TI i ,t −1 . 1 + 3. ADJ i . TI _ Ri ,t −1 { 2 2 − ADJ i . δ i = } RENT . r.(1 + 2. ADJ . δ 2 ) + δ + 2. ADJ . P _ TI . TI _ R . TI _ R 2 i ,t i i i i i ,t i ,t i ,t (5) 2 2 + (1 − δ i ). P _ TI i ,t . 1 + 3. ADJ i . TI _ Ri ,t − ADJ i . δ i where TI _ Ri ,t (rate of investment) TI _ Ri ,t = ( 2 TI i ,t r.(1 + 2. ADJ i . δ i ) + δ i TKi ,t ) (6) Steady-state condition 37 TI i ,T = δi . TKi ,T r.(1 + 2. ADJ i . δ 2 ) + δ i ( T = terminal year ) (7) Consumption The time path of aggregate consumption is given by 1 TCi ,t −1 TCi ,t P _ TCi ,t (1 + ψ i ) θi = P _ TCi ,t −1 (1 + r ) (8) Price of aggregate consumption ( ) ∑ρ log P _ TCi ,t = i ,s s ( .log P _ FCi ,s ,t ) (9) Consumption demand for goods from each firm Ci , j ,s ,t P _ FC j ,s ,t = β _ FCi , j ,s . Pi , j ,s ,t . 1 + TARi , j ,s ,t ( ) σ j ,s ρ j ,s . TC j ,t . P _ TC j ,t P _ FC j ,s ,t (10) Price of composite final consumption ( P_ FC )( 1− σ j , s ) j , s ,t = ∑ NF i , s ,t [ ( . β _ FCi , j ,s . Pi , j ,s,t . 1 + TARi , j ,s,t i )] (1−σ ) j ,s (11) Investment Price of aggregate investment ( ) ∑γ log P _ TI i ,t = s i ,s ( .log P _ FI i ,s ,t ) (12) Price of investment goods by sectors ( P _ FI j ,s ,t ) (1− σ ) j ,s = ∑ i [ ( NFi ,s ,t . β _ FI i , j ,s . Pi , j ,s ,t . 1 + TARi , j ,s,t )] (1−σ ) j ,s (13) Investment demand for goods from each firm I i , j , s ,t P _ FI j ,s ,t = β _ FI i , j ,s . Pi , j ,s ,t . 1 + TARi , j ,s ,t ( ) σ j ,s γ j ,s . TI j ,t . P _ TI j ,t P _ FI j ,s,t (14) 38 Firms Variable unit cost function VUC j ,sd ,t = 1 A j ,sd (W j ,t α L , j , sd . R j ,sd ,t α K , j , sd . Π P _ I j ,s,sd ,t α j , s , sd sd ), (15) where, ( A j , sd = α L ,sd Pi , j ,sc ,t = α L ,sd .α K ,sd VUCi ,sc ,t Gi , j ,sc α K ,sd . Π α j ,s,sd α j ,s ,sd sd ) are constants (16) ∀ sc = competitive sector (17) Demand for labour by sector α .VUCi ,s,t . Zi ,s,t LDEMi ,s,t = NFi ,s,t . L ,i ,s + LMIN i ,s Wi ,t (18) Demand for capital by sector α .VUCi ,s,t . Zi ,s,t KDEM i ,s,t = NFi , s,t . K ,i ,s + KMIN i ,s Ri ,s,t (19) Price of composite intermediates from sector s used in sector sd [ P_ INT j , s , sd ,t ]( 1− σ j , s ) = ∑ NF i , s ,t [ ( . β _ INTi , j ,s ,sd . Pi , j ,s ,t 1 + TARi , j ,s ,t i )] (1−σ ) j ,s (20) Intermediate demand for goods from each firm INTi , j ,s ,sd ,t P _ INTj ,s ,sd ,t = β _ INTi , j ,s ,sd . Pi , j ,s ,t . 1 + TARi , j ,s ,t ( ) σ j ,s α j ,s,sd .VUC j ,sd ,t . Z j ,sd ,t P _ INTj ,s ,sd ,t (21) 39 Imperfect Competition The growth in the number of firms (under imperfect competition) NFi ,nf ,t 0 NFi ,sn ,t − t >1 t0 = H ∑ NFi ,sn ,t +1 − NFi ,sn ,t ∑ where H = ∑T t − 1 , (time horizon) (22) t Bertrand direct price elasticity of demand36 ( ) ( ) σ j ,sn − 1 . Pk , j ,sn ,t . 1 + TARk , j , sn ,t . Ck , j ,sn ,t . Ci , j ,sn ,t ELBS k ,i , j , sn ,t = E i , j ,sn ,t . ρ j ,sn . TC j ,t . P _ TC j ,t ( ( ) ) σ j ,sn − 1 . Pk , j ,sn ,t . 1 + TARk , j ,sn ,t . I k , j , sn ,t . I i , j ,sn ,t + E i , j ,sn ,t . γ j ,sn . TI j ,t . P _ TI j ,t + ∑ ss ( ( ) (23) ) σ j ,sn − 1 . Pk , j ,sn ,t . 1 + TARk , j ,sn ,t . NF j , ss,t . INTk , j ,sn , ss,t . INTi , j ,sn , ss,t E i , j ,sn ,t . α j ,sn ,ss .VUC j ,ss,t . Z j ,ss,t Cournot direct quantity elasticity of demand37 ∑ ( NF k , sn ,t − 1). ELBS k ,l , j , sn ,t . ELCSi ,k , j ,sn ,t − σ j ,sn . ELCSi ,l , j , sn ,t k (24) 1 =0 + ELBS i ,l , j ,sn ,t . ELCSi ,i , j ,sn ,t − σ j ,sn Price charged by firm i at market j Pi , j ,sn ,t − VUCi ,sn ,t Gi , j ,sn Pi , j ,sn ,t = 1 ELBS i,i, j,sn,t − σ j ,sn = − ELCS i ,i , j , sn ,t − 1 = Bertrand case (25) = Cournot case σ j , sn 36 from country i, for good sn produced by firm j in country k a weighted sum of elasticities of demand for final consumption, intermediates and investment. 37 from country i, for good sn produced by firm j in country k a weighted sum of elasticities of demand for final consumption, intermediates and investment. 40 Profit equation ∑P π i ,sn ,t = i , j , sn ,t j [ . E i , j ,sn ,t − VUCi ,sn ,t . Zi ,sn ,t − Ri ,sn ,t . KMIN i ,sn + Wi ,t . LMIN i ,sn ] (26) Closure Total income by region ∑α INCi ,t = w ,i , s .VUCi , s ,t . NFi , s ,t . Z i , s ,t + Wi ,t . s + ∑ NF i , sn ,t . ∑ NF i ,nf ,t . LMIN i , sn sn + ∑R i , s ,t . KDEM i , s ,t sn (27) π i ,sn ,t + REVi ,t sn Equilibrium conditions REVi ,t = ∑ NF j , s ,t . E j ,i , s ,t . TAR j ,i , s ,t . Pj ,i , s ,t (28) s, j Capital market clearing condition TKi ,t = ∑ KDEM (29) i , s ,t s L i ,t = ∑ LDEM (30) i , s ,t s Total demand for each firm’s product E i , j ,s,t = Ci , j ,s,t + I i , j , s,t + ∑ INT i , j , s , sd ,t (31) sd Goods market clearing condition Zi ,s ,t = Ei , j , s ,t ∑G j (32) i , j ,s Rental rates are equalized across sectors in the Steady-state RENTi ,t = Ri , s,t (33) 41 Welfare index ( φ ) 40 ∑ (1 + ψ ) t =1 [TC$ .(1 + φ )] 1− θ −t t 1− θ TCt 1−θ = ∑ (1 + ψ ) 1− θ t =1 40 −t (34) Where TC$t and TCt are, respectively, the benchmark and new, post-shock composite consumption streams. The welfare gains resulting from the policy change are equivalent to the change in the reference consumption profile by φ %. 42 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12 13 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. Appendix 3: List of Variables of the Model Variable Name Variable unit cost of good s produced in region i at time t Price of composite intermediate good s used in ss in region i at t Net of tariff price in region j of good s produced in i, at t Profit in sector s, in region i at time t Number of firms in sector s in region i at t Income in region i at time t Price of aggregate consumption in region i at t Aggregate consumption in region i at t Price of aggregate investment in region i at t Aggregate investment in region i at t Rate of investment in region i at t Price of consumption of composite good s, in region i at t DD for good s produced by each firm in region i, by region j for final cons at t Price of composite investment good s, in region i at t Demand for good s produced by each firm in region i, by region j for invest at t Price of composite intermediate good s, for use by sd in region i at t Demand for good s, produced in i, for use by ss in region j at t Total demand for each firm s product in region i from j at t Gross output in sector s, in region i at t Wage rate in region i at t Rental price of capital in region i at t Supply of capital Demand for capital Net borrowing by region i at t Bertrand elasticity Cournot elasticity Notation VUCi ,s ,t P _ INTi ,s,ss ,t Pi , j ,s,t π i , s ,t NFi ,s ,t INCi ,t P _ TCi ,t TCi ,t P _ TI i ,t TI i ,t TI _ Ri ,t P _ FCi ,s,t Ci , j , s,t P _ FI i ,s,t I i , j , s ,t P _ INI i ,s,sd ,t INTi , j ,s,ss,t E i , j , s ,t Z i , s ,t Wi ,t RENTi ,t TKi ,t KiD,s ,t DEBTi ,t ELBS k ,i , j ,s ,t ELCS k ,i , j ,s ,t 43 Appendix 4: List of Parameters of the Model 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. 10. 11. 12 13 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. Variable Name World rate of interest Rate of time preference in region i Inverse of intertemporal elasticity of substitution in region i Rate of depreciation in region i Transportation cost between pairs of regions by sectors Adjustment cost in investment in region i Share of composite good s in total consumption in region i Share of region j’s good in composite consumption good s in region i Share of composite good s in total investment in region i Share of region j’s good in composite investment good s in region i Share of composite good s in total invest in region j used in sector sd Share of region j’s good in composite invest good s in i used in sector sd Share of labor in variable unit cost in sector s, region i Share of capital in VUC of S Share of intermediates in VUC of S Scale of VUC of S Different elasticity of substitution in final demands Endowment of labour by region Notation r ψi θi δi Gi , j ,s ADJ i ρ i ,s β _ FCi , j ,s γ i ,s β _ FI i , j ,s α j ,s,sd β _ INTi , j ,s,sd α L ,i ,s α K ,i ,s α j ,s,sd A j ,sd σ j ,s Li 44 Appendix 5: Mapping Scheme Followed in Aggregating Data and Parameters of the Model A. Regions of the Model Regions/countries in GTAP database Canada Canada USA The United States of America Mexico Mexico Latin America Central America and Caribbean, Colombia, Peru, Venezuela, rest of Andean Pact, Chile, rest of South America Mercosur Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay Europe Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, United Kingdom, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, rest of EFTA Rest of the World Australia, New Zealand, China, Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, Republic of Taiwan, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Viet Nam, Bangladesh, India, Sri Lanka, rest of South Asia, Hungary, Poland, rest of Central European Associates, former Soviet Union, Turkey, rest of Middle East, Morocco, rest of North Africa, Botswana, rest of SACU, Malawi, Mozambique, Tanzania, United Republic of Zambia, Zimbabwe, rest of southern Africa, Uganda, rest of sub-Saharan Africa, rest of world B. Sectors of the Model Sectors in GTAP database Agriculture Paddy rice, wheat, cereal grains nec., vegetables, fruit, nuts, oil seeds, sugar cane, sugar beet, plant-based fibers, crops nec., bovine cattle, sheep and goats, horses, animal products nec., raw milk, wool, silk-worm cocoons Resource based industries Forestry, fishing, coal, oil, gas, minerals nec. Food Bovine cattle, sheep and goat meat products, meat products, vegetable oils and fats, dairy products, processed rice, sugar, food products nec., beverages and tobacco products Textiles Textiles, wearing apparel, leather products Manufacturing Wood products, paper products, publishing, petroleum, coal products, chemical, rubber, plastic products, mineral products nec., ferrous metals, metals nec., metal products manufactures nec. Automotive Motor vehicles and parts, transport equipment nec. Electronics Electronic equipment, machinery and equipment nec. Services Electricity gas manufacture, distribution, water, construction, trade, transport nec., water transport, air transport, communication, financial services nec., insurance, business services nec., recreational and other services, public admin. and defence, education, health, ownership of dwellings Source: Authors Own Classification 45 Appendix 6: Share (%) of Intermediates, Labour and Capital in Gross Output CAN USA MEX MER LAT EUR ROW Average CanUSA Average Latin Intermediates Labour Capital Total Resources Intermediates Labour Capital Total Food Intermediates 59 16 24 100 63 15 22 100 29 33 38 100 35 21 44 100 35 30 35 100 53 31 16 100 41 30 29 100 61 16 23 100 33 28 39 100 51 12 36 100 43 18 39 100 19 7 73 100 40 17 44 100 35 11 54 100 38 17 45 100 35 14 50 100 47 15 38 100 31 12 57 100 69 68 68 74 70 70 70 69 71 Labour Capital Total Textiles Intermediates Labour Capital Total Manufacturing Intermediates Labour Capital Total Technology Intermediates Labour Capital Total Automobile Intermediates Labour Capital Total Services Intermediates Labour Capital Total 16 15 100 14 18 100 05 27 100 11 16 100 08 22 100 13 17 100 11 19 100 15 17 100 8 21 100 63 27 10 100 66 25 9 100 56 11 32 100 64 15 21 100 65 10 25 100 68 21 11 100 69 16 15 100 65 26 9 100 62 12 26 100 65 23 12 100 63 23 14 100 62 08 30 100 66 17 17 100 67 10 23 100 67 21 12 100 69 15 17 100 64 23 13 100 65 12 23 100 64 24 12 100 54 32 15 100 59 12 29 100 62 21 16 100 53 11 36 100 65 28 7 100 67 16 17 100 59 28 13 100 58 15 27 100 78 15 7 100 71 23 6 100 68 8 24 100 75 18 07 100 70 11 19 100 73 22 6 100 72 15 13 100 75 19 6 100 71 12 17 100 35 36 30 100 37 39 24 100 29 22 49 100 36 35 29 100 41 28 32 100 40 30 29 100 41 31 27 100 36 37 27 100 35 28 36 100 Agriculture Source: Computed from GTAP version 5 Database 46 Appendix 7: Benchmark Bilateral Tariff rates (%) AGRI RESO FOOD Tariff rates imposed on imports from Canada United States 4.4 0.0 8.8 Mexico 33.7 0.0 34.1 Mercosur 6.8 0.2 20.1 Latin America 12.4 8.8 17.9 Europe 31.0 0.3 48.2 Rest of the World 66.3 1.2 33.9 Tariff rates imposed on imports from United States Canada 4.2 0.0 25.4 Mexico 17.0 0.0 32.9 Mercosur 6.8 0.3 16.6 Latin America 10.0 7.8 17.2 Europe 12.7 0.5 27.0 Rest of the World 45.1 1.8 40.4 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Mexico Canada 1.9 0.0 31.8 United States 8.6 0.0 8.8 Mercosur 10.9 2.0 17.2 Latin America 12.2 4.9 16.3 Europe 18.3 0.1 31.0 Rest of the World 24.8 1.8 40.7 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Mercosur Canada 2.0 0.0 17.7 United States 16.2 0.5 15.5 Mexico 6.9 9.9 21.4 Latin America 10.9 10.1 14.8 Europe 7.8 0.2 31.9 Rest of the World 41.9 1.8 34.6 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Latin America Canada 2.2 0.0 24.0 United States 13.4 0.4 18.0 Mexico 12.0 9.5 24.4 Mercosur 7.8 3.6 15.1 Europe 10.4 0.4 42.5 Rest of the World 33.0 1.3 26.5 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Europe Canada 4.7 0.0 49.9 United States 10.6 0.4 8.8 Mexico 5.6 6.8 30.0 Mercosur 9.8 2.4 17.8 Latin America 7.0 7.3 18.2 Rest of the World 23.8 4.5 37.6 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Rest of the World Canada 3.5 0.0 22.6 United States 14.6 0.4 12.2 Mexico 10.5 6.5 31.7 Mercosur 8.8 4.4 16.7 TEXT MANU TECH AUTO SERV 0.0 0.0 16.5 15.7 8.2 12.5 0.0 0.0 8.1 7.4 2.1 3.6 0.0 0.0 14.1 9.9 3.5 5.7 0.0 0.0 12.3 25.4 3.0 6.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.8 0.0 0.4 0.0 0.0 16.8 22.3 8.6 12.3 0.0 0.0 10.5 9.9 3.4 5.8 0.0 0.0 13.5 9.1 3.2 4.6 0.0 0.0 16.5 12.9 3.1 4.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.7 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 16.2 12.9 9.1 11.7 0.0 0.0 10.1 9.0 3.7 7.0 0.0 0.0 14.4 10.9 3.7 3.4 0.0 0.0 36.3 16.9 5.3 12.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.9 0.0 0.2 11.5 7.5 11.6 13.3 5.4 8.5 4.1 3.0 9.4 10.2 4.2 5.1 2.6 2.4 11.6 9.0 3.1 7.1 3.3 1.7 13.4 16.6 6.4 14.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.1 0.0 0.3 20.1 14.5 20.8 17.3 9.4 10.4 1.8 2.5 8.1 7.9 2.3 3.0 3.7 3.5 13.6 18.0 3.1 5.6 4.6 1.3 13.2 18.4 1.1 2.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 14.9 9.7 22.3 15.9 14.5 15.0 4.3 3.1 9.6 10.8 9.8 8.6 2.8 2.2 8.8 14.2 9.2 7.1 2.6 2.0 12.8 22.1 11.9 11.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.1 0.2 18.6 13.3 21.3 19.8 4.8 2.8 10.5 10.4 2.0 1.8 10.1 14.2 6.2 2.6 14.3 34.4 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 47 Latin America Europe 12.1 10.2 4.9 0.1 18.6 40.6 13.3 10.6 10.7 3.6 9.9 3.9 15.0 6.7 2.1 0.0 Source: GTAP Data Base Appendix 8 Percentage change in Tariff rates among FTAA members AGRI RESO FOOD Tariff rates imposed on imports from Canada United States 0 0 0 Mexico 0 0 0 Mercosur 0 -100 0 Latin America 0 -100 0 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Unite States Canada 0 0 0 Mexico 0 0 0 Mercosur 0 -100 0 Latin America 0 -100 0 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Mexico Canada 0 0 0 United States 0 0 0 Mercosur 0 -100 0 Latin America 0 -100 0 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Mercosur Canada -3 -100 0 United States -47 -100 -43 Mexico 0 -100 0 Latin America 0 -100 0 Tariff rates imposed on imports from Latin America Canada -13 -100 0 United States -36 -100 -51 Mexico 0 -100 0 Mercosur 0 -100 0 TEXT MANU TECH AUTO SERV 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 0 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 0 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 0 0 0 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 0 0 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 0 0 0 0 48 Appendix 9 Effect of NAFTA-like Tariff Cuts Between NAFTA and Other FTAA Members: Regional supply of Goods and Services (Long Term) (% change over benchmark) AGRI RESO FOOD TEXT MANU TECH AUTO SERV -0.3 -0.8 2.1 -8.4 44.5 -1.9 -1.8 -0.2 -0.6 2.0 -7.7 -4.8 -1.5 -1.5 -2.9 -5.9 1.9 151.0 97.5 -0.7 -0.9 0.1 0.1 2.3 30.2 25.6 -1.4 -1.4 0.1 0.1 0.9 74.7 39.6 -1.6 -1.5 1.7 0.1 9.0 121.9 514.0 -2.8 -2.9 0.0 0.2 3.2 -6.2 4.2 -1.3 -1.3 -0.5 -0.8 1.9 -8.2 37.2 -2.1 -2.0 -0.1 -0.4 2.1 -7.6 -4.7 -1.4 -1.4 -2.2 -4.8 2.8 157.4 190.1 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.0 2.2 44.1 40.1 -1.5 -1.4 -0.1 -0.2 0.6 69.1 33.1 -1.8 -1.7 2.0 -0.2 8.6 223.7 105.1 -3.1 -3.2 -0.1 0.0 3.0 -6.3 7.5 -1.4 -1.4 -2.4 -2.9 0.2 -1.1 15.1 -4.0 -3.9 -2.1 -2.4 0.4 -9.4 -6.6 -3.3 -3.4 -7.1 -9.9 -2.0 136.9 59.7 -4.9 -5.0 -0.9 -1.0 0.7 40.0 33.4 -2.5 -2.4 -1.3 -1.4 -0.7 74.7 44.2 -3.0 -2.9 1.1 -1.1 1.8 1533.0 192.2 -4.0 -4.0 -1.8 -1.7 0.7 -7.9 2.7 -3.1 -3.1 11.6 13.9 93.1 1.3 72.9 9.7 9.8 9.2 43.9 11.6 0.7 4.2 7.8 7.8 129.1 73.9 142.2 0.6 93.0 12.2 12.0 32.0 25.6 69.9 0.1 55.3 8.2 8.2 31.7 29.9 112.1 -3.6 51.9 12.1 12.2 92.5 60.1 438.2 -9.8 287.5 30.1 30.1 7.4 7.5 10.8 0.6 13.1 6.0 6.0 8.1 57.8 10.4 0.0 2.2 6.6 6.6 314.7 190.3 354.3 224.5 -7.4 22.7 22.5 20.6 24.3 62.4 43.2 0.0 9.3 9.3 41.4 39.6 136.4 143.0 -4.2 13.2 13.3 131.9 62.6 459.0 442.8 -16.6 37.5 37.5 4.6 4.7 7.8 -2.0 2.1 3.2 3.2 Regional supply by Canada Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World -0.5 -1.5 2.6 -7.4 -0.9 -1.6 -1.5 Regional supply by United States Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World -0.7 -1.2 2.6 -7.3 -0.8 -1.6 -1.5 Regional supply by Mexico Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World -3.6 -4.3 -0.3 -10.0 -3.7 -4.5 -4.4 Regional supply by Mercosur Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World 8.9 46.7 12.2 1.4 8.5 7.7 7.8 Regional supply by Latin America Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World 5.4 26.0 7.5 -2.9 3.6 3.1 3.2 12.8 14.5 91.5 24.7 2.5 10.7 10.9 49 Regional supply by Europe Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World 0.7 0.0 4.1 -6.0 0.6 -0.1 -0.1 1.5 1.0 3.8 -7.9 -8.3 -0.2 -0.1 1.3 0.9 3.5 -6.3 -3.4 -0.1 -0.1 -2.5 -5.5 2.4 -10.3 -26.3 -0.2 -0.4 1.5 1.5 3.7 -7.7 -8.1 0.0 0.0 1.8 1.7 2.5 -15.1 -16.5 0.1 0.1 5.3 3.0 12.1 -32.0 -40.0 0.0 -0.1 1.4 1.5 4.5 -5.0 -1.4 0.0 0.0 1.3 0.9 3.5 -6.3 -3.4 -0.1 0.0 -2.5 -5.5 2.4 -10.3 -26.3 -0.2 -0.4 1.5 1.5 3.7 -7.7 -8.1 0.0 0.0 1.8 1.7 2.5 -15.1 -16.5 0.1 0.1 5.3 3.0 12.1 -31.9 -39.9 0.0 -0.2 1.4 1.5 4.6 -5.0 -1.4 0.0 0.0 Regional supply by Rest of the World Canada United States Mexico Mercosur Latin America Europe Rest of the World 0.7 0.0 4.1 -6.0 0.6 -0.2 0.0 1.5 1.0 3.9 -7.9 -8.2 -0.2 -0.1 50