FIN 30220: Macroeconomic Analysis Labor Markets Of the 317 million people that make up the US population, approximately 246 million are considered by the Bureau of Labor Statistics to be “eligible” to work. Eligible Civilian Population 249 Million Under 16 On Active Military US Population 320 Million Duty Non-Eligible Population 71 Million Inmates in Penal or Mental Institutions The US labor market is a very dynamic market. The 249 million Americans currently counted as part of the US eligible population are in a constant state of motion between three possible states Unemployment = 9M = 5.7% 157M Rate (UR) Employed 148 Million Not In Labor Force 92 Million Unemployed 9 Million Participation Rate (PR) = 157M = 63% 249M Employment Rate (ER) = 148M = 59% 249M UR = 1 - ER PR Source: Household Survey The Natural Rate, or NAIRU (Non Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment) refers to what’s “normal” in the labor market. 9 8 Cyclical Unemployment 7 6 5 4 3 2 “Natural Rate” 1 0 1990 1993 1996 2000 2003 If unemployment is at the “natural rate”, then the inflation rate should be stable. Note that the “Natural Rate” of unemployment is not zero! A healthy labor market should have some turnover as workers look for better jobs. 5% Frictional Unemployment: Workers in the process of finding a job 1.5% 0% Structural Unemployment: Workers whose skills are no longer needed due to industry evolution. These people generally require retraining A better measure of the labor market is simply the total number of people working 1200 140000 1000 800 120000 600 Total 100000 400 80000 200 60000 0 40000 -200 20000 -400 0 1980 -600 1984 Recession 1988 1992 Recession 1996 2000 2004 Recession Change From Previous Month 160000 What’s a “good” employment number? Labor Market US Population 300 Million Our population growth rate averages around 1% per year 250,000 per month 100,000 per month Every month, people retire, go back to school, etc. To maintain a constant unemployment rate, we need to create approximately 150,000 jobs per month!! The employment figures generally coincide with the unemployment rate, but not always Unemployment Rate 600 7 6 400 5 300 200 4 100 3 0 2000 -100 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2 -200 1 -300 -400 0 Unemployment Rate Change in Employment 500 Consider two economies. Both have a labor force equal to 100. In economy A, 10 people lose their jobs every month (but find a job the following month). In Economy B, 10 people get laid off every 3 months, but take three months to find work. A 10 January B 10 February 10 March 10 10 April 10 May 10 June July 10 At any point in time, both economies have identical unemployment rates of 10% Duration measures the average length of an unemployment spell. Economy A has a duration of 1 month. Economy B has a duration of 3 months. Suppose that we have the following data. Labor Force = 200M January February March April 3 Million 3.5 Million May June 24 Weeks 12 Weeks 2.5 Million 8 Weeks 3.5 Million 2.5 Million 8 Weeks 9M Unemployment Rate = = 4.5% 200M Average Duration = 3M 24 17.5M 3 Million + 12 Weeks 2.5 Million 8 Weeks 7 Million + 7.5 Million 17.5 Million 7M 7.5M 12 + 8 = 12.3 weeks 17.5M 17.5M Length of unemployment spells in the US However, average and median duration has been rising! Mean = 39 weeks Median = 22 weeks Production Functions measure the relationship between inputs and output Y F ( A, K , L) Labor Output Capital (Fixed in Short Run) Productivity (Exogenous) Typically the production function used is Cobb-Douglas Capital’s Share of Income 1 3 2 3 Y AK L Labor’s Share of Income Production in the short run – capital is fixed The Marginal Product of Labor (MPL) measures the change in production associated with a small change in employment Y MPL L As labor increases (given a fixed capital stock), labor productivity declines!! Y MPL=2 2 10 F ( A, K , L) MPL=10 L L' 1 1 L Production in the short run – capital is fixed F ( A' , K , L) or MPL=4 We also assume that the marginal product of labor is positively related to increases in either productivity and capital F ( A, K ' , L) Y F ( A, K , L) MPL=2 MPL=14 K' K A' A Y MPL L MPL=10 L L' L We assume that firms are perfectly competitive. They choose labor hours to maximize profits Y F ( A, K , L) Wage Rate Price of Capital pY Y wL pk K Price of Output Total Output Labor Costs Capital Costs (Fixed in Short Run) The best choice for labor can be found by taking looking at changes in both revenues and costs at the margin. pY MPL w A little rearranging gives us the following condition w MPL pY Real Wage Qualitatively, this tells us we would expect to see a strong positive correlation between productivity and wages Example: F ( A, K , L) Labor Hours Output MPL 1 40 2 52 12 3 62 10 4 70 8 5 76 6 6 80 4 w $40 pY $5 For the production function given above, at a real wage of 8, 4 hours of labor are hired w $40 8 pY $5 Labor demand records the hiring decision (# of hours) chosen by the firm at every real wage F ( A, K , L) Real Wage w p w 8 p L4 Labor Hours Output 1 40 2 52 12 3 62 10 4 70 8 5 76 6 6 80 4 w $40 pY $5 L Hours of Labor MPL w $40 8 pY $5 Altering the real wage (holding production values fixed) allows us to trace out the labor demand curve F ( A, K , L) Real Wage w p w 8 p w 6 p Labor Hours Output 1 40 2 52 12 3 62 10 4 70 8 5 76 6 6 80 4 l d ( A, K ) L 4 L* 5 * L Hours of Labor w $42 pY $7 MPL w $42 6 pY $7 Altering the production values (holding the real wage fixed) allows us to shift the labor demand curve F ( A' , K , L) Real Wage w p w 8 p Labor Hours Output 1 60 2 80 20 3 96 16 4 108 12 5 116 8 6 120 4 l d ( A' , K ) L* 4 L* 5 l d ( A, K ) L Hours of Labor w $40 pY $5 MPL w $40 8 pY $5 Households have utility functions that describe the relationship between choices and happiness U U (C ,1 L) Labor Hours Utility Time Endowment Consumption We only have a couple requirements for utility functions •Utility is increasing in consumption (i.e. we like to buy things!) •Utility is decreasing in labor (we don’t like to work) •Utility exhibits diminishing marginal utility (the more we have of anything, the less it is worth to us at the margin) Indifference curves show various combinations of consumption and leisure that provide the same level of utility More is always better! U (C ) U ( A) C C A U (C ,1 L) 25 B U (C ,1 L) 20 1 L The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) measures the amount of consumption you are willing to give up in order to acquire a little more leisure How much consumption do you require to give up one hour of leisure (i.e. work an extra hour)? C c * C (1 L) 1 L * MRS MU L MU c U (C ,1 L) 20 1 L Given the assumption of diminishing marginal utility, MRS varies predictably as consumption/leisure changes If you have a lot of consumption relative to leisure, then leisure is much more valuable than consumption - MRS is high! c If you have a lot of leisure relative to consumption, then leisure is much less valuable than consumption - MRS is low! MRS = 12 C * MRS = 2 U (C ,1 L) 20 C' 1 L* 1 L' 1 L Households take wages and prices as given. Further, house possess some non-labor income (i.e. asset income). Households maximize utility subject to an income constraint. max U (C ,1 L) c 0, L 0 subject to pC wL NLI Note that the choice for labor will determine the level of consumption possible. max U (C ,1 L) L 0 wL NLI where C p Suppose that the hourly wage is $10 and that consumption goods cost $2. Further, you have $20 of non-labor income. Assume you have 1 hour of time available. C L = 1: you work as much as you can 15 w slope 5 p 10 0 1 1 L L = 0: You don’t work at all Recall that maximizing anything requires equating costs and benefits at the margin C MU C MU L L How much is an extra unit of consumption worth to you? How much extra consumption will an extra hour of work buy you? (i.e. the real wage) How unhappy does working an extra hour make you?? A little rearranging…. w MU L MRS p MU C At the optimum choice for labor, the slope of the indifference curve is equal to the slope of the budget constraint. Consumption C w p w MRS p 15 Real Wage l s ( NLI 20) C 13 w 5 p 10 0 1 L .4 1 1 L L L .6 Hours of Leisure Hours of Labor Suppose the wage rate rises to $16 (non-labor income is still $20 and the price level is still $2). Does labor supply increase of decrease? c Substitution Effect: As the real wage increases, the price of leisure has increased relative to consumption – buy more consumption, less leisure. 18 C 16.4 w p Income Effect: As the real wage increases, your purchasing power goes up. Buy more of both goods (consumption and w leisure) p C 13.2 C 13 Real Wage Income Effect: Substitution Effect: 8 w 5 p 10 0 1 L .2 .4 .8 L .2 Hours of Leisure L .6 L L .8 Hours of Labor We typically assume that the substitution effect is dominant…a rise in the real wage increases hours of labor supplied. c 18 w p Real Wage C 16.4 l s ( NLI 20) w 8 p w 5 p C 13 10 0 1 L .2 .4 L .6 Hours of Leisure L L .8 Hours of Labor Suppose that the hourly wage is still $10 and that consumption goods cost $2. However, Non-labor income increases to $40. C 25 w p l s ( NLI 40) Real Wage l s ( NLI 20) C 22 15 w 5 p C 13 10 0 .4 .6 1 L L .4 Hours of Leisure L L .6 Hours of Labor An equilibrium in the labor market is defined as a real wage where labor supply equals labor demand (i.e. the labor market clears) w p l s (NLI ) w p Note: This equilibrium assumes fixed values for productivity (A), capital (K) and nonlabor income (NLI) * l d ( A, K ) L L* Note that once employment is known (capital is taken as fixed in the short run), output can be determined 1 Labor Markets 2 l s l d L* w p w p Production Function Y F A, K , L* Y l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* * l d ( A, K ) * L L L* L We need to make assumptions about the evolution of productivity. Let’s suppose that productivity evolves according to an autoregressive process At 1 At t Persistence parameter At Productivity shock At 1 At 0 1 At 0 L Suppose that the economy is hit by a positive productivity shock that is perceived to be temporary 0 For a given level of employment and capital, production increases y w p l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* Rise in productivity w p * l d ( A, K ) * L L * L L Suppose that the economy is hit by a positive productivity shock that is perceived to be temporary 0 With a rise in productivity, at the initial real wage, demand for labor rises w p Y l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* w p Non-Labor income is (relatively) unaffected * Rise in productivity l d ( A, K ) * L L * L L Suppose that the economy is hit by a positive productivity shock that is perceived to be temporary 0 Non-Labor income is (relatively) unaffected w p Y l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* w p * Rise in productivity l d ( A, K ) * L L * L The rise in labor demand increases employment and real wages L An increase in productivity that is permanent will have a larger effect on non-labor income, and create a decrease in labor supply 1 Non-Labor income increases w p Y l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* w p * Rise in productivity l d ( A, K ) * L L * L The drop in labor supply creates a larger increase in the real wage and a smaller effect on output and employment L Labor Markets and the business cycle Given the mechanics of the labor market, what relationships would we expect to see between productivity, wages, employment, and output? Just the facts ma’am. Correlation Employment Output + or - Wages + Productivity + GDP vs. Employment (% Deviation from trend) 6 Correlation = .84 4 2 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 -2 -4 -6 -8 Output Employment 1996 1998 2000 GDP vs. Productivity (% Deviation from trend) 6 Correlation = .66 4 2 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 -2 -4 -6 -8 Output MFP 1994 1996 1998 2000 GDP vs. Real Wages (% Deviation from trend) 6 Correlation = .18 4 2 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 -2 -4 -6 -8 Output Wages 1994 1996 1998 2000 The low correlation between real wages and GDP suggests that labor supply is very elastic w p l s (NLI ) l d ( A, K ) L Random labor productivity fluctuations cause large employment movements, but very little change in the real wage Example: Oil Price Shocks in the 1970’s Dollars per Barrel 1979 Iranian Revolution (Temporary Shock) 1973 Arab Oil Embargo (Permanent Shock) This dramatic rise in oil prices can be thought of as a negative productivity shock. Remember, we are measuring GDP by value added. When energy costs go up, value added goes down w p Y l s (NLI ) F ( A, K , L) Y* w p * l d ( A, K ) * L L L* L This temporary drop in labor productivity caused a decrease in labor demand A temporary shock creates a small income effect and, therefore, no change in labor supply. If the shock were more permanent, a rise in labor supply would push the real wage even lower Real Compensation (1972 – 1982) w p Ls w p LD Ls L % Deviation From Trend LD 1979 Iranian Revolution 1973 Arab Oil Embargo L Employment (1972 – 1982) w p w p s L LD L % Deviation From Trend LD 1973 Arab Oil Embargo Ls 1979 Iranian Revolution L Y Y L % Deviation From Trend L 1979 Iranian Revolution 1973 Arab Oil Embargo GDP (1972 – 1982)