ReflecT Research Paper 13/004 Governance of Sustainable Security: The Impact of Institutions and Values On Labour Market Transitions Using ESS and SILC Data? Ruud Muffels September 2013 ©ReflecT, Website: www.tilburguniversity.edu/research/institutes-and-researchgroups/reflect/, Address: PO Box 90153, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands, Phone: (+ 31) (0)13 466 21 81, ISSN 1 Governance of Sustainable Security: The Impact of Institutions and Values On Labour Market Transitions Using ESS and SILC Data? Ruud Muffels1 Abstract The paper examines the impact of labour market institutions and social norms and values on the relative performance of countries in balancing flexibility and security. In a previous paper (Muffels, 2010) we defined a set of institutional and transition outcome indicators to compare the relative labour market performance of 26 countries in the EU on these two dimensions. The picture provided little support for the supposition that regimes tend to converge. In this second paper we try to explain the transition patterns we observe. We are particularly interested in the impact of labour market institutions and social norms and values on these transition patterns. The institutions to examine concern not only the usual candidates such as EPL, Unemployment Insurance and Active Labour Market Policy but also various indicators for the wage bargain such as union density, collective agreement coverage and level of centralisation or decentralisation. The novelty is that we also consider the effects of social norms and values in society associated with work orientations and feelings of trust and altruism. We estimate multi-level multinomial regression models with country fixed effects on integrative and exclusionary labour market transitions. Integrative transitions refer to job-to-job transitions, transitions from a fixed-term into a permanent job and re-entry into employment; exclusionary transitions to exit out of employment. The evidence confirms that employment regulation exerts negative effects and UI generosity and trust positive effects on integrative transitions. Support is found for the positive impact of UI generosity on the job match. Labour market policy and wage bargain indicators exert counterintuitive or small and insignificant effects. Keywords: flexicurity, welfare regimes, labour market institutions, wage bargain, social norms and values, SILC-data JEL Classification Code: J3, J5, J6, D63 1 The paper was presented at the WP3-workshop of the GUSTO project, held on 20-22 September 2010, CES, Sorbonne University, Paris 2 1. Introduction and background In an earlier paper (Muffels, 2010) we defined dynamic indicators to measure the balance between flexibility and what is called “sustainable security” in society and secondly to apply these indicators to judge the relative performance of countries, regimes or pathways. The starting point was a ‘Stocks-Flows-Outcome’ conceptual model based on Sen’s capability approach. The stocks indicate the capabilities or free choices of people, the flows agency and the outcomes the extent by which people living in a particular country or belonging to a particular policy regime are able to safeguard income and employment security or well-being throughout the life course. Using comparative panel data (SILC), transition outcome indicators on job and contract mobility and on income, wage and employment security were next calculated. A distinction was made with respect to these “objectively assessed” indicators between ‘integrative’ transitions, which are transitions into employment or out of income insecurity, and ‘exclusionary’ transitions, which are transitions out of employment or into income insecurity. In the second step the various transition indicators were combined in a flexibility-mobility index and an income-employment security index for mapping the countries on the way they balance flexibility and security. There appeared little evidence for convergence since huge differences were observed across the 26 countries. The picture drawn from institutional and dynamic indicators appears not only dissimilar but also weakly resembling the dominant welfare regime classification of Esping-Andersen or the ‘coordinated-liberal’ varieties of capitalism classification of Hall and Soskice. In Figure 1 we show the classification of countries obtained from our transition indicators on job, contract and wage mobility (mobility Index) and on employment and income security (security Index)2. 2 The calculation of the transition indicators is explained in Muffels (2008, 2010). The indicators are a weighted average of the annual transition probabilities between the various income and employment statuses weighted with the share of each income or employment status in society. The probabilities are transformed into indices by dividing each indicator by the European average and multiplying by 100. In the last step a composite indicator is defined by taking the mean over the various separate indices. 3 Figure 1. The relationship between flexibility (job, contract plus wage mobility) and security (income plus employment security) using transition indicators (indices), EU26 Source: Muffels, 2010 (based on SILC data for 2005-2006). The Nordic countries are in the “flexicurity quadrant” with high levels of flexibility and security but the picture for the other countries is more mixed. The Eastern countries share a low level of security but very dissimilar levels of flexibility. Sustainable security The ‘stocks-flows-outcomes’ model was inspired by Sen’s capability model but also by the life course approach because what matters to people is that throughout the life course they are able to balance mobility and security in a satisfactory way. We used the term ‘sustainable security’ to underline the life course dimension of security. Sustainable security then translates into the security throughout the life course to be able or to feel able to do the things in life which one has reason to value most. The definition has an objective and subjective interpretation. The objective interpretation requires the setting of a threshold below one is considered insecure like a poverty threshold for income insecurity that generally implies a normative view about what is just or fair. 4 In this paper we aim to explain the transition patterns on the labour market. We are particularly interested in the impact of labour market institutions on these transition patterns. The institutions to examine concern not only the usual candidates such as EPL, Unemployment Insurance and Active Labour Market Policy but also various indicators for the wage bargain such as union density, collective agreement coverage and level of centralisation or decentralisation. The novelty of the paper is that we also consider the effects of norms and values in society. We estimate multi-level multinomial regression models with country fixed effects on integrative and exclusionary labour market transitions. Integrative transitions refer to job-to-job transitions, transitions from a fixed-term into a permanent job and re-entry into employment; exclusionary transitions to exit out of permanent, self or temporary employment. 2. Flexibility and security 2.1. Trade-off versus flexicurity The definition of flexibility and security used here is derived from Wilthagen’s matrix (2004) and Standing’s (1999) definition of five forms of flexibility (internal and external numerical flexibility, functional internal and external and wage flexibility) and seven forms of security (job, work-life balance, employment, employability, representation or voice, workplace and income security). The use of the SILC data does not allow us to focus on internal or functional flexibility and employability or representation security since that would require company or demand side data. For this paper we focus therefore on external numerical flexibility, wage flexibility, and on job, income and employment security but not on internal flexibility and combination security. 2.2 Flexibility and security indicators A second element is that we want to examine the effects of various policy/institutional indicators on transition patterns. From the literature on indicators three sets of institutions can be distinguished: 5 Institutional indicators on labour law and labour market policy: they pertain to EPL regulations, minimum wage, taxes, working time regulations and LMP spending as percentage of GDP (or per unemployed). Another set of institutional indicators concern indicators on unemployment insurance such as benefit replacement rates, benefit access conditions and benefit coverage. A third set refer to company practices (pay schemes, working time arrangements) and those dealing with the wage bargain (union density, union coverage, centralisation versus decentralisation etc.). For this paper we restrict ourselves to macro-level indicators for which data were readily available for most of the countries participating in SILC. Indicators can be measured in a static (stocks) and a dynamic way (flows). Institutional and outcome indicators, whether they are static or dynamic, are then used to map countries in twodimensional space showing the bivariate relationships between the indicator variable and the country dummy. That has been the approach in the previous paper (Muffels, 2010). Another approach is to examine the multivariate relationships between the outcome indicators and the institutional and/or country variables. In such a modelbased approach the static (though they might vary over time) institutional indicators act as explanatory factors and the dynamic (or transition based) outcome indicators as dependent variables (see Muffels & Luijkx, 2008). This paper focuses on the multivariate approach. 3. Data The institutional indicators to be explained in section 4 are derived from the macrolevel information mostly contained in the OECD and Eurostat databases. Most of the information in these databases stem from the European labour Force Survey. We used the time-varying information for the years 2003-2006 since these years overlap with the years for which we had panel data. For the calculation of the transition outcome indicators we used the micro-level data of SILC for the years 2003-2006. The data contain information on 26 countries for 2005-2006 but only 15 countries for 20042005 and even less countries for 2003-2004 for which reason we used the 2005-2006 6 data. The macro-level information for the corresponding years were next linked to the individual-level longitudinal SILC data for the years 2003-2006. The data on norms and values come from the European Social Survey that is a comparative repeated cross-sectional social survey on opinions, political and social attitudes, social norms and values in Europe. We used the information for the years 2002-2006 which corresponds rather nicely to the SILC data. We linked the ESS data to the SILC data by first calculating the mean scores of values by sex, age class, country and year and then matching these values to the SILC data. The ESS is though a twoyearly survey and hence not containing information for the years in between, that is for 2003 and 2005. For these years we imputed the data by taking the means for 2002 and 2004, and for 2004 and 2006 and assigned these to 2003 and 2005. 4. Institutional and outcome indicators 4.1. Institutional flexicurity indicators in the European Employment Strategy The three indicators used in the European Employment Strategy (EES) to measure and monitor flexibility, pertain to the strictness of Employment Protection Legislation (EPL) and the share of temporary and part-time workers in a country (see Chung et al., 2009). For analysis purposes also employment tenure figures are often used. The first is an institutional indicator, the other two can be viewed as outcome indicators for the employment protection legislation and part-time work legislation. For employment security the agreed institutional indicators in the EES are: the percentage of the adult population participating in education and training programmes, the expenditures on active labour market policies (ALMP) as a percentage of GDP or per capita and the frequency of unemployed people moving into paid work through the public employment services. Another indicator used is the skill level or level of educational attainment of the labour force reflecting firms’ investments in skill development programs (investment in life-long learning and continuous vocational training). Institutional indicators for income security in the EES are the replacement rates of the unemployment benefits (UIB) and the expenditures to passive labour market policies (PLMP) as a percentage of GDP. Another institutional 7 measure for income security that is often used in EU policy circles, is the headcount of people in poverty before and after social transfers. It shows how well governments with their social transfer system are able to reduce the number of people in poverty. These indicators reflect the existing social security and passive labour market policies. Most of the institutional indicators on employment security comes from the EU-LFS (Labour Force Survey) data, whereas the information for the income security indicators comes from the EU SILC data (Statistics on Income and Living Conditions). Due to increasing interest in the EES for work-life balance issues, indicators on combination security or work-life balance (WLB) security are proposed, referring to the ability to combine work and private life acting as one of the seven security aspects distinguished before. WLB indicators mentioned in the literature also pertain to indicators like the availability of child care relief facilities, the options for working in flexible working times, and the options for care leaves and other types of leave. In addition we must mention the existing EES indicators on the issue of gender equality, such as the gender pay gap and the gender-based occupational segregation rates (Philips et al, 2007b, EC 2007). 4.2 Institutional indicators on flexicurity in the literature In the economic literature the most often used indicators are the employment protection legislation indicators as developed by the OECD, the Active Labour Market Policy Expenditures indicators expressed in % of GDP and job tenure figures. In the industrial relations literature though also indicators are proposed concerning e.g. the features of the industrial relations system. The particular features and configuration of industrial relation systems impact on the wage levels as well as on the wage distribution across skill levels and industrial sectors and therewith affect wage mobility in the economy. The literature generally refers to three main indicators: - Trade union density (the % of workers being a union member) - Collective Wage Bargain coverage (% of workers covered by a Collective Agreement (CA) 8 - Degree of centralisation of the wage bargain that can differ from country to country ranging from a very decentralised way of bargaining, that is at the company or plant level, to a very centralised wage bargain at the national level. We collected information on these wage bargain indicators from the OECD and from Heejung (2009). Table 1 shows the evidence on macro-level institutional indicators for the years closest to the SILC data of 2005-2006. The information on EPL, trade union density and collective agreement coverage is available for 2003 or 2004. The EPL for 2003 as constructed by the OECD is used while this comes closest to the time period considered in SILC (2005-2006). 9 Table 1: Institutional Indicators by country (2003-2006) Internal Labour Market Employment protection (2003) EU26 Austria Belgium Cyprus Czech Rep. Germany Denmark Estonia Spain Finland France Greece Hungary Ireland Iceland Italy Lithuania Luxembourg Latvia Netherlands Norway Poland Portugal Sweden Slovenia Slovakia U Kingdom EU26 EPL 2.15 2.51 . 2.10 2.40 1.78 2.31 3.01 2.13 2.90 2.82 1.75 1.33 1.57 2.33 2.76 3.36 2.50 2.27 2.72 2.19 3.36 2.50 2.58 1.75 1.11 2.51 EPLR 2.37 1.73 . 3.31 3.00 1.63 2.58 2.46 2.17 2.47 2.33 1.92 1.60 1.73 1.77 2.93 2.75 2.30 3.05 2.25 2.06 4.17 2.86 3.15 2.31 1.12 2.41 EPLT 1.50 2.63 . 0.88 1.25 1.38 1.53 3.50 1.88 3.63 3.13 1.13 0.63 0.63 1.88 2.07 3.75 2.10 1.19 3.13 1.75 2.75 1.63 1.88 0.38 0.38 2.33 EPLCD 3.25 4.13 . 2.13 3.75 3.13 3.63 3.13 2.63 2.13 3.25 2.88 2.38 3.50 4.88 4.03 3.88 4.00 3.00 2.88 3.63 2.88 3.75 2.88 3.75 2.88 3.22 Wage Bargain (2003-2004) CACO TUD V 32 98 54 96 70 68 21 35 21 65 69 83 . . 15 81 72 90 8 90 23 65 18 42 35 . . . 33 70 . . 40 58 16 20 21 81 55 . 14 35 18 87 75 92 44 100 24 . 29 35 22 73 External Labour Market (20052006) CACEN 0.71 0.61 0.26 0.27 0.47 0.54 . 0.38 0.57 0.17 0.39 0.26 0.64 . 0.34 . 0.33 0.30 0.58 . 0.20 0.30 0.56 43.00 . 0.13 0.51 ALMP 0.72 1.22 0.09 0.26 0.86 1.37 0.07 0.72 0.87 0.92 0.16 0.28 0.66 . 0.45 0.27 0.43 0.26 1.19 0.58 0.45 0.58 1.32 0.27 0.32 0.33 0.73 NRR 62 63 66 57 65 78 37 50 71 61 22 52 70 69 8 40 70 45 73 79 54 60 72 68 39 61 53 Notes: EPL Employment Protection Regulation; EPLR=EPL for Regular Contracts; EPLT=EPL for FixedTerm Contracts; EPLCDM=EPL for Collective Dismissal; TUD=Trade Union Density; CACOV Collective Agreement Employees Coverage; CACEN=Measure of Centralization of Wage Bargain; ALMP=Active LMP expenditures as % of GDP; NRR=5 year Replacement Rates Benefits OECD Source: OECD Database for EPL, ALMP, NRR and TUD; H. Chung (2009) for CACOV, CACEN 10 4.3 Indicators on attitudes, social norms and values The observed dissimilar performance of countries in balancing flexibility and security outcomes might indeed be related to institutional differences between countries as we contended in the previous section. Institutions though are designed and implemented according to the dominant social norms and values in society. If the norm for women is to work full-time the institutions for employment and income support might function properly to get women into full-time work but will likely to render poor support to women who prefer caring for children while not working or working part-time. Values then have an indirect effect mediated through the institutions. Values though might also exert a direct effect on integrating or exclusionary transitions through affecting agency decisions of people. In countries with a stronger work ethos people might quicker re-enter employment after being dismissed than in countries with weaker work values (integrating transition). In countries with higher levels of trust in other people or in national institutions people might be more willing to take risks and to more easily change jobs than in countries where people are more left alone. But higher levels of trust might also reflect higher levels of social capital and stronger social networks because of which people are more likely to experience integrating transitions (re-entry) and less likely exclusionary transitions (exit). Societies with a higher level of tolerance to homosexuals or undemocratic parties or where the opinions towards immigrants are more positive (open pluralist societies) or less negative (less competition for scarce jobs) are likely to experience more integrative and less exclusionary transitions. It is not the purpose of this paper to unravel the causal links between values, institutions and outcomes but to examine the possible direct impact of values on transitions and to see to what extent they contribute to explain the cross-country differences in flexibility-security outcomes. The information on norms and values used are from the two-yearly European Social Survey covering the years 2002-2006 which correspond nicely with the 2003-2006 period for the SILC data. In Figure 3 we depict the figures for trust in other people, altruism and positive opinions about the contribution of immigrants to the economy, culture and lifestyle for 2004 for 24 European countries including 11 Switzerland (CH). The largest variation exists in trust with the Scandinavian countries on top; the variation in altruism and opinions about immigrants are less uneven. Figure 2: Trust in people, altruism and positive opinions about immigrants (contribution to economy, culture, lifestyle) in the EU, ESS 2004 8 6 4 2 DK NO FI SE NL IE CH EE AT UK LU ES DE BE altruism Pos opinions immigrants EU24 trustpeople FR IT CZ SI HU SK PT GR PL 0 4.4 Transition outcome indicators In previous work using the European Community Household panel for 1994-2001 we constructed flexibility indicators for job and contract mobility and security indicators for income and employment security (Muffels & Luijkx, 2008; Muffels, 2008). The same indicators are used again now for this paper but applied on the SILC data covering EU26 for 2005-2006 including the Baltic and Eastern welfare states3. Flexibility measures: job, contract, working time and wage mobility The ECHP did not allow estimating job mobility due to lack of information on whether a job change involves an employer’s change or not. SILC however contains information on self-reported job change in the last 12 months and whether the change is a voluntary or an involuntary change. This variable is now used to construct a simple measure for voluntary and involuntary job mobility, the percentage of employed 3 Indicators on combination or work-life balance security are part of the framework elaborated in Muffels (2010) but not discussed here. 12 people changing jobs across two years voluntarily or involuntarily. Involuntary mobility deals with (collective) dismissal, business close downs and end of contract whereas voluntary mobility deals with people seeking better jobs or jobs that match their working time preferences better. A second simple flexibility indicator that we used in previous work is the so-called contract mobility (CM) or the annual transition rate for the various employment contract statuses. The mobility from a temporary into a permanent job is only one of the CM indicators used here, another is the mobility from a permanent job into self-employment which seems to become increasingly important in a number of countries (own account self-employed workers). Wage or pay flexibility and mobility Wage flexibility indicated by wage mobility is an important dimension of flexibility since it touches the question whether the labour market and its institutions create sufficient incentives to workers and unemployed people to search for a job or to move to another job. It is also associated with one of the key issues in the flexicurity debate on transition security, the security attained when people either voluntarily or involuntarily change positions and because of that become more or less income secure. We therefore see yearly changes in wage or pay primarily as indicators for the level of wage flexibility. We can associate wage mobility to the occurrence of a voluntary and involuntary job change in the last year. For wage mobility we use a simple metric on wage deciles changes (income groups ranging from low to high incomes with 10% of all income earners in each group). We calculated the percentage of people moving at least one wage decile up or down the wage ladder. Those who stay in the same decile are considered to experience a lateral move. 4.2 Security indicators: dynamic income and employment security The advocates of the Transitional Labour Market approach break a lance for ‘make transitions pay’ policies which are considered more effective than ‘make work pay’ policies. TLM policies therefore facilitate ‘integrative’ transitions and prevent ‘exclusionary’ transitions. To assess whether a job change is an ‘integrative’ or 13 ‘exclusionary’ transition we might calculate upward or downward job moves determined by the employment security or the level of hourly pay . The Employment Transition Security (ETS) indicator is such a measure that allows to make this distinction. The security indicator departs from the matrix of employment status changes across two years. It is a weighted average of the “entry’ and “exit’ rates, but with stays in employment considered as entries and stays out of employment as exits. In Table 3 we show the transition matrix used to construct the ETS employment security indicator. Entries into statuses with more security are defined as upward transitions (indicated by a + sign), and exits into statuses with lower security as downward transitions (indicated by -). Stays are defined as lateral or neutral transitions (indicated by =). The matrix shows the contract statuses at t cross-tabulated with the contract statuses at t+1. The signs (+, -, =) assigned to each cell depend on the relative ranking of each of the various contract statuses with a view to the level of employment security. Table 3: Change in employment security from year t to t+1 by type of contract (ETS) Perm Rank ES SE Temp Une Stud Ret Inact [4] [4] [4] [4] [1] [2] [3] Perm 1 [+] 2 [-] 3 [-] 4 [-] 5 [-] 6 [-] 7 [-] SE 8 [+] 9 [+] 10 [-] 11 [-] 12 [-] 13 [-] 14 [-] Temp 15 [+] 16 [+] 17 [+] 18 [-] 19 [-] 20 [-] 21 [-] Une 22 [+] 23 [+] 24 [+] 25 [-] 26 [-] 27 [-] 28 [-] Stud 29 [+] 30 [+] 31 [+] 32 [-] 33 [-] 34 [-] 35 [-] Ret 36 [+] 37 [+] 38 [+] 39 [-] 40 [-] 41 [-] 42 [-] Inact 43 [+] 44 [+] 45 [+] 46 [-] 47 [-] 48 [-] 49 [-] Note: Perm=Permanent contract; SE=Self-Employment including family workers, Temp=Temporary Contract; Une=Unemployment, Stud=Studies, i.e. Education, Training; Ret=Retirement; Inact=Inactivity. Source: Derived from EMCO-IG (2009) and own additions The ranks implicitly assigned by the ETS indicator are presented in the second panel (Rank ES) ranging from 1 (high) to 4 (low) showing that the ETS assigns a higher score 14 of employment security to any employment status compared to any non-working status. The ranks within the non-working groups are identical whereas the ranks within the employed are highest for permanent, second highest for self-employed and lowest for temporary workers4. Income security transitions For income security we employed various measures for poverty and wage income transitions using the SILC data. We developed measures for upward or downward income transitions such as the share of people moving upwards or downwards in terms of wage plus social security income or for the movements out or into low wage jobs and for movements out of or into working poverty. Here we only discuss the YTS or Income Transition Security (YTS) indicator. This is similarly to the employment security indicator calculated as the weighted average of the “entry into’ and “exit out of’ poverty rates, in which a stay in poverty is counted as an entry and a stay out of poverty as an exit, weighted with the shares of people in or out of poverty at t for the years of observation. Poverty is defined according to the 60% threshold of median equivalent household income. Table 4 shows the means of all outcome indicators for the year 2006 for EU26. We also include in table 4 a few static indicators such as the poverty head count ratio based on the 60% OECD threshold and the headcount for the working poor according to the same threshold. Voluntary mobility is shown to be much higher than involuntary mobility in all countries. Job mobility turns out to be high especially in the UK but very low in Poland, France and Luxembourg, Also Denmark did at that time not show very high mobility rates though high mobility rates are observed in the other Nordic countries Norway and Sweden. In the next step we calculated the contract mobility indicator (CM) as the mean of the transition rates between the three different contract statuses 4 To avoid normative statements about these rankings, we used in an earlier study (Muffels and Luijkx, 2008) the subjective assessment of people on how secure or insecure they judge their employment status based on the European Household Panel Data. SILC though contains no such information unfortunately. Another way would be to empirically assess the probability to be in stable employment over a particular period. 15 distinguished: a permanent job, a temporary job and self-employment. Table 4 shows the contract mobility rate but also the mobility from a temporary job into a permanent job because the latter indicator shows whether temporary jobs act as stepping stones into permanent jobs or as dead-end jobs from which it is hard to escape. Table 4. Flexibility and Transition Security Outcome Indicators Based on SILC 2005-2006 Employment security Job mobility EU26 AT Austria BE Belgium CY Cyprus CZ Czech Rep. DE Germany DK Denmark EE Estonia ES Spain FI Finland FR France GR Greece HU Hungary IE Ireland IS Iceland IT Italy LT Lithuania LU Luxembourg LV Latvia NL Netherlands N O Norway PL Poland PT Portugal SE Sweden SI Slovenia SK Slovakia UK Un. Kingdom EU EU26 TJM 0.07 0.09 0.10 0.09 0.08 0.10 0.14 0.18 0.15 0.06 0.07 0.19 0.09 0.18 0.11 0.11 0.06 0.11 0.09 VJM 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.09 0.12 0.13 0.11 0.04 0.05 0.16 0.07 0.15 0.07 0.10 0.04 0.10 0.07 INVJ M 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.01 0.02 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.02 0.22 0.06 0.08 0.20 0.07 0.16 0.26 0.10 0.21 0.04 0.06 0.15 0.05 0.14 0.26 0.07 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.05 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.03 and Income TP 0.40 0.35 0.31 0.35 0.31 . 0.61 0.30 0.28 0.15 0.18 0.53 0.52 0.23 0.24 0.33 0.47 0.59 0.20 ETS 0.30 0.15 0.24 0.20 0.20 0.45 0.31 0.17 0.32 0.25 0.19 0.11 0.16 0.63 0.15 0.22 0.24 0.23 0.21 YTS 0.76 0.80 . . . 0.81 0.73 0.70 0.74 0.73 0.68 . 0.75 0.83 0.63 . 0.76 . . POOR 0.12 0.12 0.11 0.08 0.13 0.06 0.16 0.18 0.12 0.13 0.18 0.14 0.15 0.08 0.16 0.20 0.16 0.18 0.09 WPOOR 0.09 0.06 0.08 0.04 0.08 0.04 0.11 0.13 0.08 0.08 0.15 0.09 0.06 0.07 0.10 0.15 0.12 0.13 0.07 0.46 0.29 0.09 0.52 0.46 0.46 0.51 0.26 0.44 -0.05 0.29 0.43 0.13 0.13 0.38 0.20 0.79 . 0.72 0.81 . . . 0.72 0.08 0.22 0.18 0.09 0.09 0.13 0.15 0.14 0.06 0.19 0.14 0.06 0.05 0.10 0.09 0.10 Note: TJM=Total Job Mobility; VJM=Voluntary Job Mobility; INVJM=Involuntary Job Mobility; TP=Mobility from temp to permanent job; ETS=Employment Transition Security; YTS=Income Transition Security; POOR=Poor according to OECD’s 60% median equivalent household income standard; WPOOR=% of people Working Poor (poor and employed) 16 Source: Eurostat, SILC data, 2003-2006 The mobility into permanent jobs is especially high in the UK, the Baltic States and some Eastern and Nordic countries, moderate in most Continental countries and rather low in the Southern countries. Contract mobility rates on the other hand are very low in Iceland, Portugal, France and the Netherlands (The Danish figures are biased, see note 3) but high in Hungary, Slovakia and again in Spain. A low level of contract mobility signals a low turnover on the labour market. The last indicator on flexibility is the wage mobility indicator as we explained before. We defined our wage mobility measure as the percentage of people moving up or down at least one decile. In Figure 3 we depict the results graphically. The picture on wage mobility is very dissimilar to the job or contract mobility figures we presented earlier. Remarkably so, the highest mobility is achieved in Latvia, Slovakia, Poland and Estonia since these countries show high upward but also high downward wage mobility rates. In Slovakia more than 40% of the working people saw their wage rise by one decile or more from 2005 to 2006 but also one in four saw their wages decline. Wages are flexible in these countries but not very secure. The UK, Netherlands, Denmark and 17 Finland perform rather poor but as Figure 3 clearly shows, wages are much more stable across years in these countries than in Slovakia, Latvia or Poland. There seems to be a trade-off between wage stability and total mobility. The higher total mobility is the lower wage stability. Remarkable is that Germany has a relatively low stability and the UK a rather high wage stability. The two employment -and income transition indicators show the levels of security attained in the various countries. Employment transition security is high in Denmark, Sweden, the UK and Austria but rather low in Poland and the other Eastern states. The country scores according to the mobility figures in Table 2 appears to correspond generally fairly well with those according to the institutional indicators though not for all countries like Belgium, Spain and Norway. It illustrates that the institutional rules exert a strong effect on outcomes but that they still tell only part of the story since it depends also on other factors how regulations work out in practice. The underlying reason is that actors might not behave in accordance to the norms or regulations, and therefore cause unexpected outcomes. Institutional indicators need for that reason to be supplemented with outcome indicators to obtain information on the achieved level of mobility or flexibility in a country. 4. Estimation of transition state multinomial regression models In the final step we estimated various transition state models in which the dependent variable represents the various mobility and security indicators. For this paper we restricted ourselves to: job-to-job transitions (the mobility, voluntarily or involuntary, from one job into another with those not moving acting as the reference group) the mobility from a fixed-term contract into a permanent contract (staying in a fixed-term contract acting as the reference group); re-entry mobility into either an open-ended contract, self-employment or a fixed-term contract after unemployment or inactivity (those staying unemployed/inactive as reference group). 18 exit mobility out of employment from an open-ended contract, from selfemployment or from a temporary contract into unemployment/inactivity (those staying in employment acting as the reference group). The first job mobility measure is a measure for flexibility whereas the last three measures indicate the level of employment security and changes therein over time. Five models are estimated and reported in Table 5 and Table 6. In Table 5 the focus is on explaining job mobility and employment security transitions. In Table 6 we report on the so-called values model because the focus shifted to the impact of social norms and values on the various transitions. The baseline model containing all the controls at the micro-level is not presented here. The models in Table 5 and Table 6 include the micro-level controls plus some macro-level institutional measures for flexibility (Model 1), income and employment security (Model 2,3) and for norms and values (Model 4). Four models are hence formulated: Model 1: the Employment Protection model with all the micro-level controls plus the institutional measures protecting the employee such as the employment protection regulations but also the level of replacement income. Model II: the Labour Market Policy model with all the controls plus the variables indicating the investments in Active Labour Market Policies and the net replacement rates. Model III: the Wage Bargain model again with all controls plus the three wage bargain measures discussed before. Model IV: The Values model again with all controls plus the four values and norms variables: trust, altruism, positive and negative attitudes to immigrants. The controls are chosen so as to correct for obvious compositional differences between countries. These are gender, age and age squared to account for the nonlinearity in the relationship of age with job mobility and exit and (re)-entry mobility (e.g. due to differences in early retirement patterns across countries), household type and number of children indicating life course stage accounting for differences in household formation and fertility behavior, type of job accounting for differences in 19 the shares of non-standard jobs (part-time and temporary job), health status and regional unemployment rate. The models are estimated as multi-level multinomial regression models with robust estimation of the standard errors correcting for country fixed-effects. The models are multinomial transition state models because they estimate the transitions from one origin state (employment, unemployment/inactivity, fixed-term contract) into various destination states (temporary contract, open-ended contract, self-employment, unemployment/ inactivity). The estimation of the baseline model shows that the controls have the suspected effects, negative effects of bad health, low education and the regional unemployment rate. The relationship with age is non-linear, inversely U-shaped for upward transitions and U-shaped for downward transitions. Households with children show lower transition rates indicating that transition patterns vary over the life course. Table 5 shows that the best performing model is the employment protection model with the EPL and the replacement rate included, then the labour market policy model and last the Wage Bargain model that does not add much to the explanation. The employment protection regulations for regular contracts exerts significant negative effects on voluntary job mobility and on the mobility from a temporary job into open-ended contracts. On the other hand it leads to more unemployed workers to move into a temporary job instead of moving into an open-ended contract. This seems obvious and reflecting the situation in Southern countries where strict regulations act as barriers to school leavers and unemployed workers to find regular jobs. The stricter EPL for temporary workers is the less likely to move from unemployment into a permanent contract and the more likely to move from a temporary job into unemployment instead of a permanent job. The results show a number of interesting institutional effects that needs however further scrutiny by including interaction terms between the indicators while many of these institutions are highly correlated. The wage bargain variables exert hardly any effect on the transitions on the labour market except for the coverage rate and the union centralization measure on the mobility from a fixed-term contract into selfemployment. The more people are covered in collective agreements the less likely to 20 make a move from a temporary job into a permanent job. This seems to reflect the insider-outsider characteristics of labour markets with those workers falling under a CA representing the insiders. Centralization of the wage bargain on the other hand has a positive effect on the move into a regular job. The replacement rate impacts strongly on the transitions observed here but the impact is not necessarily negative. It exerts a positive effect on movements into a permanent job or into self-employment after enrollment in a temporary job. This might point to the job matching argument as referred to by Gangl (2006) suggesting that benefits allow job seekers to wait and to search for the best match. It however also has a positive effect on involuntary job mobility suggesting that in countries with strong income protection employers tend to shift the costs of economic adjustment to the government knowing that employees are well covered. The effects of ALMP are puzzling, most of the effects are negative except for the effect on involuntary job mobility. Due to ‘creaming off’ practices it might be that ALMP measures are applied unevenly to involuntarily dismissed workers. There is also a negative effect of ALMP spending on entry into a temporary job after unemployment. Job seekers might be ‘hold up’ in labour market programs because of which the transition into a temporary job is delayed. In Table 6 the negative attitudes towards immigration concerns the opinion that many or no immigrants from the own, another region or from poorer countries should be allowed to move into the own country. The higher the score the less tolerant people are towards immigrants. The largest effects are observed for the trust variable measuring the extent by which people trust other people. The higher the level of trust in a country the higher voluntary job mobility, the higher the mobility from a temporary into a permanent job and the higher the re-entry from unemployment/inactivity into a permanent job. This seems to reflect the situation in the Nordic countries with high levels of trust and high levels of integrative transitions. High levels of trust seem to have negative effects on re-entry into self-employment but positive effects on exit into unemployment/inactivity after stopping one’ s business. Societies with higher levels of altruism are performing worse in terms of reintegrating people back into a job and are more likely to have high exit rates from self-employment or a temporary job into non-activity. 21 Table 5: Results of multinomial logit regression models on 2005-2006 transitions: Institutions (robust estimation corrected for country fixed effects) Exit out of employment Job Mobility Fixed-term contracts Volunt Involunt Perm SE Une Model 1: Employment Protection EPLreg -0.513* 0.176 -0.473*** -0.073 -0.136 EPLtemp -0.205 -0.026 -0.151 -0.116 0.166*** EPLCDM -0.258 0.170 0.048 0.390*** 0.054 NRR5yr -0.002 -0.005 0.011* -0.005 0.006 Model 2: Labour Market Policies ALMP -0.741 0.652*** -1.126*** -0.417 NRR5yr 0.005 -0.012*** 0.011*** -0.116*** -0.27 0.005 Ina Entry in work after Une/Ina Perm SE Tmp Perm SE Tmp -0.387* 0.017 0.210* -0.106 -0.314*** -0.018 -0.032 -0.095 0.153 0.005 0.014* 0.009 0.293*** 0.104 -0.016 0.016*** -0.116 -0.045 -0.117 -0.002 -0.219 0.108 0.145 0.262** 0.047 -0.129 -0.018*** -0.004 -0.289 0.002 0.155 0.017*** -0.253 -0.002 -0.440* -0.020*** 0.159 -0.001 0.001 -0.005 -0.005 -0.01 0.010* -0.002 -0.431 0.020*** -0.211 0.009* Model 3: Wage Bargain TUDensity 0.011 0.002 0.08 0.006 0,000 0.011 0.004 0.001 -0.005 0.001 CACov -0.113 0.007 -0.014** -0.010** 0.003 -0.006 -0.012 -0.008* 0.004 -0.03 CACentr -0.008 -0.007 0.020*** 0.011 0.005 -0.017 -0.005 -0.001 -0.005 0.003 N Model 1 115814 11742 69759 108907 R2 Model 1 0.09 0.05 0.12 0.09 2 R Model 2 0.08 0.04 0.11 0.09 2 R Model 3 0.09 0.04 0.10 0.08 Controls: country, part-time; temporary job; household type; gender; age, age squared, regional unemployment rate Source: SILC, 2005-2006 22 Table 6: Estimation Results of multinomial logit models on 2005-2006 transitions: Values (robust estimation corrected for country fixed effects) Exit out of employment Job Mobility Fixed-term contracts Volunt Invol. Perm SE Une Model 4: Values Trust people 0.726*** Altruism 0.699 Neg attitudes to Immigrant -0.270 Pos attitudes to Immigrant -1.119*** N Model 4 R2 Model 4 83838 0.09 0.132 0.328 0.355*** 0.028 -0338 1.117 0.110 -0.299 -0.298 -0.134 0.084 0.329 Ina -0.029 0.725*** -0.309*** -0.041 0.046 -1.498*** 0.267 0.023 -1.077*** 0.316*** -0.097 -0.833*** 0.303*** Entry in work after Une/Ina Perm SE Temp 1.402 10753 0.05 Perm SE 0.102 -0.318 0.408*** -0.141 1.599*** 1.443** 0.348 0.141 0.362 0.189 -0.212 0.555*** -0.154 0.530* 0.823** -0.047 -0.144 0.688*** 64054 0.126 98727 0.088 Note: Controls are country, part-time; temporary job; household type; gender; age, age squared, regional unemployment rate 23 Temp Finally with respect to positive and negative attitudes towards immigrants we find that countries with negative attitudes towards immigrants are less likely to re-integrate temporary workers into permanent employment and more likely to experience higher levels of exclusionary transitions out of temporary jobs into unemployment or inactivity. Remarkably so, countries with more positive attitudes towards immigrants show lower voluntary job mobility, are more likely to re-integrate unemployed people in temporary jobs instead of in permanent jobs but also experience higher levels of exclusionary transitions from temporary jobs into unemployment . 6. Conclusions By way of conclusion, the paper clearly shows that the institutional and static indicators generally used for evaluating a country’s achievement on flexicurity are inadequate to show the performance of labour markets from a dynamic perspective since flexicurity policies demand information about transitions and durations. We started the paper by explaining our conceptual model for arriving at dynamic indicators for monitoring and analyzing a country’s labour market performance. We called this model the stock-flow outcome model (SFO) on flexibility and security in which the stocks of capabilities (forms of human, social and cultural capital), together with the flows (choices and events) determine the outcomes in terms of flexibility and sustainable security. The model served already as the starting point for estimating multivariate models to explain the transitions as captured in the various dynamic indicators and then to add institutional measures and country characteristics to the models to control for compositional differences and to examine the effect of institutions on these transitions. We have done that before on the European Community household panel. We conducted some preliminary analyses on the SILC data, which we discussed briefly. A number of single indicators on labour market mobility and on income and employment security were calculated and we looked into how well the various labour markets perform according to these. We in the end constructed two composite 24 indicators on flexibility and security combining the information embedded in the single indicators. The picture for the countries that we derived from the various outcome indicators is mixed. It shows that the picture derived from the institutional indicators (e.g. on the regulations for temporary and permanent jobs) is rather different from the picture obtained by using the dynamic indicators. The findings on the Eastern and Southern countries translate strongly into the relative poor outcomes of these segmented labour markets with respect to exhibiting low levels of mobility in terms of job, contract and wage mobility and simultaneously achieving low standards of income and employment security. The Scandinavian countries seem to attain fairly high levels of dynamic employment and income security. But also the UK and Ireland perform well with respect to employment security though less well with regard to income security. The information presented here covers the years 2005-2006, but a period in which the labour market was flourishing. This suggests that there is ground to suspect the outcomes to become worse in the years to come as a result of the economic crisis most of the EU countries faced since the end of 2007. We found some evidence that some of the institutions we have looked at in this paper exert rather strong effect on flexicurity transitions and outcomes. Especially the employment protection legislation create strong barriers on the labour market either to enter or to leave a job and to move into a permanent job. For the replacement rates we found mixed evidence showing positive effects on movements from a temporary job into a permanent job or into self-employment but also facilitating involuntary job mobility. This might point to the job matching argument suggesting that benefits allow job seekers to wait and to search for the best match. It however also has a positive effect on involuntary job mobility (dismissals) suggesting that in countries with strong income protection employers tend to shift the costs of economic adjustment to the government knowing that employees are well covered. We looked into the impact of values on integrative and exclusionary transitions and found significant effects for trust and positive and negative opinions about immigrants. Societies with high levels of trust seem to allow people to take more risks either to change jobs more easily or to move into selfemployment and to be more mobile. Societies with high levels of altruism on the 25 contrary seem to have higher levels of exclusionary transitions from the labour market. Countries with stronger positive or negative feelings about immigrants seem to perform worse in reintegrating temporary workers or unemployed people back into standard jobs. Much of these findings especially on the impact of values need further scrutiny to come to more evaluative conclusions. One conclusion though is that the differences in institutions and values undeniable contribute to explain the large diversity in the transition patterns in Europe and in the way countries are trying to attain a better balance between flexibility and security. References Boeri, T. & P. Garibaldi (2007). Two Tier Reforms of Employment Protection, A Honeymoon Effect? Working Paper No. 37, February 2007, Collegio Carlo Alberto, Turin Bovenberg, A.L., & Wilthagen, A.C.J.M. (2009). On the road to flexicurity: Dutch proposals for a pathway towards better transition security and higher labour market mobility. European Journal of Social Security, 10(4), 325-347 Chung, Heejung (2009), Flexibility for whom? Working Time Flexibility Practices of European Companies, thesis, University of Amsterdam Chung, HJ, Muffels, R. and T. Wilthagen (2009). Defining and testing flexicurity indicators in Europe: How well performs the Dutch Labour Market comparably? OSA-publication, OSA, 2009 EMCO (2007), Employment guidelines 2005-2008, Indicators for monitoring and analysis, Brussels (employment_strategy/pdf/list_indicators_2007_en.pdf) EMCO (2008), Indicators for monitoring and analysis of Flexicurity: Progress report, Brussels: EC, The Indicators Group, pp.42. EMCO (2009), Indicators for monitoring and analysis of Flexicurity: Final report, Brussels: EC, The Indicators Group, pp.42. Eamets, R. and T. Paas (2007), Flexicurity, combining labour market flexibility and security in the Baltic States, In: Jørgensen, H. and Madsen, P. K. (ed.), Flexicurity 26 and beyond. Finding a new agenda for the European Social Model, Copenhagen: DJØF Publishing, pp. 391-420. ISBN: 978-87-574-1708-1 Ester, P., Muffels, R., J. Schippers & T. Wilthagen (eds.) (2007), Innovating Labour Markets in Europe: Dynamics and Perspectives, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, November 2008. European Commission, (2006; 2007a). Employment in Europe, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg, European Commission (2007b). Communication from the Commission to the Council, the European Parliament, The European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions: Towards Common Principles of Flexicurity: More and better jobs through flexibility and security, Brussels, pp. 23. European Commission (2005). Integrated guidelines for growth and jobs (2005-2008), Document COM(2005), 141 final:2005/0057(CNS), Brussels 12.4.2005 European Expert Group on Flexicurity (2007), Flexicurity Pathways. Turning hurdles into stepping stones, Brussels, pp. 41. Eurostat, 2009. Sustainable development in the European Union, 2009 Monitoring report of the EU sustainable development strategy, EC, Luxembourg. Fouarge, D., R. Muffels (2009), Working part-time in The British, German and Dutch Labour Market: Scarring for the Wage Career? , Schmollers Jahrbuch-Journal of Aplied Social Science Studies, 129 (2009): 1 – 10 Kerkhofs, M., Chung, H. and Ester, P. (2008), 'Working time flexibility across Europe: a typology using form-level data', Industrial Relations Journal, 39, (6), 569-85. Klammer, U., Muffels, R. and Wilthagen, T. (ed.), (2008), Flexibility and Security over the Life course. Key findings and policy recommendations from the Foundation research, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, ISBN 978-92-897-0806-7, (forthcoming), pp. 64. Leschke, J., Watt, A. and Finn, M. (2008), Putting a number on job quality? Constructing a European Job Quality Index, Brussels: ETUI-REHS Research Department, pp.25. Muffels, R. (2010), Pathways to Flexicurity and Sustainability: How Well Perform National Labour Markets in Europe using Macro-Level (LFS) and Micro-Level 27 Data (SILC)? Paper presented at the GUSTO-WP3 conference, 11-12 March 2009, Barcelone, Spain Muffels, R. (2010), How Well Perform National Labour Markets in Europe using Dynamic Flexicurity Indicators and European Panel Data (SILC), paper presented at the SASE 2010 Conference in Philadelphia, Tilburg University, pp. 32 Muffels, R. (ed.), (2008), Flexibility and Employment Security in Europe: Labour Markets in Transition, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 422. Muffels, R., H. Chung, D. Fouarge, U. Klammer, R. Luijkx, A. Manzoni, T. Wilthagen and A. Thiel (2008), Summary Report Flexibility and Security over the Life course, Tilburg University/European Foundation, pp. 56. Muffels, R. and Luijkx, R. (2008a), ‘The Relationship between Labour Market Mobility and Employment Security for Male Employees: Trade-off or Flexicurity?’, Work, Employment and Society, 22 (2), 221-42. Muffels, R. and R. Luijkx (2008b), Male Labour Market Mobility and Income and Employment Security in Europe, In: Muffels, R. (ed.), Flexibility and Employment Security in Europe: Labour Markets in Transition, pp. 133-169. Muffels, Ruud and Bruce Headey (2008), Sen-sitising flexicurity: the role of pathways and capabilities in explaining career-long income and employment security using German and Australian Panel Data, Tilburg University, mimeo, pp. 1-32. OECD/JRC-European Commission (2008), Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators. Methodology and User Guide, Brussels: OECD, pp.148. Philips, K. and Eamets, R. (2007), Approaches to flexicurity: EU Models, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities: European Foundation, pp.51. Standing, G. (1999), Global Labour Flexibility. London: Macmillan Standing, G. (2009), Work after Globalization. Building Occupational Citizenship, Edward Elgar. Schmid, G. and B. Gazier (2002). The dynamics of full employment: social integration through transitional labour markets. Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield,US, Edward Elgar. 28 Sen, A. K. (1993) “Capability and Well-Being”. In M. Nussbaum and A. K. Sen (eds.), The Quality of Life. Oxford: OUP. Stiglitz, J. , Sen, A. & Fitoussi, J.-P. (2009). Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, European Union, Brussels. Wilthagen, T. and Tros, F. (2004). The concept of ‘flexicurity’: a new approach to regulating employment in the labour market. TRANSFER-European Review of Labour and Research. Vol.10, 2:166-186. Wilthagen, Ton. “Striking a balance? Flexibility and security in European Labour Market” In Employment policy from different angles, Copenhagen: DJØF Publishing, 2005. 29 30