An Introduction to International Economics Chapter 2: Comparative Advantage Dominick Salvatore John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-1 The basic questions of international trade • What is the basis of trade? – Two answers to this question will be discussed in this chapter: Absolute Advantage and Comparative Advantage Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-2 The basic questions of international trade • What is the basis of trade? • What are the gains from trade? – The models of Absolute and Comparative Advantage show that the gains from trade are increased consumption gained through specialization in production and trade. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-3 The basic questions of international trade • What is the basis of trade? • What are the gains from trade? • What is the pattern of trade? – What determines the pattern of specialization that drives international trade? Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-4 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? – The Mercantilist answer was the stock of precious metals possessed by a country. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-5 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? – Extraction from naturally occurring stocks • This option is available to few countries Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-6 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? – Extraction from naturally occurring stocks – Earn precious metals through exports of goods and services • Since payment for exports is made with precious metals, exporting causes precious metals to flow into a country • Similarly, since payment for imports is also made with precious metals, importing causes precious metals to flow out of country Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-7 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? • The natural conclusion – exports must exceed imports for a country to become wealthy! Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-8 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? • The natural conclusion – exports must exceed imports for a country to become wealthy! • Can this condition hold for all countries? – No! – Therefore, the wealth of one country must come at the expense of another country. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2-9 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? • The natural conclusion – exports must exceed imports for a country to become wealthy! • Can this condition hold for all countries? • Mercantilist policy – Strict government control over economic activity to ensure a positive trade balance Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 10 The Mercantilists • What is wealth? • How can precious metals be obtained? • The natural conclusion – exports must exceed imports for a country to become wealthy! • Can this condition hold for all countries? • Mercantilist policy • A further look at the Mercantilists – Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s “Major Schools of Economic Theory” • FRBSF WWW link Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 11 Is “wealth” precious metals? • To the Mercantilists, yes. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 12 Are precious metals “wealth”? • To the Mercantilists, yes. • Modern measures of wealth are based on a country’s ability to produce the goods and services that improve quality of life. – Hence, the Mercantilist conclusion is based a definition of wealth the differs significantly from modern notions of wealth. – This distinction leads to very different conclusions about how to become a wealthy nation. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 13 Absolute advantage • Built on the ideas of Adam Smith – The Library of Economic Liberty Biography of Adam Smith • WWW Link Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 14 Absolute advantage • Built on the ideas of Adam Smith • Absolute advantage exists between nations when they differ in their ability to produce goods. – More specifically, absolute advantage exists when one country is good at producing one item, while another country is good at producing another item. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 15 An example of absolute advantage • Countries – Scotland – Mexico • Goods – Coffee beans – Wool Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 16 An example of absolute advantage • How does specialization and trade advantage Scotland? – By reducing coffee bean production, resources are freed for producing more wool – Each hour of production change costs 1 unit of coffee beans but gains 4 units of wool Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 17 An example of absolute advantage • How does specialization and trade advantage Scotland? – Scotland can send 3 units of wool to Mexico and receive 7 units of coffee beans back – Thus, by specializing in production Scotland gains 1 unit of wool and 6 units of coffee per hour of production moved Gains per hour of production moved 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Coffee beans Wool Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 18 An example of absolute advantage • Does specialization and trade also advantage Mexico? – By reducing wool production, resources are freed for producing more coffee beans – Each hour of production change costs 2 units of wool but gains 10 units of coffee beans Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 19 An example of absolute advantage • Does specialization and trade also advantage Mexico? – Mexico can send 7 units of coffee beans to Scotland and receive 3 units of wool back – Thus, by specializing in production Mexico gains 1 unit of wool and 3 units of coffee beans per hour of production moved Gains per hour of production moved 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Coffee beans Wool Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 20 Policy recommendations from absolute advantage • Specialization and trade advantage both countries • Therefore, the best policy is to allow producers and consumers in both countries unfettered access to goods from both countries to maximize the number of advantageous trades that can occur. • In other words, laissez-faire. – The policy of minimum government interference with economic activity. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 21 A fatal flaw? • Absolute advantage requires one country to be better at production of one product and another country to be better at production of another good for specialization and trade to be mutually advantageous. • What if one country is better at everything? – The theory of comparative advantage provides this answer. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 22 Comparative advantage • Built on the ideas of David Ricardo – The New School History of Economic Thought Biography of David Ricardo • WWW Link Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 23 Comparative advantage • Built on the ideas of David Ricardo • The law of comparative advantage shows how mutually beneficial specialization and trade may be driven by relative advantages in production rather than absolute advantages in production. – Given the somewhat counter-intuitive nature of the law of comparative advantage its implications are best seen through example. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 24 An example of comparative advantage • Countries – Scotland – Mexico • Goods – Coffee beans – Wool • The difference lies in the relative productivity of the countries – In this case, Mexico is more productive at generating both goods. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Mexico 2 - 25 An example of comparative advantage • How does specialization and trade advantage Mexico? – By reducing wool production, resources are freed for producing more coffee beans – Each hour of production change costs 5 units of wool but gains 10 units of coffee beans Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 26 An example of comparative advantage • How does specialization and trade advantage Mexico? – Mexico can send 9 units of coffee beans to Scotland and receive 7 units of wool back – Thus, by specializing in production Mexico gains 1 unit of coffee beans and 2 units of wool per hour of production moved Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Gains per hour of production moved 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Coffee beans Wool Scotland Mexico 2 - 27 An example of comparative advantage • Does specialization and trade also advantage Scotland? – It does. To see this consider consider Scotland trading two hours of output. – Two hours of production change from coffee beans to wool costs 2 units of coffee beans but gains 8 units of wool Units produced per hour 10 9 8 7 Coffee beans Wool 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 28 An example of comparative advantage • Does specialization and trade also advantage Scotland? – Scotland can send 7 units of wool to Mexico, receiving 9 units of coffee beans in return – Thus, by specializing in production Scotland gains 1 unit of wool and 7 units of coffee beans Gains per hour of production moved 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Coffee beans Wool Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 29 Implications of comparative advantage • Laissez-faire still holds • Gains need not be equal • Hours of work traded need not be equal but the advantage still exists • Trade is based on the existence of relative – not absolute – production advantages Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 30 Does money alter the story? • No • Suppose the costs of production are as given below – Mexico: 100 pesos/hour – Scotland: 4 pounds/hour • Suppose 4£ ÷ 1 the unit exchange = 4£ per unit rate between pesos and 4£ x is 10P/£ = 40P pounds 1£ = 10Pper unit • This gives the unit costs indicated in the chart Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Peso price per unit of output 40 35 30 Coffee beans Wool 25 20 15 10 5 0 Scotland Mexico 2 - 31 Does money alter the story? • No • Suppose the costs of production are as given below – Mexico: 100 pesos/hour – Scotland: 4 pounds/hour • Suppose 4£ ÷ 4 the unitsexchange = 1£ per unit rate between pesos and 1£ x is 10P/£ = 10P pounds 1£ = 10Pper unit • This gives the unit costs indicated in the chart Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Peso price per unit of output 40 35 30 Coffee beans Wool 25 20 15 10 5 0 Scotland Mexico 2 - 32 Does money alter the story? • No • Suppose the costs of production are as given below Peso price per unit of output 40 – Mexico: 100 pesos/hour – Scotland: 4 pounds/hour 35 • Suppose the exchange 100P ÷ 10 units = 10P per unit rate between pesos and pounds is 1£ = 10P • This gives the unit costs indicated in the chart 25 Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 30 Coffee beans Wool 20 15 10 5 0 Scotland Mexico 2 - 33 Does money alter the story? • No • Suppose the costs of production are as given below – Mexico: 100 pesos/hour – Scotland: 4 pounds/hour • Suppose the =exchange 100P ÷ 5 units 20P per unit rate between pesos and pounds is 1£ = 10P • This gives the unit costs indicated in the chart Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Peso price per unit of output 40 35 30 Coffee beans Wool 25 20 15 10 5 0 Scotland Mexico 2 - 34 Does money alter the story? • At these prices goods will naturally flow from the cheaper market (Scotland for wool, Mexico for coffee beans) to the more expensive market. • Again, this demonstrates the law of comparative advantage but through prices not relative outputs. Peso price per unit of output 40 35 30 Coffee beans Wool 25 20 15 10 5 0 Scotland Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs Mexico 2 - 35 Does the source of the productive difference matter? • No • The original idea of comparative advantage was based on the labor theory of value. – The labor theory of value holds that costs and prices are solely determined by the labor content of an item. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 36 Does the source of the productive difference matter? • No • The original idea of comparative advantage was based on the labor theory of value. • The examples given above rely on opportunity cost. – Opportunity cost holds that the cost of an item is the amount of another item the must be given up to release sufficient resources to produce one more unit of the first item. Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 37 The production possibility frontier • The production possibility frontier (PPF) identifies the maximum combinations of two products that a nation can produce by fully utilizing all factors of production with the best technology available. • Consider the production possibilities schedule for an example: Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs United States Wheat Cloth 180 0 150 20 120 40 90 60 60 80 30 100 0 120 2 - 38 Constructing the PPF United States Cloth 140 120 Wheat Cloth 100 180 0 80 150 20 60 120 40 40 90 60 60 80 30 100 0 120 20 0 0 50 100 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 150 200 2 - 39 Constructing the PPF United States Cloth 140 120 Wheat Cloth 100 180 0 80 150 20 60 120 40 40 90 60 60 80 30 100 0 120 20 0 0 50 100 150 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 200 2 - 40 Constructing the PPF United States Cloth 140 120 Wheat Cloth 100 180 0 80 150 20 60 120 40 40 90 60 60 80 30 100 0 120 20 0 0 50 100 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 150 200 2 - 41 Regions of the PPF 140 Productive maximum 120 100 Cloth Underutilized resources 80 Unattainable with existing resources and technology 60 40 20 0 0 50 100 150 200 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 42 Trade with the PPF model US Cloth • Suppose the US and the UK have the PPFs given to the right 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Cloth UK 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 43 Trade with the PPF model Cloth US 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 (90W, 60C) 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat UK Cloth • Suppose the US and the UK have the PPFs given to the right • Further suppose that each country produces and consumes at the marked spot in the absence of international trade 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 (40W, 40C) 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 44 Trade with the PPF model Cloth US 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 (90W, 60C) 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat UK Cloth • Can specialization and trade lead to more aggregate production and consumption? • If the US specialized in wheat production and the UK in cloth production, aggregate production would increase from 130W to 180W and from 100C to 120C. 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 (40W, 40C) 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 45 Trade with the PPF model Cloth US 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 (110W, 70C) Production 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Production Cloth • This increased production would allow each country to consume at a point outside of its PPF as indicated by the blue lines in the graphs. • The increased consumption is the gains from trade. 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 UK (70W, 50C) 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 Wheat Dale R. DeBoer University of Colorado, Colorado Springs 2 - 46