BEMM108 Individual assignment Growth Businesses are different QIAN CHENG 630013092 Table of contents Introduction ............................................................................................................ 3 Definition ................................................................................................................ 3 Entrepreneurship and Growth Business ................................................................. 3 Discussion about Entrepreneurship ........................................................................ 4 Conclusion ............................................................................................................... 6 Reference ................................................................................................................ 8 Introduction In recent years there is an increasing interest of policy makers around the world to support and foster fast growth enterprises including companies named “gazelles” or “gorillas” in terms of its size and age. These businesses are often viewed as important driving power of economic growth, employment rate and even social well-being (Stefan, 2011). However, some firms grow but others do not, which still remains debated (Candida, Dennis, Robert, 2009) and leads to the argument that it is a dangerous assumption that all growth businesses can be a bullet that will create jobs, generate innovation and conduct sorts of economic benefits (Scott, 2009). This essay will first present the definition of high-growth business and then dialectically demonstrate the role of the defined growth business by mainly discussing issues of entrepreneurial activity before the final conclusion. Definition Perhaps the simplest method to distinguish high-growth business from other firm is to define it according to several predetermined threshold and those who are satisfied with these threshold can be seen as growth business (Ahmad, Petersen, 2007). Traditionally, high-growth business often refers to the concept of gazelle firm which is defined as “All enterprises up to five years old with average annualized growth greater than twenty percent per annum over a three-year period, and with ten or more employees at the beginning of the observation period.” by OECD (2007) (Audretsch, 2012). On the other hand, another two basic attributes are often used to define a high-growth business: a strong growth of size of its number of employees and this growth of size should happen over an intensive period (OECD, 2010). Both employment and turnover should be taken into account and thus high-growth business is defined by the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development as “all enterprises with average annualized growth greater than 20% per annum, over a three year period, and with ten or more employees at the beginning of the observation period. Growth is thus measured by the number of employees and by turnover.” The definitions from OECD will be adapted as the standard in this essay. Entrepreneurship and Growth Business By traditional view, gazelles, as a subset of high-growth business, may often be affiliated with entrepreneurial activity (Stefan, 2011) which is one of the central factors in economic development (David, 2003). Entrepreneurs not only manage to identify and grab profitable opportunities, they also take risks in order to achieve their goals (OECD, 2002). Countries with constant entrepreneurial activities are more likely to generate new products and services by which older ones are replaced (OECD, 2002). The process obviously concerns all economic activity and is not only related to high-technology areas or particular industry. At the same time, entrepreneurship can characterize the behaviors of both new and well operated firm as well as small and large business. Due to the breadth of the concept of entrepreneurship, there is no accurate measurement of entrepreneurship. However, in practice, new companies and innovation are two main features of entrepreneurship (OECD, 2002). According to the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship (Audretsch, Keilbach and Lehmann, 2006, Acs, Braunerhjelm, Audretsch and Carlsson, 2009; Audretsch and Keilbach, 2007), high growth firms are often expected to be related to the firm-oriented characteristics of size and age and growth firms may particularly expected to be young and small companies (Audretsch, 2012). The relationship between entrepreneurship and firm growth can be depicted as figure 1. In this essay, new and young venture will be seen as one of the main components of growth business and dialectically discussed. Figure 1 Discussion about Entrepreneurship It is generally believed that entrepreneurship is beneficial for economic growth and national development (Wim, 2013). There are various statements in the empirical literature presenting the relationship between entrepreneurship and economic growth and national development (Carree; Thurik, 2002). It is reported by OECD (2002) that growth firms which are measured by employment expansion rates and are often related to new and young firms account for a large portion of jobs created and play as a key role in economic growth. There exist a general claim of entrepreneurship that new and young business leads to economic growth and overall development (Maria, 2008). At the same time, program of supporting entrepreneurship has become a core part of economic strategies in many countries (Heather; Mark, 2011). Recent studies present that the contribution of the entrepreneurial activity to employment rate and GDP is increasing (Audretsch & Thurik, 2001; Birch, 1987; Kumar & Liu, 2005). Audretsch and Thurik (2001) argue that the entrepreneurial sector plays a more crucial role in national development and smaller and more flexible entrepreneurial firms become more important in an increasingly knowledge-based economy (Maria, 2008). Gilbert, McDougall, and Audretsch (2006) suggest that, in the last 20 years, smaller and more dynamic businesses have been seen as key drivers of development, and a set of national policies are designed to promote entrepreneurial activity everywhere (Maria, 2008). Figure2 shows a conceptual model developed by Global Entrepreneurship Monitor demonstrating the systematic relationship between entrepreneurial activity and national economic growth (Amit, 2012). Figure 2 New firms not only bring macro-economic benefits but also micro-economic benefits. It is suggested that new startups not only constitute a large part of high-growth business but also contribute a lot to employment rate (Audretsch, 2012). There is also evidence that new business create more new job than that of average firms, which leads to its important role in an economy (Mitusch; Shimke, 2011). Studies by Fritsch and Mueller (2004) using data for Germany, and Mueller, van Stel and Storey (2008) with longitudinal data from the Netherlands, and Acs and Mueller (2008) utilizing longitudinal data for the United States all show significant evidence that new and young companies considerably contribute to the growth of employment (Audretsch, 2012). Their studies also observe the impact of the new business on employment over a period of time after the establishment of the firm. As Figure 3 shows, the employment impact is high in the first year of the foundation of firm and then decreases in following years (Audretsch, 2012). Figure 3 As supporting entrepreneurship becomes one of the core strategies for many countries in order to make contribution to economic growth, there are also many studies concern that policy maker believe in a dangerous myth (Scott, 2009) and evidence on whether entrepreneurship contributes to economic growth is not obvious (Wim, 2013). This belief is flawed since it is not always the reality that all entrepreneurial business can generate job, enhance economic growth and boost innovation. It is found that owner of new firm do less on R&D and their contribution to productivity growth is relatively low (Wim, 2013). Wim (2013) also argue that majority of entrepreneurs would earn more than wage employees, and while entrepreneurs bring more job creations compared to non-entrepreneurs, the quality of jobs they offered is often low. Therefore not all entrepreneurial activities drive economic development, and not all entrepreneurs are innovative (Shane, Stam and Wennberg, 2009). Getting economic growth and new jobs from entrepreneurial activity is not a number game but to chase for high quality and high growth, namely not every new and young firm is growth business (Scott, 2009). Scott Shane (2009) argues that encouraging entrepreneurship may not be a good policy since new venture is not always the source of economic growth and job creation. According to the research of Haltiwanger, Lane, and Speltzer (1999), it is observed that company’s productivity often increases with firm age, which means that most of new firms make worse use of resources than that of existing larger firm and economic benefits are achieved more from expansion of large firms than that of new and small businesses. New firms contribute to a minority of gross and net new employment. In fact, in order to make the assumption that 50 percent of net new jobs are generated by new businesses all firms that are nine years old or less have to be considered as ‘‘new’’ business (Scott, 2009). Anyone knows that nine-year-olds are not ‘‘new’’. In Daniel and Ross’s view (2014), it is wrong, at least misleading, by saying that “Small business is the backbone of our economy” (Obama, 2010) or” New businesses are the lifeblood of a healthy… economy” (Cameron, 2013) because it is more wise to bet on high-growth firms than on new and young business which is often seen as a subset of all high-growth firms. Conclusion By definition, growth business should take “all enterprises with average annualized growth greater than 20% per annum, over a three year period, and with ten or more employees at the beginning of the observation period. Growth is thus measured by the number of employees and by turnover ” into account and new and young firms count little among all growth firms. In reality, it is a small minority of new and young businesses that grow significantly and create the majority of economic and other benefits. Entrepreneurial business as kind of growth business is often associated with employment, economic development and innovation. However, when it comes to relationship between entrepreneurship and employment, the results are often different (Audretsch, 2012). In fact, those high-growth firms contribute to most of the employment rate growth are often larger and more mature and they tend not to be in any particular industry or sector. Growth represents a phase during the life of an enterprise and it is not a characteristic of a specific subset of firms. Studies of Davidsson, Steffens and Fitzsimmons (2006) suggest that growth may not be a good sign of enterprise development. Another fact is that in any country, high-growth businesses represent a minority of the overall number of enterprises. As is shown in the figure 3 which is the data collected by OECD, these firms represent on average 3-6% and 8-12% of all firm population when growth is measured by employment (Figure 3.1) and turnover respectively (Figure 3.2). The number of new and young growth business is also very small in all countries. The gazelles represent on average less than 1% and 2% by employment and turnover respectively of the total population (Figure 3.3, Figure 3.4), and less than 1/5 of high-growth enterprises. Nevertheless, the main trends of high-growth business also apply to new firms namely gazelles. It is reported by OECD (2008) that high growth in young manufacturing firms is more likely to occur in terms of turnover and in services industry high growth in new firms happens in terms of both employment and turnover. Figure 3.1 Figure 3.2 Figure 3.3 Figure 3.4 Reference BERNADETTE M. CROMPTON, KOSMAS X. SMYRNIOS & RUI BI 2012. Measuring the influence of business coaching on fast-growth firms. Small Enterprise Research, 19, 16-31. BENZ, M. 2009. Entrepreneurship as a non-profit-seeking activity. The International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 5, 23-44. BOSO, N., STORY, V. M. & CADOGAN, J. W. 2013. Entrepreneurial orientation, market orientation, network ties, and performance: Study of entrepreneurial firms in a developing economy. Journal of Business Venturing, 28, 708-727. BRUSH, C. G., CERU, D. J. & BLACKBURN, R. 2009. Pathways to entrepreneurial growth: The influence of management, marketing, and money. Business Horizons, 52, 481-491. BRUTON, G. D., AHLSTROM, D. & LI, H.-L. 2010. Institutional Theory and Entrepreneurship: Where Are We Now and Where Do We Need to Move in the Future? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34, 421-440. CARDON, M. S., FOO, M. D., SHEPHERD, D. & WIKLUND, J. 2012. Exploring the Heart: Entrepreneurial Emotion Is a Hot Topic. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36, 1-10. DELMAR, F. D. R., DAVIDSSON, P. & GARTNER, W. B. 2003. Arriving at the high-growth firm. Journal of Business Venturing, 18, 189-216. LEITCH, C., HILL, F. & NEERGAARD, H. 2010. Entrepreneurial and Business Growth and the Quest for a "Comprehensive Theory": Tilting at Windmills? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34, 249-260. MINNITI, M. 2008. The Role of Government Policy on Entrepreneurial Activity: Productive, Unproductive, or Destructive? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32, 779-790. MORRIS, M. H., KURATKO, D. F., SCHINDEHUTTE, M. & SPIVACK, A. J. 2012. Framing the Entrepreneurial Experience. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36, 11-40. O'CONNOR, A. 2013. A conceptual framework for entrepreneurship education policy: Meeting government and economic purposes. Journal of Business Venturing, 28, 546-563. SHANE, S. 2009. Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business Economics, 33, 141-149. STEPHENS, H. M. & PARTRIDGE, M. D. 2011. Do Entrepreneurs Enhance Economic Growth in Lagging DAVID B. AUDRETSCH. 2012. Determinants of High-Growth Entrepreneurship. OECD. DAVID A. HARPER. 2003. Foundations of Entrepreneurship and Economic Development. New York: Routledge. 267 pp. K. MITUSCH., A. SCHIMKE. 2011. Gazelles-High-Growth Companies-Final report. EUROPE INNOVA OECD. 2010. High-Growth Enterprises: What Governments Can Do to Make a Difference. OECD Studies on SMEs and Entrepreneurship. OECD Publishing. RHETT MORRIS. 2011. 2011 High-Impact Entrepreneurship Global Report. Center for High-Impact Entrepreneurship at Endeavor. M.A. CARREE. & A.R. THURIK. 2002. The Impact of Entrepreneurship on Economic Growth. International Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research. STEFAN LILISCHKIS. BONN. 2011. Policies in support of high-growth innovative SMEs. An INNO-Grips Policy Brief by empirica Communication and Technology Research. European Commission. WIM NAUDÉ. 2013. Entrepreneurship and Economic Development: Theory, Evidence and Policy. IZA. 7507. OECD. 2002. High-Growth SMEs and Employment.