Electronic Supplementary Material (S4) – Details of Methodology We start by defining the rebound effect according Druckman et al. (2014) as the percentage of offsetting actions in relation to expected savings . (1.1) For the estimation of potential rebound effects in terms of resource use, we are in particular interested in offsetting action effects and income effects . Simplifying, this could be expressed as the sum of the time . This means, more specifically, the total effect in terms of resource use results from a new mix of activities and consumption patterns due to a changing disposability of time and income. (1.2) The income effect is defined as the product of marginal propensities to consume terms of €) and resource intensity of consumption category (in (in terms of kg/€). (2.1) While the time effect results from the multiplication of the marginal propensities to time use (in terms of h) with the resource intensity of time use category (in terms of kg/h). (2.2) In microeconomic terms, we derive Engel curves (see chapter 5.3) showing the relationship between a consumer´s income and the goods bought. The slope of the Engel curve at any point is known as the marginal propensity to consume and measures for a marginal change in income the resulting change in the consumption of good . The ratio of the marginal propensity to consume the good to the average propensity to consume is defined as the income elasticity of demand of good consumption of good and measures the proportional change in the as ratio to the proportional change in income that causes the change. (3.1) The same propensities are defined for time use along harmonized time use categories depending on a marginal change of working hours . (3.2) The resource intensities of consumption are defined as the ratio of total material requirement ( ) per total expenditure along COICOP in Germany. The total material requirement induced by the German household consumption was calculated using a model that allows the estimation of the global resource effects of German consumption. The applied model is based on the so-called Environmentally Extended Input Output Analysis (EE-IOA). The EE-IOA is a tool, which reflects the (global) environmental direct and indirect effects resulting from production and consumption within one economy. It is based on information on the production and trade structure of an economy as well as on the environmental pressures associated with them. The most prominent results from the EE-IOA are the estimations of the domestic and global environmental pressures from the consumption perspective. In the case of material use the results of the calculation are commonly called “material use footprints" and represent the total direct and indirect material used along the whole production chain of each domestically produced or imported consumed product. In the case of Germany the calculated TMR values represent the resource use footprint (i.e. direct and indirect TMR) of the corresponding product group consumed by the households in Germany. The data on expenditure of the German households were extracted from the Eurostat database. For a detailed rationale of calculations of the total material requirement, please refer to Watson et al. (2013, annex A) and Moll and Acosta (2006). (4.1) More sophisticated is the definition of total material requirement per time use categories. The total time use in category is the average load of time use in Germany according the National Survey on Time Use in Germany. The total material requirement of time use is a re-allocation of the total material requirement of consumption along those harmonized time use categories. (4.2) The marginal propensity to consume in equation (3.1) is estimated using multivariate OLS regressions of expenditures budget) per category and a vector of covariates on disposable income (as total expenditure and an error term . (5.1) The marginal propensity to consume in equation (3.2) is estimated using a panel regression according Hausman- Taylor (1981) of time use in category vector of endogenous time-varying covariates , a vector of exogenous time-unvarying covariates on vector of time use ,a , and a vector of endogenous, time-unvarying variables (5.2) We follow Hausman and Taylors (1981) research rationale for defining the four subgroups of variables. exogenous, time-varying variables and potentially uncorrelated with such as time use for job, education, sleep etc. endogenous, time-varying variables und potentially uncorrelated with such as socio- economic characteristics like schooling years etc. exogenous, time-unvarying variables and potentially uncorrelated with such as gender and birth cohorts endogenous time-unvarying variables und potentially uncorrelated with are not identified. Isolating the effect of working hours in time use in category j, the result is an HT-Estimation of marginal propensities to time as a function of working hours , exogenous time use endogenous, time-varying socio-economics demographics , and time-unvarying, exogenous socio- . (5.3) The unknown parameters MPT in (2.1) and (2.2) with and and and are estimates of MPC and MPT. By substituting MPC and in equation (5.1) and (5.3), as well as substituting from equation (4.1) and (4.2) in equation (2.1) and (2.2), we derive: (6.1) And for (6.2) With average budget shares defined as the ratio of expenditures and time use in time use category in consumption category with respect to total expenditures and total time , respectively. Replacing and in equation (1.2) with equation (6.1) and (6.2) the offsetting action is (7.1) And the rebound effect in equation (1.1) by substituting the expected savings income effect and offsetting action with with equation (7.1) is thus (7.2)