Thursday, Sept. 4, 2014
• Last class
Farm and food problems: the development paradox and structural transformation
• Today
Mouths to feed, farmers to employ: population growth and demographic transition
• Next week: farm households’ response
Slide 1
Drivers of Change:
Population growth and economic transformation
• Last class:
– broad diversity of policy problems and policy actions, but also
– strong regularities (“stylized facts”):
– the development paradox, from taxing to subsidizing farmers
– the structural transformation, from farm to nonfarm activity
• Today:
– a key driver (from outside, exogenous to agriculture) is demography:
– the demographic transition
– from large to small families
– high to low death rates and birth rates
– high to low fraction of people who are children
…and other corresponding changes
Slide 2
A pattern of steadily increasing population growth, followed by a period of slowing population growth.
Generally indicated as an S-shaped curve for population through time.
Slide 3
Three stages of population growth
1.
High growth potential
2.
Transitional growth
3.
Incipient decline we might add…
4. Sustained decline?
?
1 2 3 4
Slide 4
1. High growth potential
Pre-industrial
Birth rate high (25-40/1000)
Death rate high
Life expectancy short
Population growth low but positive
Widespread misery
Slide 5
2. Transitional growth
Early industrial
Birth rate remains high (or rises!)
Death rate low and falling
Life expectancy rises
Population growth “explosive”
Mortality declines before fertility due to better health, nutrition, and sanitation
Slide 6
3. Incipient decline
Industrial
Birth rate drops due to desires to limit family size
Death rate low and stable
Life expectancy high
Population grows until birth rate = death rate
Characterized by higher levels of wealth and reduced need for large families for labor or insurance.
Also driven by female empowerment, female education and female labor market participation.
Slide 7
A Stylized Model* of Demographic Transition
The gap between birth and death rates is the population’s “rate of natural increase”
( ≈ population growth)
* In what sense is this a model?
Slide 8
An actual demographic transition
Sweden’s population growth rate peaked at about 1.5% per year, in the late 19 th century
Slide 9
A different demographic transition
Mauritius’ peak pop. growth rate was over 3%/year, twice that of Sweden, because its death rate fell so fast…
Slide 10
A third kind of transition
Mexico’s peak population growth was even faster, because its birth rate fell slowly…
Slide 11
Message: Birth rates > death rates, country is still in stage 2 of the demographic transition
Slide 12
Birth and death rates depend in part on age structure and “population momentum”
Slide 13
A very young age structure: the population pyramid for Nigeria
1980, 2000, 2020
Reprinted from www.census.gov/ipc/www/idb.
Slide 14
A later stage of demographic transition: population pyramids for Indonesia
1980, 2000, 2020
Reprinted from www.census.gov/ipc/www/idb.
Indonesia has a much more “mature” population pyramid than Nigeria
Slide 15
The final stage of demographic transition: population pyramids for the United States
1980, 2000, 2020
Reprinted from www.census.gov/ipc/www/idb.
The population “ages”, with continued echoes of the post-WWII baby boom
Slide 16
The lower-income regions have had a later
(and much faster!) demographic transition
Slide 17
Africa’s pop. growth has been of unprecedented speed and duration, but is now slowing
Slide 18
Africa’s child dependency has been similarly unprecedented, and is now improving
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
E. Asia S. Asia Sub-Sah. Africa Whole World
Source: UN Population Division, World Population Prospects:
The 2000 Revision (http://esa.un.org/unpp)
Slide 19
Explaining the demographic transition
What can account for the patterns we’ve seen, including especially the late and rapid demographic growth and child dependency in poor regions?
Will look first at mortality decline, then fertility decline…
Slide 20
Explaining the mortality decline (UK data)
General improvements in: overall well-being education female literacy diet, water and sanitation
Not, medical breakthroughs…!
Slide 21
Explaining the mortality decline (US data)
Slide 22
The age structure of mortality decline
Slide 23
The HIV/AIDS tragedy
Slide 24
Explaining the fertility decline: social policies
Source: K. Sundstrom. “Can governments influence population growth?”
OECD Observer, December 2001, p. 35.
Slide 25
Explaining the fertility decline: infant mortality
The fertility decline lags substantially the drop in IM
Slide 26
Conclusions on population growth and the demographic transition
• Much popular understanding about population growth turns out to be wrong.
• In fact, over time and across countries:
– population growth starts with a fall in child mortality, which raises population growth because a fertility decline happens later
– the temporary burst of population growth involves a rise and then fall in the fraction of people who are children
– these changes are similar in all countries, but in today’s poor countries they occurred later and faster, with larger magnitude over shorter time period than occurred historically elsewhere
• How does demographic transition affect agriculture?
Slide 27
What happens to the number of farmers?
What happens to the number of farmers?
• Initially, farmers are much poorer than non-farmers
– less capital/worker, lower skills, less specialized this means agriculture is the “residual” employer…
(what is the opportunity cost of labor?)
The annual change in the number of farmers depends on: growth in the total population growth in nonfarm employment
Slide 29
Some arithmetic of structural transformation
If we divide the total workforce into farmers and nonfarmers:
L f
= L t
– L n
( L i
=no. of workers in sector i)
And solve for the growth rate of the number of farmers as a function of growth in total and non-farm employment, we see that size of the sectors matters a lot:
%
L f
= ( %
L t
– [ %
L n
• S n
]) / ( S f
) ( S i
=share of workers in i)
In poor countries, even if non-farm employment grows much faster than the total workforce, the number of farmers may still rise quickly:
Rate of growth in rural population, by relative size of the sector proportion of workers who are farmers (
S f
):
Country is poor but successful: nonfarm employment growth
( %
L twice rate of workforce growth
( %
n
)
=6%,
L t
) = 3%
3/4 2/3 half
+2.0% +1.5% 0.0%
Slide 30
The number of farmers rises then falls… until farmers’ incomes catch up to nonfarm earnings
The “textbook” picture of structural transformation within agriculture: farm numbers stabilized by off-farm income and rising profits per acre; latest census shows slight rise in no. of farms
Figure 5-3. Number and average size of farms in the United States, 1900-2002.
Slide 31
In very rich countries, the number of farmers does not keep falling to zero!
• In an economics model of occupational choice, farmers would move to nonfarm work if it offers higher incomes;
– recall the “Harris-Todaro” story…
• An equilibrium at which the number of farmers stays constant would offer equal farm and nonfarm earnings:
Wage off-farm
= Earnings on-farm
= Profits/acre x acres/hour
– Thus, you can have no change in the number of farmers
IF
• profits/acre or
• acres/hour rise fast enough to keep up with off-farm wages
Slide 32
In the world as a whole, the number of farmers has just peaked and will soon decline
Slide 33
Regions differ sharply in their population growth rates
Source: Calculated from FAOStat data (www.fao.org).
Slide 34
Cities are growing much faster than total population
Source: Calculated from FAOStat data (www.fao.org).
Slide 35
…but cities are still too small to absorb all population growth, especially in S. Asia and Africa
Source: Reprinted from W.A. Masters, 2005. “Paying for Prosperity: How and Why to Invest in
Agricultural R&D in Africa.” Journal of International Affairs 58(2): 35-64.
Slide 36
Conclusions on economic growth and structural transformation
As incomes grow…
(1) Farming declines as a fraction of the economy
• in favor of industry and services
• even within agriculture
(2) Farmers’ incomes at first decline relative to others
• but then farm incomes catch up…
• until farm incomes equal or pass non-farm incomes
(3) The number of farmers first rises and then falls
• speed depends on both population and income growth
• eventually the number of farmers stabilizes
• in the future, the number may even rise!
Slide 37
More conclusions…
• Demographic transition and structural transformation interact, causing a rise & then fall in the number of farmers
• Today’s developing countries have had very fast decline in death rates, leading to unprecedented speed of change;
• With small shares of the population in nonfarm employment, this led to unprecedented rural population growth and declines in land available per farmer.
• The rural effect is compounded by shift in age structure:
• first, more children/adult (the “demographic burden”),
• then, more child-bearing women (“population momentum”),
• then more working-age adults (the “demographic gift”)
• These are powerful drivers of change in agriculture and in agricultural policy, but occur slowly and are often ignored!
Slide 38