ERASMUS UNIVERSITY ROTTERDAM ERASMUS SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS BACHELOR THESIS (IBEB) Research on the Relationship Between CEO Compensation and Company Performance By Xiangzi Luo 356786 Supervisor: Prof.Dr.Otto.H.Swank June 2014 Abstract This study aims to analyze the relationship between the CEO compensation (in cash or in equity based) and company performance (return on asset, return on equity and earnings per share) of 1662 companies from ExeuComp database in 2012. I use a simple linear regression and determine a significant positive correlation, which is consistent with the previous done studies. In the meantime, I also find that there is impact of other factors such as firm size and debt ratio on the pay-performance relationship. Table of Contents I. Introduction II. Literature Reviews III. Theoretical Framework 3.1. Principal-agent theory 3.2. Executive compensation structure 3.3. CEO pay and Corporate governance IV. Hypotheses V. Data and Methodology VI. VII. 5.1. Model 5.2. Data 5.3. Key variables Statistical Results 6.1. Descriptive analysis 6.2. Empirical analysis 6.3. A comparison Conclusion and Limitations VIII. Reference IX. Annex I. INTRODUCTION The separation of ownership and control in the modern companies has brought about the so-called agency problem. Basically framed, the shareholders of a firm usually hire the executives to perform tasks on their behalf. However, with lack of the information, shareholders cannot observe the behaviors of the CEOs; thereby not ensure whether the agent will make decisions in the way they would like. To better align the interests of the two parties, the principle (in this case the shareholders) comes up with the compensation scheme which will motivate the agents (CEOs) to maximize the firm’s and in turn their own wealth. It is not authentic to say that the payment of compensation will actually align the party’s objectives and eliminate the conflicts. Nevertheless, the upward surge of the CEO compensation did provoke the public discussions and controversies. According to Frydman and Jenter (2010), the CEO compensation has increased substantially over the past 30 years. Survey done on S&P 500 US firms reported that the average annual CEO compensation has reached at $11.4 million in 2010, and has made an unbelievable 354 times that of the average workers’ pay. Other studies have also indicated a disproportionately large share of the compensation pie of CEO, as compare to a typical employee. Publications over the topic of whether CEO worth that much of pay and whether the firm performance really linked to the compensation abound. The most accepted outcome nowadays is that there is a positive relationship between level of CEO compensation and company performance (Bloom,1998). Hall and Liebman(1998) add that the major driving strength behind is the equity-based compensation reward to the CEO. On the other hand, there are also some scholars holding different views. Gomez-Mejia(1994), for instance, believes that the CEOs are always overpaid. Brick et al. (2006) even conclude that there is a negative correlation between the excess compensation and firm performance. Other studies show a positive but insignificant pay-performance relation which suggests the limitations of compensation incentive. In this paper, I want to conduct a research trial to study the correlation between the amount of CEO pay and company performance. In the meantime, I will also investigate other factors which may affect the pay-performance relationship, namely the firm size, debt ratio, industry type and so on. To do so, I analyze both descriptive and empirical study into different industries and firms obtained from the ExecuComp database in 2012. The remainder of this paper will be organized as follows: In section II, I review the relevant literatures and evidence over the topic of executive compensation. In section III, the theoretical framework is established and three leading theories are explained in details. Based on that, I come up with three hypotheses and my expectation regards to them. The next section describes the data and methodology in which I establish simple linear regression models with different indicators and discuss the data source and key variables. Section VI provides the statistic results and gives both descriptive and empirical analysis with also a comparison among three models. The final section will conclude and give some limitations and suggestions for further research. II. LITERATURE REVIEWS Despite a vast amount of empirical studies concerning to the topic, no consensus has ever been reached. The different results with regards to the relationship between executive compensation and firm performance can be interpreted by multi-factors such as the sample size, the varied indicators, the different econometric models applied, and the periodicity of the data etc. In the prior studies, some main types of performance indicators have been used: Tobin’s Q, Earnings per share, Return on Equity, Market Value and Return on Assets. For instance, Mehran (1995) investigates a random sample of 153 manufacturing firms for the period of 1979-1980. In his comprehensive study, he finds that performance of a firm, when measured by Tobin’s Q and ROA, is positively linked to the proportion of equity-based compensation and to the percentage of equity held by executives, with the correlation coefficients of 0.521 and 2.263 respectively. Ke, Petroni and Safieddine (1999) also conclude in their paper a positive relationship between ROA and level of executive pay, but only for the publicly-held insurance firms. Jensen and Murphy(1990) show in their research the same positive payperformance sensitivity, finding that CEOs receive an extra bonus pay of 2.59$ for every 1000$ increase in total shareholder’s value. It was then suggested that the correlation between CEO pay and firm performance, though statistically significant, is too weak to motivate CEO and this positive but insignificant relation has also been reported by Ozkan(2007). However, some scholars also hold the belief that CEOs are usually overpaid. Bebchuk and Fried (2004), for example, criticize in their paper that top executives’ compensation had not been closely tied to the company performance. Sigler (2011) also argues that both the cash and equity-based compensation may draw some CEOs to involve in activities that have bad impacts on the company. Cash bonuses, which are based on annual financial report, might encourage top managers to manipulate the timing of revenue and expense to maximize their own utilities at the cost of the firm’s. On the other hand, equity-based compensation may also entice CEOs to outright cheat and boost accounting numbers before exercising their options for the aim of driving up the stock price (Conyon, 2006). Devers et al. (2007) also reports his concerns regarding to the overuse of equity-based pay and the possible illegal behaviors of CEOs by steering the firms for the sake of their own goods. Some studies which focus on the impact of other factors on pay-performance relationship are also worth noting. Scott Schaefer (1998) analyzes the relationship between company size and the extent to which CEO compensation relies on the wealth of the firm. He builds an econometric model using nonlinear least squares and finds that the pay-performance sensitivity, as defined by Jensen and Murphy, is inversely consistent to the square root of the firm size. Holmstrom (1992) also notes the finding that the pay–performance sensitivity is decreasing with the size. He even uses this empirical result to support the agency theory under the assumption that risk is traded off with incentives at the margin. John and John (1993) argue that the payperformance sensitivity will be decreasing with the debt ratio under a well-formed compensation structure. Therefore, they suggest the debt ratio of a firm should be taken into consideration of setting an optimal contract. In general, although literatures differ on whether the compensation is really linked to performance, most cases have found a weak but significant relationship between them (Core, 1999). When taking into account of other factors, the pay-performance sensitivity will then be changed. III. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK Principal-Agent Theory The Principal-agent theory was first separately emerged in the work of Stephen Ross in the early 1970s. It then turned out to be one of the most used theories to explain the CEO compensation. Broadly speaking, the principal-agent theory analyzes the conflicts between the contractual relationship of two parties, namely the principals and the agents on behalf of those principals. When one party (principal) hires the other party (agent) to perform a service or work, the two sides may have different desires or goals and may also have different attitudes towards risks. In this case, either of the party would only care about its own interests and thereby act for its personal goods (Denis, 1999). The principal-agent theory also gives us a clue of why the shareholders would be willing to give out CEO a fairly large compensation package. When shareholders (principals) delegate the decision-making rights to the executives (agents), they expect their CEOs to act in the way that maximize the utility of the company. The CEOs, on the other hand, is always motivated to work in their own best profits. In the meantime, as CEOs usually grasp more private information, the shareholder cannot guarantee that agents would always put his (principal’s) interest in the first place, especially under situation in which interests of the two are in conflict and the activities of CEOs are costly for the shareholders to observe. Figure 1: To mitigate those clashes, shareholders may either monitor the managerial behaviors of the CEOs or use compensation packages as a mean of aligning executives and shareholder interests. Because the monitoring is always cost-prohibitive for shareholders and because the managerial activities are often unobservable, the company tends to adopt the compensation scheme (Bloom, 1998). Executive Compensation Structure Despite a considerable heterogeneity in CEO pay across industries and firms, most compensation packages include three basic components: monetary, non-monetary and equity rights. Monetary compensations include base salaries and annual bonuses in form of cash. Non-monetary compensations are for instance: increased responsibility, education opportunities, reputation, etc. Equity rights contain options, stocks, shares warrants and so on. Usually, the top managers are able to receive several forms of compensation for their work. The importance of the various types of compensation for CEO is obvious and worth noting as different component has its own shortcomings. A mix of the compensation allow the strength of one offset the weakness of another and may mitigate the activities of the CEOs, which would produce some problems for the company (Sigler, 2011). Cash bonuses are traditional ways of providing incentives to the CEOs to focus on short-run goals. Rewarding this monetary compensation may encourage CEOs to have undesired behaviors as this type of bonuses are usually paid once at the end of year and are based on the yearly performance of the firm. Assuming that a CEO of a company can receive only a base salary with some cash bonuses, to maximize his own compensation, this top manager is motivated to manipulate the accounting number of the annual report (Conyon, 2006). Despite of the cheating of financial report, cash bonuses may also in some cases misdirect the top managers to focus only on short term performance and may harm the health of the company in long-run perspective. Equity-based compensation is another popular tool for the company to tie pay to performance by making the executives part of the owners themselves. In principle, as the equity-based incentives (restricted stocks and option grants) will only be realizable after a certain period of time, top managers have to work in a way that will benefit both for personal goods and for the long-term sustainability of the firm. Nevertheless, it may not be wise to tie most of the components of CEO pay to the stock price as stock price of a firm will fluctuate under market forces instead of manager’s efforts. In general, not a single form of compensation would be good enough to align the interests of the two sides. Every type of compensation allows for some sorts of cheating as long as one party gets the privileged access to private information (Sahut, 2010). The complex component of CEO pay is therefore necessary. CEO Pay and Corporate Governance It is true that CEO pay can ameliorate agency problem by aligning the interests of both owners and top managers in some extent. However, when the corporate governance of a firm is weak such that CEOs may control the amount and structure of their own rewards, compensation scheme may turn to part of the problem of a company. Generally speaking, CEOs can still be overpaid and be safeguarded from their poor performance and thereby, mitigate the relationship between the CEO compensation and company performance. There are also situations in which executives themselves are members of the compensation committee, levels of CEO pay is then directly linked to the number of executives who serve for the committee(O’Reilly, 1988). The empirical studies on the CEO compensation and corporate governance are abundant. Some of the academics conclude that CEO pay levels are consistent with good firm internal governance in most cases (K, 2002 & Holmstom B, 2003). Others found that CEOs who also belong to compensation committee tend to receive a higher stock right with less overall compensation (Anderson R, 2003). IV. HYPOTHESES Due to previous theoretical part and done studies, I come up with three assumptions regarding to the relationship between the CEO compensation and corporate performance and other factors which also affect pay-performance relationship. As stated in the optimal contracting theory, compensation is used to optimize the agent-principal contract. Under the condition of good corporate governance, I expect that the compensation committee would set CEO pay consistent with the firm performance. Simply framed, the better the performance of the company, the higher pay will top managers receive. I thereby formulate the first hypothesis as below: H0: There is no significant correlation between CEO compensation and company performance Ha: There is a significant positive correlation between CEO compensation and company performance. When the size of a firm expands, the complexity of the activities to operate would also increase; thereby require higher managerial skills of the CEO. On the other side, company may also take advantage of the economics of scale and utilize the resources in a much more efficient way to earn extra profits. The higher the profit of the company, the more willing shareholders are to offer higher compensation regards to the hard work of CEO and thus, a more significant relationship between the pay and performance would achieve. So, the second hypothesis is: H0: There is no significant strengthening effect of firm size on the payperformance relationship. Ha: There is a significant strengthening effect of firm size on the payperformance relationship. Among almost all the traded companies, there are basically two ways to raise capital: equity financing and debt financing. Obviously, different types would lead to different Asset-liability ratios. Through debt financing, firms are able to raise funds in a cheaper way and increase its leverage to explore extra profits for shareholders. However, it also comes with higher risk as leverage amplifies both gains and losses. To put in another word, if the debt ratio is way too high for the firm to repay, great finance pressure may eventually force the corporate to go bankruptcy. In order to cure this financial distress, shareholders are expected to strength the correlation between the compensation and firm performance. Through this way, CEO will be motivated to operate better on the business and bring more profits to the company. Therefore, I expect that the relationship between the CEO pay and company performance is stronger as the debt rate of a firm increases. The third hypothesis would then be: H0: There is no significant strengthening effect of debt ratio on the payperformance relationship Ha: There is a significant strengthening effect of debt ratio on the payperformance relationship. V. DATA AND METHODOLOGY Model In this section, I develop a linear regression model to analyze the level of CEO compensation to firm performance after taking into account of other factors: Y=α+β1X+β2SIZE+β3 Debt +β4 X*SIZE +β5X*DEBT+∑βiINDi+εi In the equation, I assume that the CEO compensation is determined by the firm performance, firm size, debt ratio along with the interaction terms and dummy variables. Here, the dependent variable Y refers to the CEO compensation which in forms of Monetary and equity-based respectively; the independent variable X represents the firm performance with three different measures. SIZE is literally the scale of a firm and the DEBT means the ratio of debt to total asset. The SIZE, DEBT and the IND will be used as control variables and the interaction terms of X*SIZE & X*DEBT will serve for the relevant assumptions. For instance, to check my second assumption regards to the impact of size on level of pay-performance, we progress the regression under corresponding measurements of each variable. If the signs of β1 and β4 are the same (whether they are both either positive or negative), this would imply a strengthening effect. Otherwise, there is a weakening effect. Figure 2: Conceptual Framework Independent Variable X: Dependent Variable Y: Firm performance -Return on Asset (ROA) -Return on Equity (ROE) -Earnings per share(EPS) CEO Compensation -Monetary pay LN(TM) -Equity-based pay LN(TSE) Control Variable: Firm Size (SIZE) Debt Ratio(DEBT) Industry(IND) Data In order to investigate the hypotheses, I collect data from the Standard & Poor’s (McGraw-Hill) ExecuComp database via Wharton. The ExecuComp provides annual data of the executive compensation as well as the firm-specific financial statement information. It tracks corporates in the S&P 1000 from 1992 onwards, and is also the most widely used data source over the relevant topics. In this paper, I use a sample size of 1662 companies classified under the Global Industry Classification Standard (GISC). More specifically, I have groups as 10 (Energy), 15 (Materials), 20 (Industrials), 25 (Consumer Discretionary), 30 (Consumer Staples), 35 (Health Care), 40 (Financials), 45 (Information Technology), 50 (Telecommunication Services) and 55 (Utilities). I prefer the cross-sectional analysis to the time-series analysis, as the former allows a broader industry coverage at a single time point. The construction of the cross section will be based on the year of 2012 with more samples compared to 2013.To assess the CEO compensation, I gather variables such as salary, bonus, stock option from the AnnComp data table. In the meantime, I use data such as total assets, stockholder’s equity, EPS, ROA and ROE from the Codirfin datasheet to collect the company information and performance. Key Variables variable type variable description dependent LN(TM) log of total monetary compensation LN(TSE) log of total equity based compensation exercised. EPS Earnings per share(performance indicator) ROE Return on Equity(performance indicator) ROA Return on Asset(performance indicator) LN(TA) log of the total asset of a firm Debt the rate of Debt over total asset IND dummy variable: independent Control IND=1,if it belongs to a corresponding industry; otherwise, IND=0 CEO compensation: Though the compensation exists in many forms, it is acknowledged that cash and stock options are the most widely used in companies. Debate over which would serve as the optimal contract for the agency problem has still been extending. As a proxy for the executive remuneration, I thereby use two measures: total monetary compensation and total equity-based compensation. Both of the indicators are given in thousands and are represented in the form of nature logarithm to minimize the disturbance of heteroskedasiticity. The total cash compensation LN(TM) consists base salary and bonus, while the alternative equitybased compensation LN(TSE) contains stocks and options that are assessed using the value realized from the option exercise or stock vesting. Company performance: I decide in this paper to adopt three variables: ROA, ROE and EPS as a measurement of firm performance. Return on Asset (ROA) is the ratio of net income before extraordinary items and Discontinued Operations to total assets. It shows how profitable of a firm is relative to total assets and is used as one of the indicators of company performance. However, the drawback of using ROA is that the number of ROA can vary substantially as it dependents highly on industries. Return on Equity (ROE) is the ratio of net income before extraordinary items and Discontinued Operations to total common equity and allows for comparison among different firms. ROE alone can also not be a proper measurement as it can be driven up intentionally by the degree of leverage of a firm (ECB, 2012). Therefore, I also have my third indicator: earnings per share, which is the portion of the firm’s earning allocated to each outstanding share of the common stock. In principle, the higher the EPS is, the higher is the profit of the company. Nevertheless, EPS may be affected by many economic factors and is open to manipulation. To sum up, each measure has its own advantages and disadvantages. Hence, I apply three of them to adjust the unpleasant effects. Firm Size: Previous research shows that firm size is a major determinant of executive compensation. There are also some literatures investigate the effect of size on the payperformance relationship. For instance, Schaefer (1997) uses market value and total asset as two measures of firm size and finds the pay-performance sensitivity moves inversely proportional to the square root of size. Cichello (2005) also estimates the relation between size and pay-performance sensitivity and applies three variables to represent the firm size, namely total assets, total sales and number of employees. Sum up the early documents, I determine to use the natural logarithm of total asset LN(TA) as the indicator of the firm size regard to the second hypothesis. Debt ratio: The term is defined as the ratio of total debt to total asset, calculated in percentage. It shows the proportion of a firm’s asset which is financed by debt and is also used as a measurement of leverage degree of a company. It seems that the debt ratios vary significantly across industries. In general, industries with capital-intensive businesses will usually have higher debt ratios compared to others. This also explains why Industrials & Utilities industries tend to own such a high debt ratio compared to Technology. Back to this study, as higher debt ratio replies to higher risk-taking, I expect a positive effect of debt rate on the relationship of CEO compensation and company performance. Industry: As mentioned above, I have classified 1662 sample into 10 industries and will use IND as a dummy variable in my model. Though I have no assumption regards to the types of industry. I will also give a descriptive analysis and expect a larger payperformance correlation as the competition faced by the company is fiercer. Global Industry Classification Standard IND code IND type Sample N proportion 0 Energy 99 6% 1 Materials 111 7% 2 Industrials 228 14% 3 Consumer Discretionary 285 17% 4 Consumer Staples 85 5% 5 Healthcare 162 10% 6 Financials 306 18% 7 Information Technology 307 18% 8 9 Telecommunication Services Utilities Total 17 62 1662 1% 4% 100% VI. STATISTICAL RESULTS Descriptive Analysis Table 4.1 : Descriptive Statistics N Minimum Maximum Mean Std. Deviation LN(TM) 1662 -6.91 10.34 6.68 1.13 LN(TS) 1662 -6.91 13.93 8.33 1.29 ROE 1662 -3050.00 7038.46 13.71 213.71 ROA 1662 -143.77 170.30 4.17 11.14 EPS Excl 1662 -21.48 45.48 1.90 3.38 LN(TA) 1662 2.34 14.67 7.99 1.77 Debt 1662 -.73 1.00 .56 .22 Valid N (listwise) 1662 First of all, I take a glance at the descriptive analysis of the data. Table 4.1 shows the relevant statistics on the compensation level and firm performance with also other control variables in 2012. It summarizes the dependent variable of CEO pay which has a mean of 6.68 for LN(TM) and 8.33 for LN(TS), respectively. In general, I can conclude that the equity-based compensation account for a larger proportion of the total compensation. The standard deviation which measures the spread shows that there is a slightly more deviation from the mean of the equity-based compensation (1.29) as compared to the cash bonus (1.13). The fact that LN(TM) ranged from -6.91 to a maximum of 10.34 and LN(TS) ranged from -6.91 to a high of 13.93 also tells us that different pay levels exist across firms. In the meantime, the performance statistics of the company also gives us information. It can be reported from the table that the mean of the three indicators are 13.71%, 4.17%, and 1.90% respectively. So, the ROE has an increment of 9.54% compared to ROA and it also owns the highest standard deviation of 213.71 among three. To further explore how different industries behavior, I introduce the table 4.2 and 4.3 with statistics in reference to industry types. compensation, it can be concluded that: Regardless of the forms of CEO a) Compensation levels are different among industries according to the fluctuating mean values. b) Compensation levels are also different across firms within each industry based on the various minimum and maximum ranges. One possible explanation for the distinctions would be that there are different characteristics among industries. For instance, utilities have more government involvement, and finance firms have different business nature compare to others. Table 4.2 LN(TM) Industry Mean N Minimum Maximum 0 6.75 99 -6.91 9.83 1 6.78 111 5.28 7.82 2 6.73 228 -6.91 8.96 3 6.78 285 -6.91 10.34 4 6.71 85 -6.91 8.94 5 6.65 162 -6.91 8.10 6 6.83 306 4.09 10.25 7 6.33 307 -6.91 8.52 8 6.86 17 5.99 8.09 9 6.78 62 6.20 7.34 Total 6.68 1662 -6.91 10.34 Table 4.3 LN(TS) Industry Mean N Minimum Maximum 0 8.61 99 5.64 13.93 1 8.49 111 6.37 11.41 2 8.44 228 5.01 11.42 3 8.44 285 3.50 12.45 4 8.49 85 4.88 11.49 5 8.34 162 .69 11.36 6 8.30 306 5.11 11.23 7 7.94 307 -6.91 11.94 8 8.44 17 7.05 10.26 9 8.55 62 7.06 10.19 Total 8.33 1662 -6.91 13.93 Empirical Analysis On the second part of the statistical analysis, I focus more on the empirical regression results. There are 3 models relating to the two main compensation forms using three different independent indicators: (i) relationship between CEO pay and ROE; (ii) relationship between CEO pay and ROA; (iii) relationship between CEO pay and EPS. Besides that, the superscripts ***, **, and * denote the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels of significance in the regression respectively. I hereby use each model to test the hypotheses and get results as below: Regression Analysis on Model 1: LN(TM) Variable B ROE 0.006*** LN(TA) 0.150*** Debt 0.166 ROE*LN(TA) 2.291E-05 ROE*Debt -0.006** Adjusted R Square 0.070 F 25.843 Sig F 0.000 t 2.679 8.258 1.109 0.203 -2.480 P 0.007 0.000 0.268 0.839 0.013 LN(TS) B 0.016*** 0.398*** -0.332** 0.000 -0.017*** 0.303 145.112 0.000 t 6.716 22.161 -2.249 1.232 -6.659 P 0.000 0.000 0.025 0.218 0.000 In model 1 of the regression, I take ROE as the measurement of the independent variable. Two equations are derived as follow: LN(TM)= β0+β1*ROE+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4ROE*LN(TA)+β5ROE*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi LN(TS)= β0+β1*ROE+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4ROE*LN(TA)+β5ROE*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi The results in the table shows that there is a strong positive relationship between the CEO remuneration (both in cash or in equity-based) and ROE. The t statistics for the slope are significant at 0.01 critical level, with t1=2.679 and t2=6.716. Thus, Ho can be rejected and so I accept Ha for my first hypothesis. This positive finding is also consistent with the previous studies (Sigler, 2011). For the second hypothesis, I will analyze by looking at the sign of coefficients of ROE and ROE*LN(TA). However, as t statistics for neither LN(TM) nor LN(TS) are significant according to the table, H0 cannot be rejected, which implies that there is no significant strengthening impact of firm size on the pay-performance relationship. On the same line of reasoning, I test my third hypothesis and exhibit a weakening instead of strengthening effect of debt ratio on pay-performance correlation, as the signs of β1 and β5 are different. In this case, I also not reject Ho. Regression Analysis on Model 2: Variable ROA LN(TA) Debt ROA*LN(TA) ROA*Debt Adjusted R Square F Sig F LN(TM) B P LN(TS) B t t P 0.004 0.520 0.603 -0.035*** -4.317 0.000 0.147*** 7.638 0.000 0.353*** 18.848 0.000 0.145 0.919 0.358 -0.074 -0.481 0.630 -5.349E-05 -0.032 0.975 0.01*** 6.195 0.000 0.012* 1.651 0.099 -0.008 -1.056 0.291 0.071 0.328 26.525 163.238 0.000 0.000 In model 2 of my regression, the measurement is done by adopting ROA, ceteris paribus. The corresponding equations are thereby: LN(TM)= β0+β1*ROA+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4ROA*LN(TA)+β5ROA*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi LN(TS)= β0+β1*ROA+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4ROA*LN(TA)+β5ROA*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi It is important to note in this model that t value of neither the ROA nor ROA*LN (TA) is significant for the type of monetary compensation. Furthermore, with a p-value of 0.099 and a positive coefficient (0.012) of the ROA*Debt, I can see only a slightly significant strengthening effect of debt ratio on the pay-performance relationship. On the contrary, there are significant evidence for testing the first two hypotheses using LN (TS). Nevertheless, I find an oddly negative correlation between the ROA and LN (TS), and thereby also a weakening effect of the LN(TA) on pay-performance correlation. Same result can also be tracked from the other paper (Cooper, 2009). Lastly, no significant effect of debt ratio on the ROA-LN (TS) correlation as p-value of only 0.291, which is higher than 0.1 critical level. Regression Analysis on Model 3: Variable EPS LN(TA) Debt EPS*LN(TA) EPS*Debt LN(TM) B t P LN(TS) B t P 0.022 0.501 0.617 0.221*** 5.083 0.000 0.189*** 9.538 0.000 0.446*** 22.847 0.000 -0.332** -2.113 0.035 -0.800*** -5.154 0.000 -0.016*** -3.922 0.000 -0.031*** -7.521 0.000 0.230*** 6.131 0.000 0.176*** 4.751 0.000 Adjusted R Square 0.093 F 35.009 Sig F 0.000 0.322 158.582 0.000 ***Significance at 0 .01 level **significance at 0.05 level *significance at 0.1 level In the last model, a simple regression is performed to determine the relationship between the CEO compensation and EPS: LN(TM)= β0+β1*EPS+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4EPS*LN(TA)+β5EPS*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi LN(TS)= β0+β1*EPS+ β2*LN(TA)+ β3*Debt +β4EPS*LN(TA)+β5EPS*Debt+∑βiINDi+εi One advantage using model 3 is that almost all the statistics are within the significant level of 5%. Concerning the first hypothesis, there is a positive significant relationship between the LN(TS) and EPS, which is the same as my result in model 1. I would thereby reject the first hypothesis and accept the alternative one. No significant evidence supports the positive correlation between LN(TM) and EPS. Furthermore, statistics in the table also indicates a significant but negative effect of the LN(TA) on the pay-performance level regardless of the forms of the dependent variables. Finally, I will reject Ho and accept Ha for my third hypothesis, as it exhibits a significant strengthening effect of debt ratio on the pay-performance relationship in both cases. A Comparison A quick comparison of the three models would help give an overall picture of the empirical outcome: (i) Within each model, under the same indicator of firm performance, the adjusted R-squared will always be larger for the LN(TS) compared to LN(TM). This may imply that a higher percentage of the deviation of equity-based compensation can be explained by the independent variable compared to the cash reward. (ii) All of the three models are significant with small value of F-statistics, which shows a strong correlation between performance and compensation after taking into account of other factors. (iii) In model 1 and model 3, I get a similar positive result regards to my first two assumptions but a totally opposite outcome regards to the third one. In contrast, statistics in model 2 are only significant for the analysis of the equity type of compensation, but it shows an oddly negative payperformance correlation. VII. CONCLUSION AND LIMITATIONS Conclusion Nowadays, the existence of a correlation between the CEO pay and performance has been widely disputed. This paper aims to study not only the correlation but also the impacts of other factors such as firm size and debt ratio on the pay-performance relationship. To do so, I collect data from the ExecComp database and use a simple linear regression to test the relevant hypotheses. In general, there is a significantly positive pay-performance correlation, which is consistent with the previous studies. Impacts of firm size and debt on the pay-performance relationship are different according to different models. Model 1 suggests a weakening effect of the debt ratio, while model 3 indicates an opposite strengthening effect. As for the firm size, model 3 concludes a weakening effect on the pay-performance relationship for both monetary and equity based compensation. Other models, however, imply that there is no significant strengthening impact of firm size on the pay-performance relationship. The different results may be explained by the fact that each measurement of the company performance has disadvantages. ROA varies substantially as it dependents highly on industries; ROE can be driven up intentionally by the degree of leverage of a firm; EPS may also be affected by many economic factors and is open to manipulation. Limitations The major limitation in this paper is that I only infer the correlation instead of causality between the factors. Correlation is symmetry, while causation is asymmetry. Also, there might be confounders, which influence both the CEO compensation and company performance. For instance, some of the CEOs obtain larger pay package due to the fact that they start with healthier institutions. In this case, a positive relation between the two factors would not necessary indicate the effect of compensation on the consequence of performance, but the other way around. The second limitation relates to the data and methodology part of the paper. To be more specific, it is due to the lack of latest data and the mere use of cross-sectional analysis. It is noted that a sample size of only 1662 companies from 2012 is processed. To achieve a better accurate result for the future research, some of the suggestions will be proposed. First, relevant causation analysis is highly recommended. Second, a larger data sample can be collected by including the time-series study. Last but not least, the performance should be measured by not only the profitability but also other indicators such as “quality of assets, risk associated to the production value and the funding capacity” (ECB, 2012). Bibliography Anderson R, B. J. (2003). Compensation Committees: It Matters Who Sets Pay. Journal of Banking and Finance, 27: 1323-1348. Bloom.M & Milkovich, G. (1998). Relationships among Risk, Incentive Pay, and Organizational Performance. . The academy of Management Journal,41(3),283-297. Cichello, M. S. (2005). The Impact of Firm Size on Pay-Performance Sensitivities. Journal of Corporate Finance, 2005, vol. 11, issue 4, pages 609-627. Conyon, M. J. (2006). Executive Compensation and Incentives. Management 20,no.1:25-45. Cooper, M. J., Gulen, H., & Rau, P. R. (2009). Performance for Pay? The Relationship Between CEO Incentive Compensation and Future Stock Price Performance. Working Paper. Core, J. (1999). Corporate Governance,Cchief Executive Officer Compensation, and Firm Performance. Journal of Financial Economics.51(3),371-406. Denis, D. S. (1999). Agency Theory and the Influence of Equity Ownership Structure on Corporate Diversification Strategies. Strategic Management Journal,20(11),1071-1076. Devers, C. E. (2007). Executive Compensation: A Multidisciplinary Review of Recent Developments. Journal of Management, 33, 1016-1072. Fried, J., & Bebchuk, L. (2004). Pay without Performance, The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation, Part II: Power and Pay. Harvard University Press. Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998). Are CEOs Really Paid Like Bureaucrats. The Quaterly Journal of Economics, vol. 113, issue 3, 653-691. Holmstom B, K. S. (2003). The State of U.S. Corporate Governance: What’s Right and what’s Wrong? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Spring: 8-20. John, T. A. (1993). Top-Management Compensation and Capital Structure. Journal of Finance 48, no. 3: 949-74. K, M. (2002). Explaining Executive Compensation: Managerial Power vs the Perceived Cost of Stock Options. Chicago Law Review, 69(3): 847–69. Ke, B. K. (1999). Ownership Concentration and Sensitivity of Executive Pay to Accounting Performance Measures: Evidence from Publicly and PrivatelyHeld Insurance Companies. Journal of Accounting and Economics 28, 185209. Mehran, H. (1995). Executive Compensation Structure,Ownership,and Firm Performance. Journal of Financial Economics 38, no. 2: 163-84. Murphy, J. a. (1990). Performance Pay and Top-managment Incentives. The Journal of Political Economy,Vol.98,No2,225-264. O’Reilly, C. B. (1988). CEO Compensation as Tournament and Social Comparison: A Tale of Two Theories,”. Administrative Science Quarterly 33,p. 257-274. Ozkan, N. (2011). CEO Compensation and Firm Performance: An Empirical Investigation of UK Panel Data. European Financial Management, Volume 17, Issue 2, 260–285. Schaefer, S. (1998). The Dependence of Pay-Performance Sensitivity on the Size. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 80, No. 3, 436-443. Sigler, K. (2011). CEO Compensation and Company Performance. Business and Economics Journal, Volume 2011: BEJ-31. Tosi Jr., H. L., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (1994). CEO Compensation Monitoring and Firm Performance. Academy of Management Journal, vol. 37 no. 4, 10021016. ANNEXS (1) LN(TM)=f(ROE,LN(TA),Debt,ROE*LN(TA),ROE*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 a. R R Square Square .269a .072 .070 Predictors: (Constant), ROE*Debt, R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.08742870404 5415 LN(Total Assets), Debt, ROE*LN(Total Assets), ROE ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 152.796 5 30.559 25.843 .000b Residual 1958.222 1656 1.183 Total 2111.018 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) b. Predictors: (Constant), ROE*Debt, LN(Total Assets), Debt, ROE*LN(Total Assets), ROE Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.363 .123 ROE .006 .002 LN(Total Assets) .150 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 43.428 .000 1.217 2.679 .007 .018 .236 8.258 .000 .166 .149 .032 1.109 .268 ROE*LN(Total Assets) 2.291E-5 .000 .043 .203 .839 ROE*Debt -.006 .003 -1.216 -2.480 .013 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) (2) LN(TS)=f(ROE,LN(TA),Debt,ROE*LN(TA),ROE*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 a. R R Square Square .552a .305 .303 Predictors: (Constant), ROE*Debt, R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.07480090582 5320 LN(Total Assets), Debt, ROE*LN(Total Assets), ROE ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 838.164 5 167.633 145.112 .000b Residual 1913.006 1656 1.155 Total 2751.170 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS) b. Predictors: (Constant), ROE*Debt, LN(Total Assets), Debt, ROE*LN(Total Assets), ROE Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.263 .122 ROE .016 .002 LN(Total Assets) .398 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 43.122 .000 2.642 6.716 .000 .018 .548 22.161 .000 -.332 .148 -.057 -2.249 .025 ROE*LN(Total Assets) .000 .000 .225 1.232 .218 ROE*Debt -.017 .003 -2.827 -6.659 .000 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS) (3) LN(TM)=f(ROA,LN(TA),Debt,ROA*LN(TA),ROA*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 R R Square Square .272a .074 .071 R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.08639191403 6239 a. Predictors: (Constant), ROA*Debt, Debt, ROA, LN(Total Assets), ROA*LN(Total Assets) ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 156.528 5 31.306 26.525 .000b Residual 1954.490 1656 1.180 Total 2111.018 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) b. Predictors: (Constant), ROA*Debt, Debt, ROA, LN(Total Assets), ROA*LN(Total Assets) Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.388 .125 ROA .004 .008 LN(Total Assets) .147 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 43.157 .000 .042 .520 .603 .019 .232 7.638 .000 .145 .158 .028 .919 .358 ROA*LN(Total Assets) -5.349E-5 .002 -.003 -.032 .975 ROA*Debt .012 .007 .063 1.651 .099 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) (4) LN(TS)=f(ROA,LN(TA),Debt,ROA*LN(TA),ROA*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 R R Square Square .575a .330 .328 R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.05491593298 7620 a. Predictors: (Constant), ROA*Debt, Debt, ROA, LN(Total Assets), ROA*LN(Total Assets) ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 908.295 5 181.659 163.238 .000b Residual 1842.876 1656 1.113 Total 2751.170 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS) b. Predictors: (Constant), ROA*Debt, Debt, ROA, LN(Total Assets), ROA*LN(Total Assets) Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.367 .121 ROA -.035 .008 LN(Total Assets) .353 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 44.276 .000 -.299 -4.317 .000 .019 .486 18.848 .000 -.074 .153 -.013 -.481 .630 ROA*LN(Total Assets) .010 .002 .517 6.195 .000 ROA*Debt -.008 .007 -.035 -1.056 .291 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS) (5) LN(TM)=f(EPS,LN(TA),Debt,EPS*LN(TA),EPS*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 R R Square Square .309a .096 .093 R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.07373255292 9834 a. Predictors: (Constant), EPS Excl*Debt, Debt, LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 201.812 5 40.362 35.009 .000b Residual 1909.205 1656 1.153 Total 2111.018 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) b. Predictors: (Constant), EPS Excl*Debt, Debt, LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.347 .138 EPS Excl .022 .044 LN(Total Assets) .189 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 38.716 .000 .066 .501 .617 .020 .297 9.538 .000 -.332 .157 -.065 -2.113 .035 EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets) -.016 .004 -.467 -3.922 .000 EPS Excl*Debt .230 .038 .409 6.131 .000 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TM) (6) LN(TS)=f(EPS,LN(TA),Debt,EPS*LN(TA),EPS*Debt) Model Summary Adjusted Model 1 R R Square Square .569a .324 .322 R Std. Error of the Estimate 1.05991803100 6872 a. Predictors: (Constant), EPS Excl*Debt, Debt, LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl ANOVAa Model 1 Sum of Squares df Mean Square F Sig. Regression 890.776 5 178.155 158.582 .000b Residual 1860.394 1656 1.123 Total 2751.170 1661 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS) b. Predictors: (Constant), EPS Excl*Debt, Debt, LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets), EPS Excl Coefficientsa Standardized Unstandardized Coefficients Coefficients B Std. Error Beta (Constant) 5.117 .136 EPS Excl .221 .043 LN(Total Assets) .446 Debt Model 1 t Sig. 37.537 .000 .579 5.083 .000 .020 .615 22.847 .000 -.800 .155 -.137 -5.154 .000 EPS Excl*LN(Total Assets) -.031 .004 -.774 -7.521 .000 EPS Excl*Debt .176 .037 .274 4.751 .000 a. Dependent Variable: LN(TS)