Absolute Advantage to Comparative Advantage Introducing Opportunity Cost Suppose we want to look at absolute advantage for the following set of information Olives Sheep Spain 8 4 Portugal 6 8 To ascertain absolute advantage look at the product across the two countries and asked this question: Who can produce the most? If we look at olives, Spain can produce 8 whereas, Portugal can produce 6. Therefore we say that Spain has the absolute advantage in olives. If we look at sheep, Spain can produce 4 whereas, Portugal can produce 8. Therefore, we say that Portugal has the absolute advantage in sheep. But suppose we have the following set of information: Olives Sheep Spain 12 20 Portugal 6 4 To ascertain absolute advantage look at the product across the two countries and asked this question: Who can produce the most? If we look at olives, Spain can produce 12 whereas, Portugal can produce 6. Therefore we say that Spain has the absolute advantage in olives. If we look at sheep, Spain can produce 20 whereas, Portugal can produce 4. Therefore, we say that Spain has the absolute advantage in sheep. What are the ramifications of this? The ramifications are that Spain produces everything while Portugal sits on its rear end doing nothing. And we know that this is not how the world works. Absolute advantage has a fundamental flaw. That flaw occurs because it ignores opportunity cost. So let's introduce comparative advantage which does incorporate opportunity cost into the calculations. Document1 Page 1 of 9 Spain 12 20 Olives Sheep Portugal 6 4 Who is the Low Spain where 12 olives = 20 Portugal where 6 olives = 4 sheep sheep Opportunity Cost Producer? Olives Portugal Sheep Spain Document1 Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one olive. Calculate the up to the cost of producing one olive. 12 olives = 20 sheep 6 olives = 4 sheep 12/12 olives = 20/12 sheep 6/6 olives = 4/6 sheep 1 olives = 1.66 sheep or the opportunity cost of one olive is 1.66 sheep Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one sheep. 1 olive = 0.66 sheep or the opportunity cost of one olive is 0.66 sheep Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one sheep. 20 sheep = 12 olives 4 sheep = 6 olives 20/20 sheep = 12/20 olives 4/4 sheep = 6/4 olives 1 sheep = 0.6 olives or the opportunity cost of one sheep is 0.6 olives 1 sheep = 1.5 olives or the opportunity cost of one sheep is 1.5 olives Page 2 of 9 France 4 3 Bread Wine U.S. 10 4 To ascertain absolute advantage look at the product across the two countries and asked this question: Who can produce the most? If we look at bread, France can produce _____ whereas, the U.S. can produce ______. Therefore we say that ___________ has the absolute advantage in bread. If we look at wine, France can produce _____ whereas, the U.S. can produce _______. Therefore, we say that _____________ has the absolute advantage in wine. But this leaves us with the U.S. producing both things and France producing nothing. That is not the real world. So let’s apply Comparative Advantage. Who is the Low France where 4 breads = 3 U.S. where 10 breads = 4 wines wines Opportunity Cost Producer? Bread Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one bread. Calculate the up to the cost of producing one bread. or the opportunity cost of one bread is ________ wines. or the opportunity cost of one bread is ________ wines. __________ Who is the Low France where 4 breads = 3 U.S. where 10 breads = 4 Document1 Page 3 of 9 Opportunity Cost Producer? Wine wines wines Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one wine. Calculate the opportunity cost of producing one wine. or the opportunity cost of one wine is________ breads. or the opportunity cost of one wine is________ breads. __________ Table 2.1 in the textbook already calculates these opportunity costs for you. We can see from Table 2.1 that the United States has the comparative advantage in the production of computers whereas Mexico has comparative advantage in the production of shirts. Figure 2.2 in the textbook shows these opportunity costs in a graph using a Production Possibilities Frontier. By definition, under self-sufficiency (autarky) your consumption is limited by your production. There is no way to ever consume beyond what you directly produce without trade. Your production possibilities curve defines your available consumption set and it is strictly limited to what you produce. Is there a way to consume beyond your own production possibilities curve? The answer is yes and it occurs through trade. Remember that trade allows people to specialize. Through specialization we become more efficient and better at what we do. Trade also greatly expands the scope and types of operations that can occur in complex economy. Think about the multitude of products that you use on a daily basis that you obtained through trade. As a thought experiment, simply take everything that you were wearing or you have in your Document1 Page 4 of 9 possession and ask this simple question: Which of these goods and services did I make? And if I didn't make them how did I get them? And what would YOUR world the central authorities banned you from trading? We might, as did 19th century economist Carl Menger, refer to this as a “round-about method of production.” Here is a famous example out of Stephen Landsburg’s book The Armchair Economist. [T]here are two technologies for producing automobiles in America. One is to manufacture them in Detroit, and the other is to grow them in Iowa. Okay… how does that work? First you plant seeds, which are the raw material from which automobiles are constructed. You wait a few months until wheat appears. Then you harvest the wheat, load it onto ships, and sail the ships eastward into the Pacific Ocean. After a few months, the ships reappear with Toyotas on them. Now your book introduces labor into the equation, and allows for specialization and trade. Assume that there are 24 units of labor in both countries, and that both countries assigned 12 units of labor to shirts and 12 units of labor to computers. QLMEX = 24, QLUS = 24 QLMEX,shirts = 12, QLMEX,computers = 12 QLUS,shirts = 12, QLUS,computers = 12 Production MEXICO U.S. WORLD Document1 No Specialization with No Trade Computers Shirts 1 6 12 12 13 18 Page 5 of 9 Production MEXICO U.S. WORLD Specialization with No Trade Computers Shirts 0 12 14 10 14 22 Note here that just through specialization in PRODUCTION we increase the number of computers in the world by one while simultaneously increasing the number of shirts by four. Why did this occur? Because we increase efficiency by moving production to the low opportunity cost producers. Net world production rises and the world is made better off! Now let's allow the two countries to trade and focus for a moment on consumption. Let's s introduce trade and allow the United States to give up one computer in exchange for three shirts from Mexico. Now the production is the same BUT CONSUMPTION is divorced from PRODUCTION! Consumption MEXICO U.S. WORLD Specialization with Trade Computers Shirts 0+1=1 12 – 3 = 9 14 -1 = 13 10 + 3 = 13 14 22 Now we can introduce wages. Wages are already included really within the model but we can become a bit more specific here. One assumption we have to make to Document1 Page 6 of 9 simplify our analysis is that there is an average wage in each industry and some price. We will also assume a price of shirts relative to computers that is 3 to 1 to match the trade we show in the table above. To do this we set: Pshirts = $100 and Pcomputers = $300 We can then calculate the average wage in each country by finding out the total consumption and dividing by the number of workers. No Specialization and No Trade (Autarky) Consumption for Mexico = [(Q computers X Pcomputers) + (Q shirts X Pshirts)] Consumption for Mexico = [(1 computers X $300) + (6 shirts X $100)] Consumption for Mexico = $300 + $600 = $900 Avg Wage for Mexico = $900/QL = $900/24 = $37.50 Consumption for U.S. = [(Q computers X Pcomputers) + (Q shirts X Pshirts)] Consumption for U.S. = [(12 computers X $300) + (12 shirts X $100)] Consumption for U.S. = $3,600 + $1,200 = $4,800 Avg Wage for Mexico = $4,800/QL = $4,800/24 = $200.00 Specialization AND Trade (Autarky) Consumption for Mexico = [(Q computers X Pcomputers) + (Q shirts X Pshirts)] Consumption for Mexico = [(1 computers X $300) + (9 shirts X $100)] Consumption for Mexico = $300 + $900 = $1,200 Avg Wage for Mexico = $1,200/QL = $1,200/24 = $50.00 Document1 Page 7 of 9 Consumption for U.S. = [(Q computers X Pcomputers) + (Q shirts X Pshirts)] Consumption for U.S. = [(13 computers X $300) + (13 shirts X $100)] Consumption for U.S. = $3,900 + $1,300 = $5,200 Avg Wage for Mexico = $5,200/QL = $5,200/24 = $216.66 COMPARE NO-TRADE (AUTARKY) to TRADE What happened to the wages in Mexico? They rose from $37.50 to $50.00 What happened to the wages in the U. S.? They rose from $200.00 to $216.67 Both sets of workers are better off and both countries are better off. The argument that small countries cannot trade with large countries is wrong. The argument that workers (generally) lose through trade, is also wrong. It is true that there are sectors of our economy – and their workers - that will be hurt by the opening up trade. This is always true when a group or sector has protected status and they lose that privilege (in this case, protection from the competition of foreign firms.) But, workers, on average in the U.S. will be made better off by being allowed to purchase and consume low opportunity cost goods (that now happen to be imported.) Note – there will be job losses in high opportunity cost industries. And from an efficiency stand point this is a good thing! What is the major argument we hear about competing with Mexican labor? That there is no way that American workers can compete with those low-wage workers in Mexico. Document1 Page 8 of 9 What do you think is the major argument that Mexicans here about competing with American labor? That there is no way that Mexican workers can compete with those high-productivity workers in America! Document1 Page 9 of 9