Agricultural Markets Globalization, and Agricultural Development. Alexander Sarris January 2015 Agricultural Markets and Agricultural Trade (AS) • • • • • • • • • • • • • • The basic agricultural trade partial equilibrium model Measures of agricultural policy interventions Evolution of support in agriculture World trends and prospects for agricultural trade Differential performance of developed and developing countries in international markets Current pattern of protection in agricultural products Vulnerability of commodity dependent developing countries to trade shocks Developments in DC and LDC trade related agricultural indicators Making sense of the declining terms of trade for agricultural commodities Structural changes in global agricultural markets Evolution of agricultural trade negotiations The World Bank “Distortions” study Speculation and price transmission Agricultural risk management 2 Why is a section on Agriculture trade part of this course? • Agriculture is one of the main “sticking points” in the current WTO trade negotiations (the “Doha Round”), and it was important to the formation of the WTO. • Agriculture is important for the EU and all other countries • Policies, particularly those in developed countries, strongly influence agricultural sectors in those countries, and (via international markets) also influence agriculture in developing countries. 3 Background of Uruguay Round Agriculture Agreement (URAA) • Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture sought to bring Ag into GATT. (History, ag exemption, examples of accidental developments, e.g. Europeans had low import restrictions on soybeans when soybeans were not an important crop in the 60s and 70s. Imports increased drastically and Europe sought to impose restrictions, which were resisted by the US) • Trade restrictions cause welfare losses; countries gain by reducing their trade restrictions even if partners maintain their restrictions. Ag policies inflict costs on domestic economies and also on trade partners. • A given level of producer support is more costly to achieve with tariff than with producer subsidy. Production and consumption distortions. • Trade and domestic policies are linked; for example, maintaining a producer price higher than world price requires import barriers or export subsidies, or for govt to hold large stocks. (History of EU's lakes and mountains.) 4 Background, continued • Trade restrictions may be a cheap way -- in terms of government revenue, not of social welfare -- to provide producer protection. Reduction of trade restrictions increases the fiscal costs of protecting producers. Therefore, a reduction of trade restrictions may put downward pressure on domestic (non-trade) policies. • If an importing country imposes a production subsidy, without a trade restriction, the government has to either buy surplus or make “deficiency payments” – the subsidy. • Payments under farm programs are capitalized into land value. This means that the farmer who is receiving current government payments may already have "paid" for them in paying a higher price for land. 5 Suppose that the world price is pw. Under free trade, country shown in this diagram is an importer. Government wants to support producers by increasing producer price to p* > pw. (i) Show that tariff and import quota (where quota licenses are auctioned) are “equivalent”. (ii) Show that under either policy, deadweight loss is b+d. (iii) Show that if govt switches from tariff to a producer subsidy, producer price remains at p* and consumer price falls to pw. Consumers gain a+b+c+d and taxpayers lose a+b+c. The net gain is d, the amount by which deadweight loss falls. Producer subsidy is more efficient than trade policy (tariff or quota) but producer subsidy requires higher govt expenditures P* pw a b c d 6 Basic agricultural trade model • Gains from trade • Comparative advantage • Small country case effects of tariffs and quotas • Large country case effects of tariffs and quotas • Effects of producer subsidies and export subsidies • Effects of tariffs in general equilibrium • Trade policy Measures of agricultural policy interventions • Nominal protection coefficient (NPC) • NPC= P • Where PPd is domestic price, Pb is border price • Nominal rate of protection is NPC-1 • Effective protection coefficient • NEPC= VA P a P VA P a P • Effective protection rate=NEPC-1 d b d d i ij d j ij b j j b b i j Measures of agricultural policy interventions (2) • Distortion =gap between marginal social cost to seller and the marginal social cost to buyer. In absence of externalities this is the gap between the price paid and the price received irrespective of whether the level of these prices is affected by distortions • Total effect of distortions will depend not only on the size of direct agricultural policy measures but also on policy measure altering incentives in nonagricultural sectors. It is relative prices and hence relative rates of assistance that affect producer incentives Direct agricultural distortions • In small open perfectly competitive economy with many firms producing a homogeneous farm product, in the absence of externalities, processing and marketing margins, exchange rate distortions, and domestic and international trading costs, maximum welfare is achieved when domestic farm product price and consumer price is equal to E*P where E is the domestic currency value of foreign exchange and P is the foreign currency price of the product in the international market. Trade measures at national border Trade measures at national border (2) Exchange rate distortions (overvaluation or undervaluation) • • Figure 1 supply and demand of foreign exchange. If exchange rate to exporters is E0, while for importers is Em, then the price of importables is raised by Em-E=em*E, while the price of exportables is lowered by E-E0 =ex*E. If Em is much different than E0 then a black market in foreign exchange may emerge. So exchange rate to use in the calculations of the NRA is Em if the product is importable or E0 if the product is exportable. If taxes or subsidies are applied to intermediate products then they must be considered in computing an effective rate of assistance Almost all basic food commodities have seen their international prices rise significantly over the past few years (Commodity price indices: 1998-2000=100) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 2008 2007 2006 OILS 2005 2004 2003 CEREALS 2002 2001 2000 1999 DAIRY 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 MEAT SUGAR But prices for tropical export crops have lagged behind Prices for selected cereals and tropical export products 450 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 Wheat Rice Cocoa Coffee 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 0 Real prices of bulk food commodities have tended to decrease but since mid 1980s tendency seems to have stopped Real Prices: Bulk Commodities (1957-2008) 1400 1200 Wheat Rice 1000 Maize Soybeans 800 600 400 200 2008 2005 2002 1999 1996 1993 1990 1987 1984 1981 1978 1975 1972 1969 1966 1963 1960 1957 0 Real prices of vegetable oils have tended to decrease but since mid 1980s tendency seems to have stopped Real Prices: Vegetable Oils (1957-2008) 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 2008 2005 2002 1999 1996 1993 Rapeseed Oil 1990 1987 1984 1978 1975 1972 1969 1966 1963 1960 1957 0 1981 Palm Oil Soybean Oil Real prices of livestock commodities have tended to decrease albeit at slowing pace since mid 1980s Real Prices: Livestock Commodities (1957-2008) 300 Butter Pigmeat 250 Beef Poultry 200 150 100 50 2008 2005 2002 1999 1996 1993 1990 1987 1984 1981 1978 1975 1972 1969 1966 1963 1960 1957 0 Real prices of sugar and beverages have tended to decrease but since mid 1980s tendency seems to have stopped Real Prices: Sugar & Beverages (1957-2008) 1800 Coffee Sugar 1600 Tea Cocoa 1400 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 2008 2005 2002 1999 1996 1993 1990 1987 1984 1981 1978 1975 1972 1969 1966 1963 1960 1957 0 Global food commodity price volatility has been unusually high between 2006-2011. World food commodity price index 1990-2011 (FAO) Recent year wheat prices Wheat futures prices Recent year maize prices Maize future prices Rice prices Oilseed prices Soybean futures prices Sugar prices Dairy product prices Causes of high commodity prices • Strong growth in demand – sustained historically high economic growth world wide – bio-fuel feedstock demand, • particularly for maize and vegetable oils – stronger currencies/ weak USD • Constrained supply – high energy related input costs... crude oil up since 2000 – repeated yield shortfalls in key areas – climate change? • Low commodity stocks – increased speculation/ demand to rebuild • Increased activity on commodity exchange – higher volatility • Policies and policy changes – tariff liberalization by importers – decoupling of subsidies, reduction in export subsidies, lower public stocks – increased use of export taxes/ bans – biofuel subsidies/tariffs/tax credits etc, changing mandates etc Impact of high prices and global volatility on developing countries • Increase in world agricultural commodity prices may “double squeeze” low-income importers of food and oil, but may benefit agricultural exporters • How do recent price developments affect poor agriculture based economies in the aggregate and at the household levels? • Developing countries have structural features quite different from those of developed economies. How do these affect the impact of world price developments? • What is the role of trade and other structural policies in adjusting to global price developments? • Is domestic risk likely to increase in developing countries? Net importers of petroleum products and major grains as a percent of domestic apparent consumption - ranked by prevalence of undernourishment Countries Eritrea Burundi Comoros Tajikistan Sierra Leone Liberia Zimbabwe Ethiopia Haiti Zambia Central African Republic Mozambique Tanzania Guinea-Bissau Madagascar Malawi Cambodia Korea, DPR Rwanda Botswana Niger Kenya Petroleum % imported 100 100 100 99 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 98 100 100 100 100 Major grains % imported 88 12 80 43 53 62 2 22 72 4 25 20 14 55 14 7 5 45 29 76 82 20 % undernourishment 75 66 60 56 51 50 47 46 46 46 44 44 44 39 38 35 33 33 33 32 32 31 Estimated import bills of total food and major food commodities (US$ million) World Developing 2006 2007 2006 Total Food 630 135 812 743 190 975 Cereals 186 794 268 300 Vegetable Oils 70 822 Dairy 2007 LDC LIFDC 2006 2007 2006 2007 253 626 13 822 17 699 88 577 119 207 74 615 100 441 6 101 8 031 31 363 41 709 114 077 34 831 55 658 1 948 3 188 22 919 38 330 45 572 86 393 13 593 25 691 824 1 516 5 079 9 586 Meat 78 704 89 712 17 064 20 119 872 1 079 6 295 8 241 Sugar 33 024 22 993 13 892 11 904 1 755 1 320 7 598 4 782 Distribution of Low-Income and Lower-Middle-Income Countries according to their Current Account Position and the Estimated Increase in Cereals Import Bill Current account balance (% of GDP) Averages (2004-2007) Very Large deficit Estimated Change in Cereals Import Bill(% of GDP): Large deficit 5-10% >10% Moderate Deficit Surplus 0-5% Total Number of Countries Number of Countries <1% 5 6 20 22 53 1-2% 4 8 3 4 19 2-3% 2 1 2 2 7 >3% 2 2 3 0 7 Total Countries 13 17 28 28 86 Average Change in the Cereals Import Bill (% of GDP): 1.5% 2.2% 1.1% 0.4% 1.1% Summary of changes in domestic prices of main basic food commodities observed in 45 developing countries Commodities Proportion of 45 reporting countries indicating increases in consumer prices of 0-75% Proportion of 45 countries indicating decreases in consumer prices 01/2006 01/2007 01/2008 01/2006 01/2007 01/2008 to to to to to to 01/2007 01/2008 03/2008 01/2007 01/2008 03/2008 67 72 65 27 15 29 57 69 57 36 18 40 60 71 52 26 16 37 43 65 52 39 28 42 Rice Wheat Maize Root crops Vegetable oils 72 75 63 23 Pulses 67 59 70 20 Milk 70 90 49 26 Meat 69 76 49 29 Eggs 58 70 49 33 Fish 62 62 43 26 Source: Survey of countries where FAO has a representative 2 32 3 17 25 28 24 23 46 46 43 51 Proportion of Net Staple Food Seller Households (percent) Share of Households b Urban Rural All Bangladesh, 2000 3.3 18.9 15.7 Pakistan 2001 2.8 27.5 20.3 Vietnam, 1998 7.1 50.6 40.1 Guatemala, 2000 3.5 15.2 10.1 Ghana, 1998 13.8 43.5 32.6 Malawi, 2004 7.8 12.4 11.8 Madagascar, 2001 14.4 59.2 50.8 Ethiopia, 2000 c 6.3 27.3 23.1 Zambia, 1998 c 2.8 29.6 19.1 Cambodia, 1999 c 15.1 43.8 39.6 Bolivia, 2002 c 1.2 24.6 10.0 Peru, 2003 c 2.9 15.5 6.7 Max 15.1 59.2 50.8 Min. 1.2 12.4 6.7 Unweighted average 6.8 30.7 23.3 Structural features that are important in an impact and policy analysis context – – – – – backward technologies hence low productivity poor infrastructural endowments imperfect price transmission wide marketing margins inadequate production of tradables and low substitutability between tradables and domestically produced goods – Need framework to capture these features in an analysis Global food demand: growth is slowing and shifting composition • Population growth slowing • Income growth helps offset slower population growth • Products more sensitive to income growth growing more rapidly • Consumer preferences also shifting • Greatest demand growth in developing countries, particularly Asia. World Oceania Developed North America Latin America and Carabbean Europe Asia and Pacific Africa Slow down population growth 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 1998 - 2007 2008 - 2017 0.5 0.0 0 Russia EU15 USA Japan Korea Australia Brazil China India Vietnam Thailand Philippines Malaysia Indonesia Lower GDP Growth expected to grow fast in Asia 12 10 8 6 4 2 2005-2007 2008-2011 2008-2017 World demand growth slows: income sensitive products grow most Average annual growth 7.0% 6.0% 5.0% 4.0% 1998-2007 2008-2017 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% -1.0% ic R e y ls at at at ns r i e i e t e o l a m m u r m e l e W ig G b Po ne n a P i i e t v v e rs o g O a e B o V C at e h Growth in food demand in 2008-17 much higher in developing countries Annual average growth 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% -1.0% at ice ains eat eat eat ltry ese tter der der eds oils eal oils e h R r m m m ou he u ow ow lse le ilm le W e G vine vine Pig P C Bilk p lk P Oi etab O etab s i ar Bo O m eg eg M o e V V C l ho Skim W Developed Developing Supply: Moderate rate of growth • Real prices firmness continue over medium term – Moderate level of technical progress (crop yield growth continues, livestock revolution) – Further trade liberalization unlikely to reverse the price trend • Competition in export-supply is increasing – Low cost, low policy support countries increase supply most – South America, especially Brazil has great potential • Uncertain: energy prices, demand for biofuel In the next ten years trade will continue to grow faster than production… Annual average growth % 3.0% 2.0% Production Trade 1.0% 0.0% Wheat Rice Coarse Grains Meat, Total Oilseeds Nominal commodity prices have risen to record highs and will likely stay high 1200 1000 800 600 400 200 19 85 19 89 19 93 19 97 20 01 20 05 20 09 20 13 20 17 0 Wheat Rice Maize Oilseed Veg Oil Oilmeal Real international prices: expected to decline (2005-07 average=1) 1.6 1.4 Wheat Rice Sugar Beef Veg. Oil Dairy 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 2016 2013 2010 2007 2004 2001 1998 1995 0.0 Cereal commodity prices in long term perspective (current prices) Cereal commodity prices in long term perspective (real prices) Volatility matters for developing countries because of increasing exposure. Medium term OECD-FAO projections of agricultural production and trade LDC Countries (Base 1999-2001 =1) Medium term OECD-FAO projections of agricultural production and trade for other developing countries (nonLDC, non-BRIC) (Base 1999-2001 =1) Net grain imports other than rice have increased in Asia and Pacific 50 40 Wheat Rice Coarse Grains 20 10 0 -10 2016 2013 2010 2007 2004 2001 1998 1995 1992 1989 -20 1986 million MT 30 Net imports of basic foods to grow over 3.6 % annually in LDCs $US billion (at 2005 prices) 1 2 0 Net imports by commodity 1 0 0 Dairy products Meat Oilseeds vegetable Oil Coarse Grains Rice Wheat Total Net Imports 8 0 6 0 4 0 2 0 0 1995 -20 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 In summary, over the next ten years…. • Global demand growth will slow. Per capita consumption continues to increase, with more growth in higher valued products. • Supply potential continues to meet demand growth, at prices that decline in real terms • Excess supply growth is coming more from low cost suppliers. • Trade continues to grow, with developing country and least developed countries balance of trade in basic foods deteriorating. • Asian economies becoming larger net importers of food products. • Increased potential for inter-Asia and Pacific Trade The income terms of trade for agriculture have evolved differently for developing and developed countries. 9 200 8 180 LDCs Industrialized countries 160 7 140 $US Bil - LDCs 6 120 5 100 4 80 3 60 Other developing countries 2 40 1 20 0 0 1961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 $US Bil Other developing and Industrialized Income terms of trade for agriculture Productivity growth has been different in developed and developing countries: Cereals Cereals - weighted average yields: 1985 - 2004 4 .5 Dev'ed 4 .0 LDCs ODCs 3 .5 3 .0 2 .5 2 .0 1.5 1.0 0 .5 0 .0 19 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2000 2005 Productivity growth has been different in developed and developing countries: Oilcrops Oilcrops - weighted average yields: 1985 - 2004 0 .7 Dev'ed LDCs 0 .6 ODCs 0 .5 0 .4 0 .3 0 .2 0 .1 0 .0 19 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2000 2005 Productivity growth has been different in developed and developing countries: Fiber crops Fiber crops - weighted average yields: 1985 - 2004 1.0 Dev'ed LDCs 0 .9 ODCs 0 .8 0 .7 0 .6 0 .5 0 .4 19 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2000 2005 Productivity growth has been different in developed and developing countries: Fruits Fruits - weighted average yields: 1985 - 2004 14 .0 Dev'ed 13 .0 LDCs ODCs 12 .0 11.0 10 .0 9 .0 8 .0 7.0 6 .0 5.0 4 .0 19 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2000 2005 Productivity growth has been different in developed and developing countries: Vegetables Vegetables - weighted average yields: 1985 -2004 2004 2 5.0 Dev'ed LDCs ODCs 2 0 .0 15.0 10 .0 5.0 19 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2000 2005 Pattern of trade in all agricultural products. Export shares to various destinations (2001) USA USA BRAZIL EU25 CHI-IND ROECD LDCs ODCs ROW 0.0 8.5 3.1 11.5 29.4 6.5 15.8 5.0 BRAZIL 0.3 0.0 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.7 4.8 0.4 EU25 13.8 49.1 76.7 19.9 11.5 50.5 30.4 42.7 CHI-IND ROECD 8.0 11.1 1.0 2.0 11.3 7.9 7.3 2.7 45.0 11.4 4.6 25.6 17.0 5.8 11.5 5.5 LDCs 1.7 0.3 1.2 3.8 2.5 6.6 1.4 1.7 ODCs 29.2 16.1 8.9 32.3 27.3 18.5 25.4 17.5 ROW 2.1 3.6 4.2 4.5 0.9 3.5 3.5 24.5 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Total exports (million $) 29982.8 7042.1 44867.5 9894.7 24509.5 7954.8 37189.1 6933.7 Pattern of trade in all agricultural products. Import shares from various sources (2001) USA USA BRAZIL EU25 CHI-IND ROECD LDCs ODCs ROW TOTAL Total imports (million $) BRAZIL EU25 CHI-IND ROECD LDCs ODCs ROW 0.0 3.5 8.3 6.7 42.2 3.0 34.3 2.0 100.0 3.7 0.0 4.5 1.4 2.0 2.7 84.3 1.3 100.0 6.4 5.3 52.9 3.0 4.3 6.2 17.4 4.6 100.0 23.6 7.8 4.6 1.9 27.3 6.2 26.8 1.8 100.0 47.8 2.8 7.3 9.0 14.8 1.6 15.2 1.3 100.0 15.7 0.6 17.1 11.6 18.8 16.2 16.4 3.6 100.0 24.4 3.2 11.1 8.9 18.6 4.1 26.3 3.4 100.0 9.6 3.8 27.8 6.7 3.2 4.1 19.6 25.4 100.0 17080.6 2097.1 65074.0 10121.0 28182.0 3233.2 35880.8 6705.5 Structure of agricultural exports of LDCs by product and destinations (2001) USA Cereals and rice Oilseeds Vegetable oils Fruits and vegetables Sugar Plant based fibers Animals and meat Dairy products Beverages and tobacco Other primary products Other food products Total 5.6 3.7 5.8 1.1 7.5 0.1 5.3 2.8 9.6 9.8 6.7 6.6 BRAZIL EU25 0.2 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.1 3.3 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.1 0.5 15.6 24.7 53.4 56.4 70.8 28.1 30.7 26.2 24.3 57.8 63.0 53.6 CHIIND 1.2 0.5 0.2 28.2 1.2 14.5 6.1 0.8 1.3 0.9 1.3 5.6 ROECD 5.3 24.5 4.1 2.3 1.2 3.1 4.2 3.1 7.6 6.4 9.1 6.4 LDCs 50.2 2.9 32.3 3.4 15.5 7.8 17.2 50.7 43.6 5.9 9.2 9.3 ODCs 15.6 41.8 3.8 8.1 3.5 40.6 34.9 15.6 11.6 14.1 8.9 15.2 ROW 6.2 1.9 0.2 0.5 0.1 2.5 1.5 0.6 1.8 4.6 1.8 2.8 Value of Share of TOTAL exports ($ total million) exports 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 218.8 284.9 163.9 1408.3 474.5 1086.9 403.5 35.9 216.3 4721.0 3099.3 12113.3 1.8 2.4 1.4 11.6 3.9 9.0 3.3 0.3 1.8 39.0 25.6 100.0 Protection in agricultural products is high in both developed and developing countries (ad valorem tariff equivalent of country in column for agricultural products imported from country in row in 2001) USA USA BRAZIL EU25 CHI-IND ROECD LDCs ODCs ROW 0.0 5.6 1.8 1.1 0.2 2.5 1.4 6.3 BRAZIL 5.9 0.0 7.3 8.7 5.5 10.1 1.5 10.3 EU25 5.1 3.5 0.9 12.7 3.2 3.0 12.3 2.9 CHI-IND 62.2 95.8 22.1 20.0 20.3 26.7 53.4 14.6 ROECD 36.3 99.3 16.3 86.8 32.1 32.3 20.1 10.0 LDCs 7.3 8.5 9.5 11.8 8.2 8.7 10.3 3.0 ODCs 8.9 9.8 12.8 6.8 5.5 6.3 9.1 16.3 ROW 11.1 29.7 16.3 7.9 11.2 5.9 16.7 4.5 Considerable binding overhang in agricultural tariffs exists for both developed and developing countries (2000-2002) Countries Industrial countries European Union Japan United States All developing countries High income: non OECD Upper middle income Lower middle income Low income World Value of imports Weighted average Million Applied US % Dollars 143,669 14.1 49,381 17.4 31,556 20.9 41,304 5 87,896 24.4 13,996 61.8 23,209 23.1 36,091 14.4 14,600 15.5 231,564 18 Binding Lines overhang bound at zero Bound % of % % bound rate 24.9 43.4 29.0 21.3 18.3 25.2 51.6 59.5 29.2 6.6 24.2 28.5 60 59.3 1.2 79.6 22.4 1.1 54.1 57.3 2.8 41.8 65.6 1.2 95.6 83.8 0.3 38.2 52.9 3.6 OECD support falling slowly in real terms 400 $US billion 350 Real Producer Support Estimate 300 250 Nominal PSE 200 Source: OECD, FAO calculation 20 04 20 02 20 00 19 98 19 96 19 94 19 92 19 90 19 88 19 86 150 SPS notifications to WTO reflect increasing standards affecting trade 1200 1000 Annual notifications to WTO SPS Committee 800 600 400 200 0 1995 Source: WTO 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 What determines long term commodity prices? • Cost of production of marginal producer • Marginal producers still in developing countries using labour intensive technology with labour paid subsistence wages • Supply of agricultural commodities highly elastic at low wages • Demand for agricultural commodities quite inelastic • Opposite case for non-agriculture • Implication: Differential productivity gains can alter terms of trade between agriculture and non-agriculture How do productivity gains affect agriculture and non-agriculture? • Productivity affects agriculture differently than non-agriculture P P a a p p’ d S’ S p c S S’ p’ b b D D Q Q Panel A. Agricultural Commodity Sector Panel B. Non-agricultural sector Declining terms of trade for agricultural commodities due to faster rates of total factor productivity growth for agricultural than non-agricultural products • Rate of growth of TFP has been faster in agriculture than in nonagriculture • Between 1967-92 the average annual growth rate of TFP in manufacturing in developing countries varied between 0.62 and 0.92 percent. In developed countries the range was between 1.91 and 3.29. • In agriculture the average rate of growth of TFP in developing countries ranged between 1.76 and 2.62 percent, while for developed countries the range was between 3.35 and 3.46 percent. • For low-income developing countries, the average rate of TFP growth in agriculture was between 1.44 to 1.99, while in manufacturing it was between 0.22 to 0.93 percent. • The rate of growth of TFP in agriculture seems to be higher than that of manufacturing. • “Globalization” of agricultural research, has contributed to faster TFP growth in agriculture, • Incidence of productivity advances largely on consumers (through lower prices) and little to producers. Annual TFP growth in agriculture does not appear to have slowed down for the world. Hence most likely reason for real price leveling must be lower inputs and faster demand growth Developing countries Developed countries USSR & Eastern Europe World Source: Fuglie, 2008 1970–1979 1980–1989 1990–1999 2000–2006 0.55 1.67 2.31 2.08 1.62 1.48 2.25 1.76 -0.46 0.27 1.59 2.10 0.60 0.94 1.60 1.55 Agricultural productivity developments for the world Source: Fuglie (2008) Average annual growth rate by period (%) 1970–1989 1990–2006 Output index Input index TFP index Output per worker Output per hectare 2.24 2.06 1.36 0.50 0.87 1.56 1.25 1.51 1.96 1.95 Grain yield (t/ha) 2.29 1.35 Issues concerning secular declines in prices • Agricultural trade liberalization by developed countries may not increase export earnings by LDCs by much. Most benefits to more developed among developing countries • Attempts to improve market balance through producer-only agreements on production and export control difficult to implement • Commodity demand promotion can work if there is commitment and funds • Diversification a possible solution Constraints to diversification • Horizontal diversification the only long-run solution to market imbalance? • Product differentiation • Vertical diversification into processed forms to capture value-added – trade in processed forms growing fastest, but developing country participation limited • Constraints of tariff escalation, market barriers to entry and supply conditions Agriculture in LDCs has remained largely underdeveloped, despite its importance • Agricultural is the backbone of the LDCs • Accounts for between 30-60% of GDP and employs as much as 70% of labour force • Yet, after growing at 2.8% in the 1990s, virtually no increase in output or even a slight decline in 2000-05. More than half of the yield growth has been due to area expansion. • Per caput staple food production has stagnated • As a result, and not being able to import foods as required, between 1995-97 and 2002-04 the proportion of undernourished increased from 34% to 41%, and absolute number undernourished increased from 116 to 169 million. • A strong and vibrant food and agricultural system should form a primary pillar in the strategy of overall economic growth and development. Can agricultural growth lead to growth and poverty reduction in LDCs? • Most of the LDCs have large rural and agriculture based sectors. Cannot have fast overall growth without growth in agriculture • Most late developing countries faster growth episodes has been spurred by increased agricultural growth (recent successes China, India, Indonesia, Vietnam). • Agricultural growth has been shown to be more conducive to poverty reduction than nonagricultural growth • LDCs have the resource potential (land, labour) to expand agriculture. In about half of the LDCs the land in agricultural use is less than 50% of the potentially arable land. LDCs continue to be commodity dependent 1982/84 1992/94 Percent 2002/04 LDC avg share of agriculture in total exports of goods and services 41.6 27.2 22.5 LDC avg share of 4 most important commodities in agricultural exports 72.8 77.4 76.2 LDC avg share of 4 most important commodities in merchandise exports 37.4 31.9 23.8 LDC avg share of 4 most important commodities in merchandise and service exports 33.7 23.6 19.1 Despite the commodity dependence of LDCs, the export performance of agriculture has been weak World All developing LDCs Agricultural exports relative to agricult. GDP 2002-4 Percent 37.6 20.8 13.8 Main solution consistent with poverty alleviation: Agricultural commodity labour productivity must be improved in LDCs • • • • Increase of wages through general development Technological improvement at the farm level Increase farm size? Increase farmer assets (education, own and borrowed capital) • Improve non-farm assets (infrastructure) • Better producer organizations Producer support estimates