Consumption & Investment The Multiplier and the MPC Disposable Income (YD) What consumers have left over to spend or save once they have paid out their net taxes Net taxes = taxes paid – transfers received YD = Gross Income – Net Taxes With no government transfers or taxation, YD = Consumption + Savings Consumption and Saving Schedules Show the direct relationship between Disposable income, consumption, and savings As YD increases for a typical household, C and S both increase Disposable Income (YD ) Consumption (C) Savings (S) 0 40 -40 100 120 -20 200 200 0 300 280 20 400 360 40 500 440 60 Consumption Function A linear equation showing how an individual household’s consumer spending varies with the household’s current disposable income C = a + MPC x YD C = 40 + .80 x YD The constant $40 is referred to as the autonomous consumption because it does not change as YD changes The slope of the consumption function is .80 Autonomous Consumer Spending (a): the amount of money a household would spend if it had no disposable income Consumption Function C = 40 + .80 x YD Saving Function S = -40 + .20 x YD Marginal Propensity to Consume Marginal always means an incremental change caused by an external force Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC): the change in consumption caused by a change in disposable income MPC = ∆ consumer spending (C) ∆ disposable income (YD) Because we are looking at the part of each additional dollar that consumers will spend, the MPC is a number between 0 and 1 Marginal Propensity to Save The remainder (1 - MPC) is the Marginal Propensity to Save MPS: the fraction of an additional dollar of disposable income that is saved A change in savings caused by a change in disposable income MPS = 1-MPC * Note that MPC + MPS = 1 Multiplier in Recent History Not too long ago, the federal government enacted the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. This “stimulus package” of $787 billion was intended to spark job growth to reverse the worst recession since the Great Depression. How was this supposed to work? The short answer is that $1 of spending in one area of the economy multiplies into more than $1 of spending throughout the economy. The Spending Multiplier Class Example Ted is a chicken farmer in the local community. Suppose Ted decides to spend $1000 on some chicken coops at Anthony’s farm supply shop. This money now starts to be circulated around the economy. 1. Anthony now has $1000 from the sale and spends 80% ($800) on clothes at Marcia’s boutique. 2. Marcia now has $800 from the sale and spends 80% ($640) to fix her car at Pat’s garage. 3. Pat now has $640 from the sale and spends 80% ($512) at Dianna’s grocery store. 4. Dianna now has $512 from the sale and spends 80% ($409.60) with Catherine’s catering company. The Spending Multiplier Multiplier: the ratio of total change in Real GDP to the size of autonomous change in spending (the cause of the chain reaction) ∆Y -OR1 ∆AAS (1-MPC) Size of the multiplier depends on MPC Higher the MPC, the higher the multiplier! So based off of the previous example… M = 1__ M=5 (1-.80) The Tax Multiplier Taxes, foreign trade, etc. complicate the model Taxes on disposable income reduce the size of the spending multiplier Tax Multiplier = - MPC/(1-MPC) The tax multiplier is always negative Consumer Spending Consumer spending accounts for 2/3 of the US real GDP Let’s use our consumption function from the earlier schedule C = 40 + .80 x YD If YD increases from $200 to $300, C increases from $200 to $280. This is seen as movement upward along the fixed consumption function. What would cause C to increase, no matter the level of YD? There are several factors that will shift the consumption function upward or downward. Shifters of the Consumption Function Two 1. 2. factors will shift CF Change in Expectations about future disposable income – Expecting good times will shift CF up, expecting hard times will shift it down Changes in aggregate wealth – Those with the most savings (wealth) can afford to spend more…a rise in aggregate wealth will shift CF up, while a fall in aggregate wealth will shift it down Wealth is accumulated assets, and this is very different from disposable income. If you own a house, a car, share of stock or even a savings account, you have wealth. And this is what shifts of the aggregate consumption function look like! The Interest Rate and Investment Spending Firms analyze the benefits and costs in investment spending Expected return on the investment must be equivalent to the expected economic profit from the investment Return on Investment/Profit = (total revenue—total cost) investment cost The 1. 2. market interest rate is the cost of investment Interest rate is cost of borrowed funds Interest rate is also cost of investing your own funds (no borrowing), since it is income forgone Investment Demand Curve Investment demand curve shows the inverse relationship between interest rates and investment demand Expected Future Real GDP & Production Capacity on Investment Spending Various factors can increase spending at any interest rate Expected Future Real GDP Low or no expectation of sales growth results in minimal investment spending High expectation of sales growth results in need to expand production capacity Production Capacity If current capacity is higher than needed for current sales, growing capacity is a lesser concern. Inventories & Unplanned Investment spending Businesses maintain inventories to satisfy future sales Inventory investment – Value of total inventories in an economy over a period of time. This can be a negative number when inventories are reduced. If sales fall, businesses might end up with larger inventories than expected (unplanned inventory investment) Rising inventories signal economic slowdown Investment Spending Actual investment spending is equal to planned investment spending plus unplanned inventory investment. I= IPlanned + I Unplanned Planned Investment: Interest Rates, Expected Future real GDP, Production capacity Unplanned Inventory investment: when actual sales are less than businesses expected, leading to unplanned increases in inventories Sales higher than expectations result in negative unplanned inventory investment Sales lower than expectations result in positive unplanned inventory investment