MSP neg 1NC T “Increase” means to become larger or greater in quantity Encarta 6 – Encarta Online Dictionary. 2006. ("Increase" http://encarta.msn.com/encnet/features/dictionary/DictionaryResults.aspx?refid=1861620741) in·crease [ in kr ss ] transitive and intransitive verb (past and past participle in·creased, present participle in·creas·ing, 3rd person present singular in·creas·es)Definition: make or become larger or greater: to become, or make something become, larger in number, quantity, or degree noun (plural in·creas·es) “Ocean development” is utilization of ocean resources, spaces, and energy JIN 98– Japan Institute of Navigation, “Ocean Engineering Research Committee”, http://members.j-navigation.org/e-committee/Ocean.htm 2. Aim of Ocean Engineering Committee Discussions of "Ocean Engineering" are inseparable from "Ocean Development." What is ocean development? Professor Kiyomitsu Fujii of the In the light of its significance and meaning, the term "Ocean Development" is not necessarily a new term. Ocean development is broadly classified into three aspects: (1) Utilization of ocean resources, (2) Utilization of ocean spaces, and (3) Utilization of ocean energy. Among these, development of marine resources has long been established as fishery science and technology, and shipping, naval architecture and port/harbour construction are covered by the category of using ocean spaces, which have grown into industries in University of Tokyo defines ocean development in his book as using oceans for mankind, while preserving the beauty of nature. Japan. When the Committee initiated its activities, however, the real concept that caught attention was a new type of ocean development, which was outside the coverage that conventional terms had implied. Violation---the plan doesn’t develop ocean resources, use space or energy – Just creates a form of framework Voting issue--Ground---resource-focus provides a stable and predictable direction for the topic and creates a balanced set of arguments for each side---depth of literature on energy resources, fishing, conservation, etc. is strong and creates high-quality debates Limits---other interpretations make all ocean activity topical – at best the aff is effectually topical – framework is a prerequisite to development Owen 3 – (Daniel Owen, Consultant to the UN Food and Agriculture Organization, “Legal And Institutional Aspects Of Management Arrangements For Shared Stocks With Reference To Small Pelagics In Northwest Africa”, FAO Fisheries Circular No. 988, http://www.fao.org/docrep/006/y4698b/y4698b04.htm) .2 The legal regime for management of shared stocksFor a stock shared between two or more neighbouring coastal States and not ranging onto the high seas, the regime of Art 63(1) LOSC is appropriate. It states that:Where the same stock or stocks of associated species occur within the exclusive economic zones of two or more coastal States, these States shall seek, either directly or through appropriate subregional or regional organizations, to agree upon the measures necessary to coordinate and ensure the conservation and development of such stocks without prejudice to the other provisions of this Part. Regarding the term “development”, Nandan, Rosenne and Grandy[4] state that: The reference to “development”... relates to the development of those stocks as fishery resources. This includes increased exploitation of little-used stocks, as well as improvements in the management of heavily-fished stocks for more effective exploitation. Combined with the requirement in article 61 of not endangering a given stock by overexploitation, this envisages a long-term strategy of maintaining the stock as a viable resource. Military CP Counterplan Text: The Department of Defense should establish a national coordinated coastal and marine spatial planning system for the ocean. Only the Navy’s participation in CMSP will be able to solve for conflict Schregardus 14 (Donald R. Schregardus, Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Navy, winter 2014, Currents, “Ocean Stewardship through Marine Spatial Planning”, http://greenfleet.dodlive.mil/files/2014/03/Win14_DASNE_Outlook.pdf, LM) Marine Spatial Planning represents a new and unique opportunity for the Navy to engage with our communities, states, and regions and other ocean stakeholders early in this voluntary planning process. By increasing communications and focusing on identifying complementary and sustainable uses for these areas, we avoid conflicts, improve regulatory efficiencies, and increase ocean productivity/ benefits. While there have been effective programs addressing these activities in some parts of the country, the National Ocean Policy represents a first attempt to conduct comprehensive, integrated planning that includes the federal family, states, tribes, and other stakeholders. Our country is struggling with escalating costs, duplicative activities, and conflicting priorities on ocean use. A comprehensive planning process, working with all stakeholders, provides an important venue for the Navy to protect national security equities while jointly working with of our federal, tribal, state, municipal, and neighborhood partners to responsibly utilize, manage and protect our ocean and Great Lakes resources. 4 DON represents the Department of Defense (DoD) on the National Ocean Council. We have established a formal executive steering group within DoD and the Joint Chiefs of Staff (JCS) comprised of senior executives and flag officers to ensure that DoD leadership is kept abreast of developments and contributes to national ocean policy implementation. Our primary objective is to ensure that operational, training, research and development, test and evaluation, environmental compliance, and homeland/national security equities are considered in developing national ocean policy and throughout the marine spatial planning process. The DoD, with special emphasis on the Navy and the unique role of the Army Corps of Engineers within the DoD, has interests in each of the nine Regional Planning Bodies (RPB). Accordingly, we have formally designated representatives for both the DoD and Joint Chiefs for each of the RPBs. These RPB representatives participate in planning activities and.coordinate activities internally to ensure consistency throughout the DoD. DoD and Navy leadership strongly support regional planning in the coastal and marine systems to both reduce spatial and temporal conflicts and to promote healthier and more resilient coasts and oceans. Additionally, the Navy has offered to serve as the federal co-lead for both the South Atlantic and the Gulf of Mexico RPBs given the level of Navy and other military service activities in the region. Together, these two RPBs largely coincide with the Area of Responsibility for our Southeast Regional Commander. Ptx Republicans will win the Senate now – they’re winning the mobilization race Jim Malone, 7-3-14, http://www.voanews.com/content/political-forecast-moregridlock/1950498.html Given that the chances for agreement on substantial legislation in Congress are now fleeting, both sides are ramping up their arguments for midterm voters. Democrats start with a huge disadvantage. A lot of their folks are much less inclined to turn out in midterm congressional elections than they are for a presidential contest. Obama and other Democrats are now heavily focused on encouraging core Democratic supporters, especially what they like to call the “rising electorate”, to get off their rumps and out to the polls in November. That rising electorate includes younger voters, especially unmarried women, as well as Hispanic and Asian-American voters. In fact, many Democrats see motivating younger unmarried women as the key to boosting turnout enough that it could save their majority in the U.S. Senate. There is general consensus among political analysts and pundit-types that Republicans appear to have a big advantage in holding on to their majority in the House of Representatives. In fact, by some estimates, they could add seats. The real battle is for control of the Senate, where 36 of the 100 seats are at stake. Republicans need to gain six Democratic seats to reclaim a majority. That would normally be a tall order in any election year but this year there are far more Democratic seats at stake than Republican, and many of the Democratic seats are in states where Republicans have an advantage. New policy is key to boost Democratic votes. No risk of a link turn – the Republican base is already mobilized Sargent 7/9 [Greg Sargent, Washington Post writer, “Morning Plum: Obama to set off bomb in middle of midterms”, http://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/plum-line/wp/2014/07/09/morning-plumobama-to-set-off-bomb-in-middle-of-midterm-elections/, 7/9/14] Now that Republicans have made it clear that they will not participate on any level in basic problem solving when it comes to our immigration crisis, it is now on Obama to determine just how far he can go unilaterally, particularly when it comes to easing the pace of deportations. This is going to be one of the most consequential decisions of his presidency in substantive, moral, and legal terms, and politically, it could set off a bomb this fall, in the middle of the midterm elections. I’m told there are currently internal discussions underway among Democrats over whether ambitious action by Obama could be politically harmful in tough races. According to two sources familiar with internal discussions, some top Dems have wondered aloud whether Obama going big would further inflame the GOP base, with little payoff for Dems in red states where Latinos might not be a key factor. I don’t want to overstate this: These are merely discussions, not necessarily worries. Indeed, some Dems are making the opposite case, and that argument is described well in a new Politico piece out this morning. The story notes that Obama has privately told immigration advocates demanding ambitious action that they might not get what they advocates still hope for aggressive action and believe Dems see it as in their own political interests: Adding to the elevated hopes about what Obama will do is the feeling among Democratic strategists that immigration reform is a clear political winner: The people who will be opposed to reform or to the president taking action on his own are already likely prime Republican base voters. But voters whom Obama might be able to activate, both among immigrant communities and progressives overall who see this issue as a touchstone, are exactly the ones that Democrats are hoping will be there to counter a midterm year in which the map and historical trends favor GOP turnout. want, telling them: “We need to right-size expectations.” And yet, according to Politico, some Ocean regulation is empirically popular with the democratic base Hotakainen 11 ROB HOTAKAINEN, 4 October 2011, Congress spars over 'ocean zoning', http://www.mcclatchydc.com/2011/10/04/126154/congress-spars-over-ocean-zoning.html WASHINGTON — House members clashed Tuesday over a White House plan that essentially calls for zoning the oceans, with Republicans charging that it already has created more job-killing bureaucracy and Democrats saying it could give Americans more certainty on how they can use busy public waters. "It has the potential to stunt economic growth and the jobs associated with that growth," said Rep. Doc Hastings, R-Wash., chairman of the House Natural Resources Committee. Rep. Ed Markey of Massachusetts, the top-ranked Democrat on the panel, likened the idea — formally known as marine spatial planning — to making plans for air space. "Opposing ocean planning is like opposing air-traffic control," he said. GOP win immigration reform May, 5-22 (Caroline May, 22 May 2014, IMMIGRATION MAY COME BACK WITH A VENGEANCE IN 2015, http://www.breitbart.com/Big-Government/2014/05/22/Immigration-May-Come-Back-With-AVengeance-In-2015) Republicans are already in the beginning stages of planning their legislative agenda if they take control of the Senate in November, and many say immigration reform would be a top priority, even while President Obama's trustworthiness as a legislative partner remains in doubt. “I don’t know anyone who thinks the immigration system is working the way it should, so we’re gonna have some ideas and we’re going to move them across the floor in smaller consensus — on a consensus basis. And not the sort of divisive, all-or-nothing, pig-in-the-python sort of method,” Senate Minority Whip John Cornyn told Breitbart News last week when asked about the prospect of a GOP-controlled Senate pushing its own immigration reform agenda. Days earlier, Florida Republican Sen. Marco Rubio said Republicans would “absolutely” try to pass better immigration reform legislation if the GOP wins the Senate in November. Even some noted anti-amnesty hawks sounded relatively optimistic. “I think there is a better prospect that we would go forward with some immigration initiative if the Republicans control the Senate, but we still have the problem of trusting the president. But I think we’d be in a better position to try and enforce the law if we have both the House and the Senate,” Texas Republican Lamar Smith told Breitbart Tuesday. House Republicans are quick to point out the lack of confidence many have in the Obama administration’s willingness to fully implement what Congress passes. South Carolina Republican Rep. Trey Gowdy noted that the GOP has controlled the Senate before without passing immigration reform and alluded to concerns about Obama’s lack of enforcement of immigration law. Immigration reform key to the economy Kelley and Wollgin, 11 (Angela Maria Kelley, Vice President for Immigration Policy at American Progression, and Philip Wolgin, Senior Policy Analyst on the Immigration Policy team at American Progress, 9-29-11 “10 Reasons Why Immigration Reform Is Important to Our Fiscal Health,” http://www.americanprogress.org/issues/immigration/news/2011/09/29/10375/10-reasons-whyimmigration-reform-is-important-to-our-fiscal-health/-- WH) Here are the top 10 reasons why immigration reform, or the lack thereof, affects our economy.¶ Additions to the U.S. economy¶ 1. $1.5 trillion—The amount of money that would be added to America’s cumulative gross domestic product—the largest measure of economic growth—over 10 years with a comprehensive immigration reform plan that includes legalization for all undocumented immigrants currently living in the United States.¶ 2. 3.4 percent—The potential GDP growth rate over the past two years if comprehensive immigration reform had gone into effect two years ago, in mid2009. (see Figure 1)¶ figure 1¶ 3. 309,000—The number of jobs that would have been gained if comprehensive immigration reform had gone into effect two years ago, in mid-2009. A GDP growth rate of 0.2 percent above the actual growth rate translates into, based on the relationship between economic growth and unemployment, a decrease in unemployment by 0.1 percent, or 154,400 jobs, per year.¶ 4. $4.5 billion to $5.4 billion—The amount of additional net tax revenue that would accrue to the federal government over three years if all undocumented immigrants currently living in the United States were legalized.¶ Revenue generated by immigrants¶ 5. $4.2 trillion—The amount of revenue generated by Fortune 500 companies founded by immigrants and their children, representing 40 percent of all Fortune 500 companies.¶ 6. $67 billion—The amount of money that immigrant business owners generated in the 2000 census, 12 percent of all business income. In addition, engineering and technology companies with at least one key immigrant founder generated $52 billion between 1995 and 2005 and created roughly 450,000 jobs.¶ Taxes generated by immigrants¶ 7. $11.2 billion—The amount of tax revenue that states alone collected from undocumented immigrants in 2010.¶ Negative consequences of mass deportation¶ 8. $2.6 trillion—The amount of money that would evaporate from cumulative U.S. GDP over 10 years if all undocumented immigrants in the country were deported.¶ 9. 618,000—The number of jobs that would have been lost had a program of mass deportation gone into effect two years ago, in mid-2009. A mass deportation program would have caused GDP to decrease by 0.5 percent per year, which, based on the relationship between economic growth and unemployment, translates to an increase in unemployment by 0.2 percent, or 309,000 jobs, per year.¶ 10. $285 billion— The amount of money it would cost to deport all undocumented immigrants in the United States over five years.¶ The upshot¶ Most Americans and their elected representatives in Congress would be pleasantly surprised to learn about the substantial benefits of comprehensive immigration reform to our nation’s broad-based economic growth and prosperity, and thus our ability to reduce our federal budget deficit over the next 10 years. Given how difficult a challenge the super committee faces, we cannot afford to ignore any viable options for strengthening our economy. We hope the super committee takes these top 10 economic reasons into account as they move forward with their deliberations. Bio-D MSP poorly represents fisheries and other stakeholders Jentoft and Knol 14(Svein and Maakie, work at the Norwegian College of Fishery Science Faculty of Biosciences, Fishereies and Economics University of Trosmo, “Marine spatial planning:risk or opportunity for fisheries in the north sea”, January 8th online:http://www.maritimestudiesjournal.com/content/13/1/1) As Toonen and Mol (2013) illustrate in their article about the Dutch North Sea plaice fishery, being able to table good maps is crucial in many cases. Stakeholders who are unable to do so are more likely to be pushed aside by those who can and are more powerful. If fishers cannot provide a credible map that exemplifies their fishing grounds and spatial needs, they are more likely to be displaced when, for instance, a location for wind parks is being researched (Smith and Brennan 2012). A problem for fishers is that their geographical focus is less static than the focus of most other users. This also explains some of their resistance toward mapping in MSP. They fear that their much needed mobility will be reduced as they might become bound by their own maps. In the same way that maps might fence other usergroups out, they may also fence user groups such as fishers in. Thus a map is not just neutral representation of land-or seascape features and uses. They have economic, social and political consequences that raise issue of social justice. As observed by Nietschmann (1997): “Maps are power. Either you will map or you will be mapped. Still there is a need to be cautious. MSP may not appear to be a win-win. On the contrary, for the least powerful stakeholders, those who are poorly represented and who have few resources to back up their claims, they risk being ignored in the planning process. For them MSP may add further pressure and result in a loss. As illustrated in this paper, there is reason to assume that fishers and their communities may be within this group of stakeholders. MSP is a governance mechanism that may provide a more secure tenure but it also involves the risk of losing it, for instance as a result of spatial mapping. They have therefore reason to be ambivalent regarding this new tool and how it works from a fisheries governance perspective.¶ Leaving stakeholders to fight for space on their own is a recipe for social and ecological failure. It would also have implications regarding social justice as some user-groups do not only have more urgent needs and stakes than others, but their powers to protect their interests, define the problems, and shape the planning process are not equally distributed. Fisheries have large stakes but relative to other users such as the oil or shipping industry, they are a small player risking to be displaced. Therefore, spatial ordering through zoning is necessary also as a protective measure, but territorial boundaries cannot always be impenetrable, especially for fishers who need to remain mobile. Ocean biodiversity is getting better now– disproves their impact Panetta 13 (Leon Panetta , former US secretary of state, co-chaired the Pew Ocean Commission and founded the Panetta Institute at California State University, Monterey Bay, “Panetta: Don't take oceans for granted,” http://www.cnn.com/2013/07/17/opinion/panettaoceans/index.html, 7/17/13, 7/23/14, MEM) Our oceans are a tremendous economic engine, providing jobs for millions of Americans, directly and indirectly, and a source of food and recreation for countless more. Yet, for much of U.S. history, the health of America's oceans has been taken for granted, assuming its bounty was limitless and capacity to absorb waste without end. This is far from the truth. The situation the commission found in 2001 was grim. Many of our nation's commercial fisheries were being depleted and fishing families and communities were hurting. More than 60% of our coastal rivers and bays were degraded by nutrient runoff from farmland, cities and suburbs. Government policies and practices, a patchwork of inadequate laws and regulations at various levels, in many cases made matters worse. Our nation needed a wake-up call. The situation, on many fronts, is dramatically different today because of a combination of leadership initiatives from the White House and old-fashioned bipartisan cooperation on Capitol Hill. Perhaps the most dramatic example can be seen in the effort to end overfishing in U.S. waters. In 2005, President George W. Bush worked with congressional leaders to strengthen America's primary fisheries management law, the Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act. This included establishment of science-based catch limits to guide decisions in rebuilding depleted species. These reforms enacted by Congress are paying off. In fact, an important milestone was reached last June when the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration announced it had established annual, sciencebased catch limits for all U.S. ocean fish populations. We now have some of the best managed fisheries in the world. Progress also is evident in improved overall ocean governance and better safeguards for ecologically sensitive marine areas. In 2010, President Barack Obama issued a historic executive order establishing a national ocean policy directing federal agencies to coordinate efforts to protect and restore the health of marine ecosystems. President George W. Bush set aside new U.S. marine sanctuary areas from 2006 through 2009. Today, the Papahanaumokuakea Marine National Monument, one of several marine monuments created by the Bush administration, provides protection for some of the most biologically diverse waters in the Pacific. Tons of environmental improvements now --- not on the brink of collapse Mandell 12 (Erik Mandell is an intern for Global Envision and a current graduate student at Portland State University. He graduated from Middlebury College in Vermont and has traveled extensively to numerous countries and six of the seven continent, Global Envision, DON'T PANIC, ENVIRONMENTALISTS: A RICHER WORLD CAN BE A BETTER ONE, http://www.globalenvision.org/2012/09/11/dont-panic-environmentalists-richer-world-can-be-better-one, 9/11/12, 7/23/14, MEM) 3. Certain threatening pollution trends have halted. Specific pollutants, including DDT, lead, mercury and pesticides, which were predicted to spike in the report, “haven’t gotten more deadly, and the risk of death from air pollution is predicted to continue to drop” due to environmental regulations, Lomborg says.¶ The second problem with “Limits to Growth,” Lomborg argues, is that while its three primary predicted drivers of collapse have proven incorrect, it shaped how people think about environmental policy and behavior in a way that led to responses that actually do little to help, and in fact exacerbate problems by focusing away from economic growth.¶ Supposed solutions are often just “feel-good gestures that provide little environmental benefit at a significant cost,” writes Lomborg. Recycling paper cuts demand for tree farming, he says, tree farming which replants trees because it's profitable to do so. Without that demand, those forests are more likely to be turned into slash-and-burn farming tracts. Organic farming is less efficient and so drives up agricultural costs, which lowers consumption of healthy produce for those who can't afford it.¶ What should we have chosen to focus on for well-being instead? Lomborg puts it in simple terms, writing that “poverty is one of the greatest of all killers, and economic growth is one of the best ways to prevent it.” Painting growth as the antithesis of improved well-being, as he argues that “Limits to Growth” did, caused people to see growth as the core problem, rather than an important part of the solution.¶ Alarmism, he said, creates a lot of attention but makes realistic policy solutions hard to achieve. For example, “Limits to Growth” and other publications directed significant attention to specific pesticides like DDT, but led to little action on the broader issue of air pollution. He compares the alarmism triggered by “Limits to Growth” to crying wolf: real, dangerous wolves exist, but they are often overlooked due to false cries. For much of the world, the wolf at the door isn't environmental cataclysm—it's old-fashioned poverty. Changes in biodiversity are inevitable – the impact can be managed Ellis 13 (Erle C. Ellis, Associate professor of geography and environmental systems, University of Maryland, PhD at Cornell University, Jon Moen;editor, Umea University, Sweden, “All Is Not Loss: Plant Biodiversity in the Anthropocene”, PLOS ONE is an international, peer-reviewed, open-access, online publication and welcomes reports on primary research from any scientific discipline, http://www.plosone.org/article/info:doi/10.1371/journal.pone.0030535, 1/17/13, 7/23/14, MEM) In the Anthropocene, anthropogenic changes in biodiversity are neither temporary nor fully avoidable: they are the inevitable, predictable and potentially manageable consequences of sustained human residence and use of land together with the interactive effects of global climate change [2], [4], [7], [22], [23]. This study presents the first spatially explicit integrated assessment of the anthropogenic global patterns of vascular plant species richness created by the sustained actions of human populations and their use of land at regional landscape scale [24]. To accomplish this, a set of basic global models and estimates of anthropogenic species gains and losses were used to predict contemporary global patterns of plant species richness within regional landscapes, which we define here by stratifying Earth's ice-free land surface into equal-area hexagonal grid cells of 7800 km2, a spatial scale well within the size range of the regional landscape units generally used to characterize regional and subregional patterns in biodiversity at the global scale [24]. We then use these modeled and estimated richness data to explore what these can tell us about the global patterns of plant species richness created by human populations and their use of land across biomes, anthromes, biogeographic realms, and biodiversity hotspots. Overfishing Fish stocks are high now- ecosystems are resilient Lindsay 12 (Jay Lindsay, Content Strategist and Writer at CXO Communication, “U.S. Fish Stocks Rebound, Report Says”, http://www.weather.com/news/fish-stocks-rebound-20120515, 5/15/12, MEM) BOSTON -- A record number of fish populations have been rebuilt in U.S waters, even as problems continue to threaten the future of the high-profile New England fishing industry, according to a federal report. Six species considered overfished have rebuilt to optimal population levels in waters from the Bering Sea to the Atlantic Coast, according to the annual report to Congress by the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration's fisheries arm. The report also said just 45 of 219 fish populations (21 percent) were considered overfished in 2011. Still, 13 of those stocks are in New England. That's the most, by far, of any geographic region. Emily Menashes, acting director of NOAA's sustainable fisheries office said, overall, the report shows, "We are turning the corner on ending overfishing." Gulf of Maine haddock are also among the six fish species now considered rebuilt. But New England is defying the positive trends and it's unclear how that can change, said NOAA's Galen Tromble. "It's a challenging situation and there aren't any easy solutions," he said. The report looks at fish populations on both coasts and off Alaska and Hawaii, using the most recent data, generally two to three years old, Menashes said. The six fish species now considered rebuilt include Bering Sea snow crab, Atlantic coast summer flounder, Gulf of Maine haddock, northern California coast Chinook salmon, Washington coast coho salmon and Pacific coast widow rockfish. In the last 11 years, 27 U.S. marine fish populations have been rebuilt, according to the report. Tromble said that reflects years of effort by fishery managers and sacrifice by fishermen to follow rebuilding plans started 10 or 15 years ago. "We're starting to see the results of those," Tromble said. Marine ecosystems are resilient Kennedy 02 (Victor, PhD Environmental Science and Director of the Cooperative Oxford Lab, 2002, “Coastal and Marine Ecosystems and Global Climate Change,” Pew, http://www.c2es.org/docUploads/marine_ecosystems.pdf, CH) There is evidence that marine organisms and ecosystems are resilient to environmental change. Steele (1991) hypothesized that the biological components of marine systems are tightly coupled to physical factors, allowing them to respond quickly to rapid environmental change and thus rendering them ecologically adaptable. Some species also have wide genetic variability throughout their range, which may allow for adaptation to climate change. New federal ACL’s mean overfishing stopped in the squo NOAA 12 (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, paper was written in cooperation with the U.S. Department of Commerce and the National Marine Fisheries Service,“Turning the Corner on Ending Overfishing U.S. Fisheries Reaches Historic Milestone in 2012” http://www.nmfs.noaa.gov/stories/2012/01/docs/Annual%20Catch%20Limits%20Fact%20Sheet%20Final.pdf, 2012, 7/22/14, MEM) In 2006 Congress made the bold decision to end overfishing once and for all by amending the Magnuson Stevens Fisheries Conservation and Management Act to require annual catch limits (ACLs) and associated accountability measures to be implemented for all federally managed fisheries in fishing year 2011. Through the commitment and tireless efforts of our fishermen, fishery management councils, scientists and managers, the U.S. is poised to achieve this historic milestone in natural resource management. As of December 31, 2011, 40 of the 46 fishery management plans had ACLs and corresponding accountability measures in place. The remaining six management plans will have ACLs in place that are affective in the 2012 fishing season. Full implementation of ACLs establishes a robust process of science-based management that monitors and responds to the needs of the resource to sustain its long-term use and the economies that rely on our fisheries. With the investment in stock assessments, cooperative research and innovation, and science-based management, the U.S. model of fisheries management has become an international hallmark for addressing the ecological and economic sustainability challenges facing global fisheries. No impact to overfishing—its exaggerated hype Baker 6/22 (Michael Van Baker, publisher and editor in chief for the sunbreak,“Is the Overfishing Crisis Oversold?”, The SunBreak, 6/22/12,http://thesunbreak.com/2012/06/22/is-the-overfishing-crisisoversold, 6/22/12, 7/22/14, MEM) HAS “THE INCREASINGLY ENERGETIC AND SOPHISTICATED FISHING INDUSTRY HAS LEFT THE WORLD’S OCEANS A SHAMBLES?” ASKS THE NEW YORK TIMES AT THE OUTSET OF ITS REVIEW OF OVERFISHING: WHAT EVERYONE NEEDS TO KNOW. AS IT TURNS OUT, THAT’S NOT A PARTICULARLY GREAT WAY OF FRAMING THE QUESTION, BECAUSE YOU CAN GET PAGES AND PAGES OF LEARNED AND CONTRADICTORY DEBATE ON HOW THE “WORLD’S” FISHERIES ARE DOING.¶ THE PRAGMATIC QUESTION IS, CAN WE AVOID SHAMBLING OCEANS? AND THIS BOOK ARGUES: YES, WE CAN.¶ NOW, IF YOU’RE NOT UP TO EVEN A SLIM BOOK ON OVERFISHING, ITS AUTHOR, DR. RAY HILBORN, GOT TO MAKE SOME OF ITS POINTS IN AN APRIL OP-ED IN THE TIMES, “LET US EAT FISH“–ORIGINALLY LESS IMPERATIVELY TITLED “THE UNHERALDED REVIVAL OF AMERICA’S FISH STOCK.”¶ THAT UNUSED TITLE IS IMPORTANT, BECAUSE WHEN HILBORN SAYS IN HIS ARTICLE THAT “THE OVERALL RECORD OF AMERICAN FISHERIES MANAGEMENT SINCE THE MID-1990S IS ONE OF IMPROVEMENT, NOT OF DECLINE,” THAT’S NOT BUT IT IS TO SUGGEST THAT THE U.S. MAY HAVE FOUND A WAY TO BREAK OUT OF THE VICIOUS CIRCLE THAT LEADS INVARIABLY TO COLLAPSE. (NOR IS IT JUST THE U.S.; IN HIS BOOK, HILBORN REFERENCES OTHER FISHERIES THAT HAVE FOUND “GOOD ENOUGH” MANAGEMENT METHODS, WHILE ACKNOWLEDGING THERE ARE PLENTY OF SPECTACULAR FAILURES OUT THERE.)¶ YOU COULD SAY THAT HILBORN IS “TALKING BACK” TO THE RHETORIC OF APOCALYPSE USED BY ENVIRONMENTAL GROUPS PUSHING FOR CLOSING AREAS TO FISHING ENTIRELY. THEIR MESSAGE IS THAT EVERYTHING WE HAVE TRIED HAS FAILED, SO IT’S TIME FOR DESPERATE MEASURES. TO QUOTE OCEANA: “85 PERCENT OF THE WORLD’S FISHERIES ARE NOW EITHER OVEREXPLOITED, FULLY EXPLOITED, SIGNIFICANTLY DEPLETED OR RECOVERING FROM OVEREXPLOITATION. NO MATTER WHICH CATEGORY IS CONSIDERED, THERE IS NO GOOD NEWS.”¶ BUT IT’S EQUALLY IMPORTANT TO STRESS THAT THERE IS SUCH A THING AS SUSTAINABLE FISHING BECAUSE AN ABSENCE OF BETTER OPTIONS HASN’T, HISTORICALLY, LED TO PEOPLE ADOPTING STRICT CONSERVATION SO MUCH AS IT HAS RESULTED IN A GENERAL SHRUG AS THE LAST WHATEVER IS USED UP.¶ FOR OVERFISHING, HILBORN, WHO ALSO WRITES PAPERS WITH TITLES LIKE “BAYESIAN TO GIVE THE WORLD’S FISHERIES A COATTAIL A+ IN MANAGEMENT.¶ HIERARCHICAL META-ANALYSIS OF DENSITY-DEPENDENT BODY GROWTH IN HADDOCK,” HAS TAKEN UP A MORE GENERAL-INTEREST TONE (THAT MAY BE THE GIFT OF HIS CO-WRITER ULRIKE HILBORN). IT’S INFORMATIONAL, MUCH DEPENDS UPON CONTEXT. HILBORN’S CONCERN IS NOT TO MAINTAIN A “NATURAL” STATE–WHATEVER THAT IS–BUT IS WITH “HARVESTING” AND “YIELDS.” SO YIELD OVERFISHING IS WHEN YOU TAKE MORE FISH THAN YOU SHOULD IF YOU WANT TO GET THE BEST HARVEST. IT DOESN’T MEAN EXTINCTION, STRUCTURED FOR EASY REFERENCE, WITH QUESTIONS AS SUBHEADS, BEGINNING WITH THE BIG ONE: WHAT IS OVERFISHING?¶ THOUGH IT CAN, IF PURSUED–BUT THE WEAKENED POPULATION SIMPLY DOESN’T PRODUCE AS MANY FISH AS IT WOULD OTHERWISE.¶ THEN THERE’S ECONOMIC OVERFISHING, WHEN YOU OVERSHOOT THE ECONOMIC RETURN, AND MAY BEGIN A RACE TO THE BOTTOM, WITH EACH PARTICIPANT EARNING LESS THE MORE FISH THEY TAKE. HILBORN SINGLES OUT ICELAND, NEW ZEALAND, AND NORWAY FOR THEIR STEWARDSHIP OF THE ECONOMIC COMMONS, AS WELL AS FOR AVOIDING YIELD OVERFISHING.¶ OFTEN, THESE TWO MODES OF OVERFISHING JOIN FORCES TO ALMOST ERADICATE A FISH POPULATION. AND IT’S NOT A NEW CONCEPT: HILBORN LOCATES AN 1877 REFERENCE TO “OVERFISHING” IN NATURE. BUT THIS WOULD ALSO BE A GOOD MOMENT TO POINT OUT THAT FISH POPULATIONS CAN FLUCTUATE DRAMATICALLY, AND THAT IS ALSO NATURAL. IF YOU COMPARE YEAR-OVER- WHAT IS IMPORTANT IS TO KEEP THE PERCENTAGE OF FISH TAKEN IN LINE WITH THE ACTUAL NUMBER OF FISH OUT THERE, WHICH IS EASIER SAID THAN DONE.¶ ONE IMPORTANT FACTOR IN DEVELOPING A FISHING MANAGEMENT STRATEGY, HILBORN NOTES, IS TO REALIZE THAT FISH REPRODUCE ON DIFFERENT TIMELINES (WHALES, BEING MAMMALS, ARE PARTICULARLY VULNERABLE TO OVERHUNTING). YOU CAN MORE OR LESS DRAW UP FORMULAS FOR TAKING SUSTAINABLE PERCENTAGES, BASED ON REPRODUCTION RATES AND GROWTH RATES. THE OPTIMAL TIME TO TAKE A FISH IS AFTER IT HAS REPRODUCED AND HAS REACHED ITS MATURE SIZE. IF YOU KNOW THAT, AND THE NUMBER OF FISH, IT’S JUST MATH.¶ UNFORTUNATELY, THERE’S AN OCEAN IN THE WAY THAT MAKES IT A CHALLENGE TO COUNT FISH PRECISELY. AND THAT OCEAN CONTAINS DIFFERENT ECOSYSTEMS IN WHICH YEAR FISH POPULATIONS, YOU MAY SEE A LOT OF VOLATILITY, BUT THAT DOESN’T ALWAYS HAVE TO DO WITH THE NUMBER OF FISH TAKEN. FISH REACT DIFFERENTLY TO DIFFERENT PRESSURES. HILBORN DISCUSSES THE COLLAPSE OF THE NEWFOUNDLAND COD FISHERY, BUT ALSO CONTRASTS THAT WITH AMERICAN AND EUROPEAN COD FISHERIES THAT STABILIZED AT A THEME THAT EMERGES IS SUCCESSFUL FISHERY MANAGEMENT WILL DEPEND UPON WHAT’S KNOWN IN SOFTWARE CIRCLES AS LOCALIZATION. YOU CAN’T ROLL OUT A ONE-SIZE-FITS-ALL PROGRAM DUE TO DIFFERENCES IN FISH AND FISHERPEOPLE HABITATS. WHAT WORKS IN THE U.S. BECAUSE OF LEGISLATION AND INFRASTRUCTURE MAY NOT WORK ELSEWHERE. (CONVERSELY, THE PERVERSE ECONOMIC INCENTIVES THAT EXIST IN A LOWER ABUNDANCE, AND THE BARENTS SEA AND ICELANDIC COD STOCKS, THAT NEVER COLLAPSED.¶ THE U.S.–CREATING A “RACE FOR FISH,” WHERE EACH BOAT TRIES TO HOOVER UP THE MAXIMUM–MAY NOT EXIST ELSEWHERE.)¶ CHILEAN CALETAS, FOR INSTANCE, USE A MORE “LOCAL-MOTION” ETHOS TO MANAGE FISHERY CATCHES–EACH HAS BEEN GRANTED THE RESPONSIBILITY TO EXCLUDE OTHERS FROM FISHING THEIR PATCH. WITH A LOCAL GROUP OF STAKEHOLDERS MANAGING THEIR WATERS, THINGS HAVE IMPROVED WITHOUT CENTRAL GOVERNMENTAL ENFORCEMENT. (THOUGH, AGAIN, NATURAL VARIABILITY IN FISH ABUNDANCE MAKES IT DIFFICULT–FISHING BOATS WILL ALMOST ALWAYS GO IN SEARCH OF “MISSING” FISH.)¶ HILBORN TACKLES RECREATIONAL FISHING (IS IT NEXT TO GODLINESS?), TRAWLING (IS IT PURE EVIL?), AND MARINE PROTECTED AREAS (HOW PROTECTIVE ARE THEY?). IF THIS IS YOUR FIRST REAL DIVE INTO THE TOPIC, YOU’LL BECOME INTIMATELY ACQUAINTED WITH COMPLEX THE ISSUES ARE.¶ IN CONCLUDING, HILBORN IS CAREFUL TO STEER AWAY FROM POLLYANNA PREDICTION; WHILE HE’S IMPRESSED WITH THE REBOUND HE’S SEEN IN FISHERIES WITH GOOD MANAGEMENT, THE WORLD IS STILL WEIGHTED TOWARD OVERFISHING. IF NOT CRITICALLY IN ALL CASES, CERTAINLY IN TERMS OF GETTING THE BEST YIELD FROM THE FISH POPULATIONS IN WHATEVER ABUNDANCE THERE ARE: “AT PRESENT ABOUT TWO-THIRDS OF STOCKS ARE BELOW THE ABUNDANCE LEVEL THAT WOULD PRODUCE MAXIMUM SUSTAINABLE YIELD.”¶ FOLLOWERS OF EUROZONE TROUBLES WILL NOT BE SURPRISED TO HEAR THAT, WITH EUROPEAN THE SUBJECT OF OVERFISHING IS A SUBJECT THAT ENGENDERS LIVELY DEBATE, AND HILBORN, WHILE WELL-KNOWN AND -RESPECTED, IS NOT THE LAST WORD, ESPECIALLY WHEN IT COMES TO HOW THE WORLD’S FISHERIES ARE ACTUALLY BEING MANAGED. BUT IF YOU’VE BEEN STARING AT YOUR GUIDE TO FISH THAT ARE OKAY TO EAT AND WONDERING WHETHER IT’S NOT EASIER TO GIVE UP FISH ENTIRELY, THIS FISHERIES, PART OF THE PROBLEM IS THE MANY DISPARATE STAKEHOLDERS WHOSE INTERESTS NEED TO BE HARMONIZED.¶ AS MENTIONED, BOOK HAS INSIGHTS THAT YOU DO NEED TO KNOW. Solvency 1. We can never fully understand the ecosystem because it is too complex Shucksmith and Kelly 5/0 (Rachel J. Shucksmith and Christina Kelly, Marine Spatial Planning Manager at NAFC Marine Centre “Data collection and mapping – Principles, processes and application in marine spatial planning”, published by Elvesier Marine Policy Journal, http://ac.els-cdn.com/S0308597X14001365/1-s2.0-S0308597X14001365-main.pdf?_tid=ff1d312a-0bb9-11e4-bacd00000aab0f6c&acdnat=1405385600_e0d187308a2cf5e87a7dee268613a084) Our incomplete understanding of the marine environment can be manifested in data sets which do not fully reflect all spatial and temporal elements of the uses and values associated with marine features. Data sets may be out of date or may not detail the effects of competition or co-dependency of outside actors [25,39]. Whilst data and mapping outputs can offer a useful baseline for further investigation it is important that the data's limitations and accuracy are fully recognized before it is used as a decision support tool in the MSP process or by third parties. In some cases data sets may only be suitable as baseline information and should not replace marine planner's or user's obligation to consult with stakeholders or preclude the need to collect new or more detailed data. An example of this complexity is examined by the authors in [25], who examine the drivers causing fisheries utilization. Changes in fishing patterns can be linked to regulation including spatial and non-spatial measures such as catch limits, rolling closures, zoning and MPAs [38]. They could also be linked to technological changes or advancements. The socio-economic benefits derived from fisheries locations at sea will be linked to an onshore community [25]. Whilst efforts can be made to map activities such as fishing grounds through participatory mapping, as external factors shape user choices data sets be subject to frequent temporal and spatial changes. Biophysical ecosystem features may also show temporal and spatial fluctuations caused by user–environment impacts, climate change and natural fluctuations (e.g., [40]). Historical records can be used as a baseline to guide further surveying [41]. Due to the complexity of the marine environment and temporal fluctuations it is unlikely that our understanding of the marine environment will ever be complete, regardless of the level of resource allocated to data collection, mapping and modelling. This incomplete understanding may limit the potential detail of future planning. Where data sets are limited strategic decision making will be limited to high level decision making. At a regional level it may be easier to collect more detailed data to provide fine scale guidance, however it is perhaps unrealistic and unnecessary for this level of detail to be collected at a national level. Where our knowledge or understanding of some uses is stronger than others, mapping outputs have the potential to create or reinforce bias towards certain types of use. Where there are significant data gaps and/or the data is out of date then the confidence of any mapping output is reduced. Projecting an incomplete understanding of the complexity of ecosystems and services into a 2-D map requires a number of assumptions and simplifications [39]. Robust strategies for dealing with complexity are therefore especially import for marine planners [3]. Inadequacies in the mapping process have the potential to further exclude certain groups or types of use from the MSP process. This may be of particular relevance to cultural ecosystem services which can be under-represented in mapping [25]. Therefore, whilst mapping can be an important tool for the management of the marine environment care should be taken in its use as a decision-support tool Many Obstacles to developing MSP Collier 13 (Briana W. Collier studied environmental law and policy at Vermont Law School and now works as an Environmental Protection Specialist with the National Park Service, “Orchestrating Our Oceans: Effectively Implementing Coastal and Marine Spatial Planning in the U.S.”, http://nsglc.olemiss.edu/sglpj/vol6no1/5-Collier.pdf, 2013, 7/22/14, MEM) Regions with little to no CMSP development face a number of obstacles including concern over increased bureaucracy where CMSP goals overlap with fisheries council or coastal zone management goals, concern over increased and perhaps overreaching federal authority and regulation in areas of state jurisdiction, and “planning fatigue.” Some CMSP proponents attribute these “marketing” problems to the uniqueness of the CMSP concept and the lack of understanding that still exists in the ocean and coastal policy-making community.312 Others note that industry is opposed to efforts that will bring more regulation, as can occur with zoning, because of the costs of compliance and uncertainty of when the rules will change.313 This uncertainty can interfere with industry’s investment-backed expectations, especially with fixed-point commerce such as oil rigs.314 In addition to general problems managers face in marketing CMSP to constituent groups, some major logistical hurdles remain in the way of CMSP progress. Many regions need more data collection to fill gaps, more ability to share and integrate data, and better collaboration vertically and horizontally across government agencies and levels of government. Lack of funding streams and staffing infrastructure to take on new tasks are also impediments to CMSP progress. The lack of funding is an important issue, especially considering recent tightening of the federal budget. NOAA continues to ask for funding to support CMSP efforts in its budget requests each year, and members of Congress continue to propose amendments to eliminate that funding stream. Funding will become an increasing importantly factor for regions as they continue to hire staff, form regional planning bodies, and attempt to craft CMS plans. Bio-D Rest of bio-D cards Numerous alt causes - coastal development, ocean acidification, warming Panetta 13 (Leon Panetta, former US secretary of state, co-chaired the Pew Ocean Commission and founded the Panetta Institute at California State University, Monterey Bay, “Panetta: Don't take oceans for granted,” http://www.cnn.com/2013/07/17/opinion/panettaoceans/index.html, 7/17/13, 7/23/14, MEM) Despite the strides made in the 10 years since the Pew Oceans Commission issued its report, challenges remain. Coastal development continues, largely unchecked, and wetlands and marshes continue to shrink. That exposes more than half of the Americans who live along the coasts to the physical and economic damage caused by increasingly high-intensity storms such as Hurricane Katrina and Superstorm Sandy. On top of that, major challenges that the commission could not see as clearly in 2003, including ocean acidification and rising ocean temperatures, further threaten some of our most valuable fisheries. The United States must pursue a broader, ecosystem-based approach to build resilience in our oceans and respond to future threats. Alternative causes to biodiversity lossInvasive Species Craig 12 (Robin Kundis Craig, S.J. Quinney College of Law, University of Utah, “Marine Biodiversity, Climate Change, and Governance of the Oceans”, lifeadrift.info/media/3483/martin_and_gregory_s_pnas.pdf, 5/18/12, 7/23/14, MEM) invasive species, which can opportunistically exploit coastal ecosystems that are already degraded and destroyed as well as causing new and independent stresses. As has been A third existing stressor is demonstrated repeatedly, from jellyfish in the Black Sea to zebra mussels in the Great Lakes, non-native species can quite successfully travel to new coasts in ships’ as many as 7,000 marine species may be transported in ballast water every day, including marine-facilitated human diseases such as cholera [12]. Invasive species also escape from aquariums or are intentionally introduced into new marine ecosystems [12]. Once introduced into new environments, invasive species can alter marine ecosystem function and ecosystem services and can reduce native biodiversity [2,12]. In some circumstances, the invader simply takes over the new ecosystem. As one ballast water [12]. According to estimates, extreme example, in the 1980s the comb jelly Mnemiopsis was introduced into the Black Sea through ballast water, where it bloomed prodigiously and devoured the base of the Black Sea food chain, devastating the anchovy population and most of the rest of the food web [13]. Marine pollution Craig 12 (Robin Kundis Craig, S.J. Quinney College of Law, University of Utah, “Marine Biodiversity, Climate Change, and Governance of the Oceans”, lifeadrift.info/media/3483/martin_and_gregory_s_pnas.pdf, 5/18/12, 7/23/14, MEM) A variety of sources of marine pollution affect marine biodiversity. In many parts of the world, for example, sewage discharges remain an important source of coastal pollution [14]. Nutrient pollution from on-land activities, such as runoff from farms that includes fertilizer or atmospheric deposition from power plants, can contribute to harmful algal blooms and marine hypoxic, or “dead,” zones [15]. Harmful algal blooms directly impact marine biodiversity by toxifying marine organisms, especially shellfish [15], while dead zones drive oxygen-dependent life away [15]. The number of dead zones in the ocean has doubled every decade since 1960, and a 2008 study identified more than 400 dead zones throughout the world [16].Diversity 2012, 4 228 Toxic pollution is also a substantial impairment to marine biodiversity. As the MEA noted, “the estimated 313,000 containers of low-intermediate emission radioactive waste dumped in the Atlantic and Pacific Oceans since the 1970s pose a significant threat to deep-sea ecosystems should the containers leak, which seems likely over the long term” [4] (p. 483). Moreover, toxic chemicals continue to reach the oceans through a variety of industrial processes discharging wastes into upstream waterways and through various forms of dispersed water pollution, such as atmospheric deposition and runoff. Several of these chemicals bioaccumulate in ocean organisms. For example, methyl mercury, the organic form of mercury, becomes more concentrated the further up the food web a species resides [17]. High-level marine predators such as tuna, swordfish, shark, and mackerel can end up with mercury concentrations in their bodies that are 10,000 times or more the ambient concentration of mercury in the water [18]. Indeed, mercury contamination is already prevalent in food fish [19–22]. Other toxic pollutants such as polychlorinated biphenyls (PCBs) also bioaccumulate and are considered a cause of increased mortality to marine mammals such as the beluga whales in the St. Lawrence River [23,24] and orcas off the west coast of the United States [25]. Plastic pollution also affects marine biodiversity. Floating plastic waste accounts for 80 percent or more of marine debris [25]. Various marine animals can become physically entangled in larger forms of plastic debris, leading to injury, dismemberment, and death [26,27]. Many marine species also consume plastic trash; plastic bags, it turns out, look a lot like jellyfish, which is a food item for sea turtles and other species, and other marine animals intentionally or accidentally consume plastic trash [26,27]. Once swallowed, the plastic can both inhibit adequate nutrition by taking up space in the digestive system and directly cause death by choking or through internal damage [28]. A 2011 study reported that at least 9.2 percent of fish in and below the Great Pacific Garbage Patch—a concentrated gyre of plastic pollution in the northern Pacific Ocean—had plastic debris in their stomachs, and the researchers estimated that fish in the North Pacific are ingesting 12,000 to 24,000 tons of plastic every year [29]. Investment in protecting biodiversity now IUCN 13 (IUCN, International Union for Conservation of Nature, “France and IUCN Enhance Their Efforts To Protect Global Diversity”, icun.org, http://www.iucn.org/?uNewsID=13119, 6/13/13, 7/23/14, MEM) Yesterday IUCN signed a new partnership agreement with France, which aims to support the Union's global biodiversity conservation work, focusing on sub-Saharan Africa, oceans and global governance of natural resources. Delphine Batho, Minister of Ecology, Sustainable Development and Energy, Victorin Lurel, Minister of Overseas France, Pascal Canfin, Deputy Minister for Development and Anne Paugam, CEO of the French Development Agency signed the agreement with IUCN, represented by Julia MartonLefèvre, its Director General. The partnership aims to bring significant progress in biodiversity conservation that is expected to be achieved by 2016. Initially signed in 2005 and renewed in 2009, the partnership agreement between France and IUCN has thus been extended for another four years, thereby strengthening France's commitment to protecting biodiversity, in accordance with its international engagements regarding the Convention for Biological Diversity (CBD). France will invest almost 8 million Euros in order to support actions in three major areas aimed at protecting global biodiversity: The conservation of biodiversity and the sustainable management of natural resources in sub-Saharan Africa; The governance of the Oceans and the protection of the marine, coastal and insular ecosystems, the EU overseas entities; Global biodiversity governance. No impact – previous mass extinctions prove NatGeo, ’12 (National Geographic, “Mass Extinctions, What Causes Animal Die Offs?”, science.nationalgeographic.com, https://science.nationalgeographic.com/prehistoric-world/massextinction, 2012, 7/23/14, MEM) More than 90 percent of all organisms that have ever lived on Earth are extinct. As new species evolve to fit ever changing ecological niches, older species fade away. But the rate of extinction is far from constant. At least a handful of times in the last 500 million years, 50 to more than 90 percent of all species on Earth have disappeared in a geological blink of the eye. Though these mass extinctions are deadly events, they open up the planet for new life-forms to emerge. Dinosaurs appeared after one of the biggest mass extinction events on Earth, the Permian-Triassic extinction about 250 million years ago. The most studied mass extinction, between the Cretaceous and Paleogene periods about 65 million years ago, killed off the dinosaurs and made room for mammals to rapidly diversify and evolve. Conservation groups solve for biodiversity and environment. Tryon 13(Brett Tyron, coordinator of Blue Flag in Canada, “The Blue Flag and Biodiversity – Keeping Canada au Naturel!”, Envoirnmentdefense.ca, inspiring environmental change, http://environmentaldefence.ca/blog/blue-flag-and-biodiversity%E2%80%93-keeping-canada-au-naturel, 6/13/13, 7/23/14, MEM) With such diversity of landscapes, habitats and ecosystems here in Canada, it is no wonder communities are so willing to work to preserve Canada, au naturel, through the Blue Flag program. In fact, environmental management is a core tenant of the Blue Flag program. Dedicated management committees are set up at Blue Flag sites to conduct environmental audits and to ensure that local habitats and sensitive natural areas are protected and managed sustainably. Programs like Blue Flag are critical to protecting and preserving Canada’s natural landscapes, coastal ecosystems, biodiversity, culture and heritage, and recreational areas. Personally, I’m proud and in awe of Canada’s natural diversity. With the help of the Blue Flag program, I think we can work to make sure that the True North strong and free, stays au naturel as well! Overfishing Rest of Overfishing cards Collapse of oceanic systems are exaggerated Scoop 06 (Science- technology news, “ Imminent collapse of ocean ecosystems refuted”, http://www.scoop.co.nz/stories/SC0612/S00038/imminent-collapse-of-ocean-ecosystems-refuted.htm, 12/15/06, 7/22/14, MEM) Friday 15 December 2006, Secretariat of the Pacific Community (SPC), Noumea – Research conducted by an international team of scientists, including SPC’s Oceanic Fisheries Programme Manager, Dr John Hampton, and reported in a paper published this week in Science, refutes claims that ocean ecosystems are on the brink of collapse. Although the new research finds significant decreases in abundance of some large pelagic (oceanic) fish stocks resulting from increased fishing, the picture is not nearly as gloomy as has been previously reported. The paper, entitled “Biomass, size and trophic status of toplevel predators in the Pacific Ocean”, is co-authored by Dr Hampton and three other well-known fisheries scientists: John Sibert of the University of Hawaii, Pierre Kleiber of NOAA Fisheries in Honolulu, and Mark Maunder of the Inter-American Tropical Tuna Commission (IATTC). Unlike the previous studies, which have made exaggerated claims concerning the impacts of fishing, this study analysed all available data assembled by SPC and IATTC for Pacific tuna fisheries from 1950 to 2004, to estimate the impact that fishing has had on Pacific fish populations in the past 50 years. The analysis finds that the situation of different types of top predators, such as tuna and sharks, varies considerably. “Recent claims of catastrophic reduction in the biomass of top-level predators and the collapse of oceanic food chains have attracted widespread attention and provoked alarm among the lay public,” reports the paper. Dr Hampton notes, “Alarmist and exaggerated claims of stock collapses based on inadequate analyses and data have attracted a lot of attention, but the situation is more complex than that. These reports are dangerous not only because they are wrong, but also because they detract attention from the real management problems facing pelagic fisheries in the Pacific.” No overfishing Economist 9 (Economist, offers authoritative insight on international news, politics, business, finance, science and technology, “Plenty More Fish in the Sea?”, 2009, 7/22/14, MEM) AN even gloomier ASSESSMENT CAME in an article by 14 academics in Science IN 2006. The accelerating EROSION OF BIODIVERSITY, OFTEN ASSOCIATED WITH OVERFISHING, presaged a "global collapse" to the point, in 2048, where all species currently fished would be gone, they said. Even MANY SCIENTISTS WHO ARE ALARMED BY THE EVIDENCE OF OVERFISHING FIND SUCH CONCLUSIONS CONTROVERSIAL. MOST NON-SCIENTISTS ARE UNMOVED. For a start, FISH APPEARS TO BE IN PLENTIFUL SUPPLY. Even cod is available; over 7m tonnes of cod-family (Gadidae) fish are caught each year. Sushi bars have spread across the world. To cater for the aversion to red meat, and a new-found need for omega-3 fatty acids, SUPERMARKETS AND RESTAURANTS BOAST OF "SUSTAINABLE" SUPPLIES, and sandwiches are reassuringly labelled "dolphin-friendly", however threatened the tuna within them may be. Best of all, for the ethical consumer, fish are now farmed (see box below). SALMON HAS BECOME so PLENTIFUL that people weary of its delicate taste. Moreover, FISHERMEN themselves SEEM SKEPTICAL OF ANY LONG-TERM SCARCITY. They clamour for bigger quotas and fewer fish dishes are on every menu, even in steak houses. restrictions (except on foreign competitors), and complain that the scientists are either ignorant or one step behind the new reality. Those with long memories can PREVIOUS COLLAPSES that HAVE BEEN FOLLOWED BY RECOVERIES. AND, in truth, NOT ALL COLLAPSES ARE DUE solely TO OVERFISHING: the sudden crash of California's sardine industry 60 years ago is now thought to have been partly caused by a natural change in the sea temperature. PLENTY OF FIGURES seem to SUPPORT THE OPTIMISTS. Despite the exploitation round its coasts, BRITAIN, for instance, STILL LANDED 750,000 TONNES OF ATLANTIC FISH IN 2006, twocite thirds of what it caught in 1951; even cod is still being hauled from the north-east Atlantic, mostly by Norwegians and Russians. Some British fishing communities— Fraserburgh, for example—are in a sorry state, but others still prosper: the value of wet fish landed in Shetland, for example, £54m ($33m-99m) in 2006. ROSE FROM £21m in 1996 to EARNINGS FROM FISHING IN ALASKA, in whose waters about half of America's catch is taken, rose from less 2002 TO 2007 than $800m in nearly $1.5 billion in . And for the world as a whole, the catch in 2006 was over 93m tonnes, according to the UN's Food and Agriculture Organisation, compared with just 19m in 1950 (see chart on next page). Its value was almost $90 billion. Alternative causalities1. Subsidies Oceana 08 (Oceana.org, Over 80 percent of fisheries overfished: Report”, http://oceana.org/sites/default/files/o/fileadmin/oceana/uploads/Oceana_in_the_News/05.27.08.AFP.pdf, 2008, 7/22/14, MEM) GENEVA (AFP) — More than 80 percent of the world's fisheries are at risk from over-fishing and the World Trade Organisation must act urgently to scrap unsustainable subsidies, lobby group Oceana said Monday. "The world's fishing fleets can no longer expect to find new sources of fish," said Courtney Sakai, senior campaign director at Oceana. "If the countries of the world want healthy and abundant fishery resources, they must improve management and decrease the political and economic pressures that lead to overfishing." Based on data from the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organisation, the report found that only 17 percent of the world's known fish stocks are under-exploited or moderately exploited. Particularly overfished are stocks in significant parts of the Atlantic Ocean, the Western Indian Ocean and the Northwest Pacific Ocean. The report said that in the Western Indian Ocean, for example, over 70 percent of known stocks have been fully exploited, while the remainder are overexploited, depleted or currently at a stage of recovery. Oceana also notes that emerging fishing grounds have large numbers of stocks with unknown status, saying that it opens them up to the risk of overfishing and depletion. The group estimated that current fishing subsidies are worth at least 20 billion dollars annually, or the value of 25 percent of the world's catch, giving strong economic incentives for overfishing. "The scope and magnitude of these subsidies is so great that reducing them is the single greatest action that can be taken to protect the world's oceans," according to the group. It urged countries to push to "reduce and control subsidies" during the current World Trade Organisation negotiations on fisheries subsidies. The WTO last November proposed the elimination of most subsidies for the fishing industry in a compromise package. 2. Too many boats VOA 09 (Voice of America, “Overfished Vietnam Subsidizes More Fishing Boats”, http://www.voanews.com/content/a-13-2008-05-08-voa15-66819052/374339.html, 10/27/09, 7/22/14, MEM) There are a 100,000 fishing boats in Vietnam - too many, say conservation experts, who warn of overfishing in Vietnam's coastal waters. But Vietnamese fishermen are hurting from rising fuel prices. To help them, the government is offering subsidies to build even more boats. Matt Steinglass reports from Hanoi. Vietnamese fisherman works on a basket-shaped boat locally called Thuyen Thung at a fishing village in Danang, Vietnam (File photo) Deputy Agriculture Minister Nguyen Van Thang told Vietnamese fishermen this week that the government will lend them a hand. Thang says any fisherman who buys a new boat with an engine of 90 horsepower or more will get a subsidy of about $3,500 a year. Thang says the subsidies will help fishermen to switch to more powerful boats that can fish further from shore. He says they will also soften the pain of high fuel prices Vietnam has nearly a 100,000 fishing boats. That is far too many, according to wildlife experts like Keith Symington of the international conservation group WWF, who say stocks of fish are declining. "In 2001, for tuna, on average 25 kilograms of tuna could be caught with 100 hooks on a long-line tuna boat. And in 2005, on average, that number's gone down to about 15. You have to fish harder to catch the same amount," said Symington. Overfishing like this could severely damage Vietnam's fisheries."In scientific terms they call it serial depletion. Which means you'll eventually hit a .But the new policy seemed to contradict Vietnam's official strategy of shrinking its fishing fleet. point where there's no recruitment of baby fish," he added. "And then there's really a crisis commercially extinct." . The fishery can become quickly Solvency Extra card MSP is terrible- 10 reasons why Natural Resources 11 (Committee of Natural Resources, “Top 10 Things to Know About President Obama’s Plan to Zone the Oceans”, http://naturalresources.house.gov/news/documentsingle.aspx?DocumentID=262435, 9/30/11, 7/22/14, MEM) Lacks Congressional Authorization. In four separate Congresses, legislation has been introduced to implement similar farreaching ocean policies, and to-date NO bill has passed the House or been reported out of a Committee. Unilateral Action. The Obama Administration has failed to cite any specific statutory authority for the Coastal and Marine Spatial Planning initiative. Instead, it throws up a smokescreen list of all statutes that impact the oceans and claims that is their authority. Imposes ‘Ocean Zoning.’ The Coastal and Marine Spatial Planning initiative is entirely new, mandatory ocean zoning that involves up to 27 Federal agencies and will cost the taxpayers millions, if not billions, in Federal spending. This initiative could place huge portions of the ocean off limits to all types of recreational and commercial activities. Threatens American Jobs. ‘Ocean zoning’ has the potential to damage sectors such as agriculture, commercial and recreational fishing, construction, manufacturing, marine commerce, mining, oil and natural gas, renewable energy, recreational boating, and waterborne transportation, among others. These industries support tens of millions of jobs and contribute trillions of dollars to the U.S. economy. Far-Reaching Impacts Not Limited to the Ocean. This new ‘ocean zoning’ authority would allow Federally-dominated Regional Planning Bodies to reach as far inland as it deems necessary to protect ocean ecosystem health. It specifically mentions the Great Lakes and could potentially impact all activities that occur on lands adjacent to rivers, tributaries or watersheds that drain into the ocean. Creates More Bureaucracy. The Executive Order creates: 10 National Policies; a 27-member National Ocean Council; an 18member Governance Coordinating Committee; and 9 Regional Planning Bodies. This has led to an additional: 9 National Priority Objectives; 9 Strategic Action Plans; 7 National Goals for Coastal Marine Spatial Planning; and 12 Guiding Principles for Coastal Marine Spatial Planning to be created. Tool for Litigation. The ‘ocean zoning’ initiative involves vague and undefined objectives, goals, and policies that can be used as fodder for lawsuits to stop or delay Federally-permitted activities. This initiative is poised to become a litigation nightmare. New Cost to Taxpayers. This new policy will affect already budget-strapped agencies such as NOAA, Department of Commerce, Department of the Interior, EPA, Department of Transportation, USDA, Homeland Security, and the Army Corps of Engineers. As Federal budgets are further reduced, it is unclear how much funding the agencies are taking from existing programs to develop and implement this new initiative. Those Impacted by Regulations Need Not Apply. The Regional Planning Bodies, created by the ‘ocean zoning’ initiative, will have no representation by the people, communities and businesses that will actually be impacted by the regulations. These heavily Federal bodies will create zoning plans without any stakeholders yet all Federal agencies, the States, and the regulated communities will be bound by the plan. New Regulatory Uncertainty. The impacts of this new regulatory layer and ‘ocean zoning’ initiative contribute to an uncertain regulatory climate that is hindering economic activity and job creation. Even the Interagency Task Force recognized this potential in their report stating, “The Task Force is mindful that these recommendations may create a level of uncertainty and anxiety among those who rely on these resources and may generate questions about how they align with existing processes, authorities, and budget challenges. The NOC (National Ocean Council) will address questions and specifics as implementation progresses.” In other words…don’t worry, trust us. Ptx Extra Links The commercial fishing industry hates the plan – excluded from MSP and their effect on fisheries Winn 11 (Pete, writer at CNS News, “Fishermen to Congress: Please Scuttle Obama’s National Oceans Policy,” Published November 17, 2011, http://cnsnews.com/news/article/fishermen-congress-pleasescuttle-obama-s-national-oceans-policy, CH) (CNSNews.com) – The nation’s commercial fishermen say the Obama administration is trying to impose top-down bureaucratic regulation on the use of the oceans and the nation’s fisheries, which they say will put fishing jobs at stake. A group calling itself the Seafood Coalition is calling on Congress to do what it can to scuttle President Obama’s National Ocean Policy National Ocean Policy, which the president unilaterally imposed by executive order in 2010. In a letter to the House Natural Resources Committee, the Seafood Coalition said that the president’s plan adds a needless level of top-down bureaucracy and regulation on fisheries. “The National Ocean Policy creates a federal ocean zoning regime that will likely result in substantial new regulations and restrictions on ocean users,” Nils Stolpe, spokesman for the Seafood Coalition, told CNSNews.com on Monday. The coalition says it is also concerned that the administration is going to take money away from programs that are currently working well to pay for the new layer of bureaucracy. “What we’ve asked for in our letter to the chairman was for Congress to use whatever funding capacity they have to stop this,” Stolpe said. The Seafood Coalition describes itself as a “broad national coalition of commercial fishing interests, seafood processors, and coastal communities” that includes members from every region of the U.S. and “accounts for about 85 percent of the fish and shellfish products landed annually in the U.S.” In July of 2010, President Obama signed the order establishing a National Policy for the Stewardship of the Ocean, Our Coasts, and the Great Lakes. The order directs all federal agencies to implement the Final Recommendations of the Interagency Ocean Policy Task Force, which was created by White House Council on Environmental Quality. The National Ocean Policy identifies nine objectives and outlines a “flexible framework” for how bureaucrats will “effectively address conservation, economic activity, user conflict, and sustainable use of the ocean, our coasts, and the Great Lakes.” One of the key objectives is called “coastal and marine spatial planning (CMSP)” -- which the executive order defines as “a comprehensive, adaptive, integrated, ecosystem-based, and transparent spatial planning process, based on sound science, for analyzing current and anticipated uses of ocean, coastal, and Great Lakes areas.” It added: “In practical terms, coastal and marine spatial planning provides a public policy process for society to better determine how the ocean, our coasts, and Great Lakes are sustainably used and protected -- now and for future generations.” But Stolpe and the Seafood Coalition said CMSP essentially means the imposition of top-down federal planning boards to govern ocean use. “It establishes a number of regional boards that in essence are in charge of what goes on in the oceans of those particular regions -- from a fishing perspective, from an energy development perspective, from a transportation perspective, from a recreational use perspective,” Stolpe said. The executive order also creates a National Oceans Council, headed by White House Science Adviser Dr. John Holdren and Council for Environmental Quality director Nancy Sutley, to oversee overall ocean planning. No one from the seafood industry will be part of the council, the coalition said. Fishermen fear that extremist environmental technocrats will take away their fishing rights Jonsson 10 (Patrick, staff writer for CSM, “Fishermen’s fear: Public's 'right to fish' shifting under Obama?,” Published March 9, 2010, http://www.csmonitor.com/USA/2010/0309/Fishermen-s-fearPublic-s-right-to-fish-shifting-under-Obama, CH) ATLANTA — The Obama administration has proposed using United Nations-guided principles to expand a type of zoning to coastal and even some inland waters. That’s raising concerns among fishermen that their favorite fishing holes may soon be off-limits for bait-casting. In the battle of incremental change that epitomizes the American conservation movement, many weekend anglers fear that the Obama administration’s promise to “fundamentally change” water management in the US will erode what they call the public’s “right to fish,” in turn creating economic losses for the $82 billion recreational fishing industry and a further deterioration of the American outdoorsman’s legacy. Proponents say the Interagency Ocean Policy Task Force established by President Obama last June will ultimately benefit the fishing public by managing ecosystems in their entirety rather than by individual uses such as fishing, shipping, or oil exploration. “It’s not an environmentalist manifesto,” says Larry Crowder, a marine biologist at Duke University in North Carolina. “It’s multiple-use planning for the environment, and making sure various uses … are sustainable.” (Amateur outdoorsmen have been fighting for their rights for years, as the Monitor reports here.) Faced with the prospect of further industrialization along America's coasts and the Great Lakes (wind turbines and natural-gas exploration, for example), the task force is charged with putting in place a new ecosystem management process called marine spatial planning. Marine spatial planning (MSP), according to the United Nations, is “a public process of analyzing and allocating the spatial and temporal distribution of human activities in marine areas to achieve ecological, economic, and social objectives that usually have been specified through a political process." That kind of government-speak scares Phil Morlock, director of environmental affairs at the reel-and-rod maker Shimano. Mr. Morlock points to references by the ocean task force to “one global sea” as evidence that what’s really being proposed are broad changes to America's user-funded conservation strategy, potentially affecting even inland waters. “I suggest that the task force recommend our model to the United Nations rather than us adopting the United Nations model,” he says in a phone interview. “The American model is the best in the world, so our question is: Why seek the lowest common denominator?” Mr. Obama has said he will not override protections put in place by Presidents Clinton and Bush that established recreational fishermen as a special class. But critics still worry about the Obama administration’s ties to environmental groups that espouse “anti-use” policies that put some habitats out of reach even for rod and reel fishermen, who take only 3 percent of America’s landed catch every year. “Angling advocates point out that senior policy officials on the task force seem inclined to ally themselves with preservationists and environmental extremists who want to create ‘no fishing’ preserves, with no scientific justification,” writes ESPN.com’s Robert Montgomery. On the other hand, nonpartisan experts say the task force has already made strides in better recognizing various stakeholder groups, including recreational fishermen, and that it doesn’t intend to undermine the ability of states to manage their natural resources, as many fishermen fear. “There’s been huge progress by the task force in terms of being more inclusive in thinking about economic, ecological, social, and political concerns,” says Mr. Crowder at Duke. “The paranoia – and there is paranoia on all sides – is that the process will be captured. My hope is that mutual concern gets people to the table.” The final report of the task force is expected in late March. Congress will decide its fate, unless Obama issues an executive order establishing MSP as the law of the water. Security 1NC Shell Attempts to gain spatial knowledge are projects of sovereign domination Steinberg 9 (Phillip E. - Department of Geography at Florida State University, “Sovereignty, Territory, and the Mapping of Mobility: A View from the Outside”, Annals of the Association of American Geographer, http://mailer.fsu.edu/~psteinbe/garnetpsteinbe/Annals%20Offprint2.pdf, JS) A key concept here, as stressed by Sahlins (1989), is¶ that the rise of the territorial state is characterized not¶ simply by the construction of its bounded territory as¶ a homogenous administrative zone (as Sahlins charges¶ that Allies [1980] and Gottman [1973] emphasize), but `¶ that the territorial state constructs its space as a differentiated set of points that are amenable to being plotted¶ (and thus manipulated and rationalized) against an abstract spatial grid (see also T. Mitchell 1991). Historically, the development of technologies and institutions for performing cadastral mapping and land surveying stand out as mechanisms through which the state has achieved a “bird’seye” view over territory as a means toward achieving social control over people (Bohannan 1964; Kain and Baigent 1992; Vandergeest and Peluso 1995; Edney 1997; Scott 1998; Biggs 1999). Thus, Biggs (1999) locates the origins of the territorial state in national surveying efforts of the seventeenth century. As surveyors mapped royal domains, they graphically noted each village’s affiliation. What had been thought of as a personal relationship came to be expressed as a territorial relationship, and, at the same time, surveyors imposed a grid of ¶ ¶ ¶ ¶ abstract space over the domain to¶ facilitate mapping. Eventually, these two phenomena¶ associated with surveying converged in an example of¶ what Pickles (2003) calls “overcoding”: The abstract, geometric space of the map came to define the lived in space of the state, and the territorial relationship between land and sovereign came to be seen as predicating the personal relationship between individual and sovereign. Other scholars have further illustrated the relationship between the way that we hierarchically map¶ space and the way that we hierarchically organize social relationships. Knowledge of space is a crucial tool for control, and the technologies of mapping (and the¶ underlying assumptions about society and space that enable modern mapping), joined with hierarchical systems for drawing lines and assigning names, play a crucial role in constructing instruments of sovereign domination (Akerman 1984, 1995; Carter 1987; Buisseret 1992; Ryan 1996; Edney 1997; Brotton 1998; Burnett 2000; Craib ¶ ¶ ¶ 2000; Hakli 2001; Harley 2001; Pickles 2003; ¨¶ Jacob 2006).4 In short, these scholars emphasize the key role that ¶ the ordering of space plays in the construction of state¶ territoriality. This is an important advance over a¶ perspective that simply looks at the bounding of space,¶ but, as Strandsbjerg (2008) notes, these scholars of the¶ cartographic origins of modern state sovereignty still¶ tend to analyze the state as an isolated unit. Given that¶ the modern institution of sovereignty necessarily exists¶ within a system of sovereign units, a study of the modern¶ state (or a story of its origins) that works only from the¶ perspective of the inward-looking aspect of sovereignty¶ cannot be complete. As Taylor (1995) asserts, the starting point of political geography (and political history)¶ must be a theory of the states rather than a theory of the state. In a similar vein, geographies and histories of territoriality (or the ordering of space) must examine not just the “emptiable” and “fillable” space constructed inside the territories of sovereign states but also the spaces on the outside that are designated as not being amenable to this organization of space. Otherwise, any study of ¶ ¶ state territoriality risks falling into the “territorial trap”¶ wherein states are viewed as internally coherent units,¶ existing ontologically prior to the overall ordering of¶ the state system, and wherein cross-border processes¶ can be viewed only as “international relations” among¶ these preexisting states (Agnew 1994; see also Sparke¶ 2005). Security politics authorizes limitless global destruction. Der Derian 98 (James, Professor of Political Science at the University of Massachusetts, On Security, Ed. Lipschutz, p. 24-25) No other concept in international relations packs the metaphysical punch, nor commands the disciplinary power of "security." In its name, peoples have alienated their fears, rights and powers to gods, emperors, and most recently, sovereign states, all to protect themselves from the vicissitudes of nature--as well as from other gods, emperors, and sovereign states. In its name, weapons of mass destruction have been developed which have transfigured national interest into a security dilemma based on a suicide pact. And, less often noted in international relations, in its name billions have been made and millions killed while scientific knowledge has been furthered and intellectual dissent muted. We have inherited an ontotheology of security, that is, an a priori argument that proves the existence and necessity of only one form of security because there currently happens to be a widespread, metaphysical belief in it. Indeed, within the concept of security lurks the entire history of western metaphysics, which was best described by Derrida "as a series of substitutions of center for center" in a perpetual search for the "transcendental signified." Continues... 7 In this case, Walt cites IR scholar Robert Keohane on the hazards of "reflectivism," to warn off anyone who by inclination or error might wander into the foreign camp: "As Robert Keohane has noted, until these writers `have delineated . . . a research program and shown . . . that it can illuminate important issues in world politics, they will remain on the margins of the field.' " 8 By the end of the essay, one is left with the suspicion that the rapid changes in world politics have triggered a "security crisis" in security studies that requires extensive theoretical damage control. What if we leave the desire for mastery to the insecure and instead imagine a new dialogue of security, not in the pursuit of a utopian end but in recognition of the world as it is, other than us ? What might such a dialogue sound like? Any attempt at an answer requires a genealogy: to understand the discursive power of the concept, to remember its forgotten meanings, to assess its economy of use in the present, to reinterpret--and possibly construct through the reinterpretation--a late modern security comfortable with a plurality of centers, multiple meanings, and fluid identities. The steps I take here in this direction are tentative and preliminary. I first undertake a brief history of the concept itself. Second, I present the "originary" form of security that has so dominated our conception of international relations, the Hobbesian episteme of realism. Third, I consider the impact of two major challenges to the Hobbesian episteme, that of Marx and Nietzsche. And finally, I suggest that Baudrillard provides the best, if most nullifying, analysis of security in late modernity. In short, I retell the story of realism as an historic encounter of fear and danger with power and order that produced four realist forms of security: epistemic, social, interpretive, and hyperreal. To preempt a predictable criticism, I wish to make it clear that I am not in search of an "alternative security." An easy defense is to invoke Heidegger, who declared that "questioning is the piety of thought." Foucault, however, gives the more powerful reason for a genealogy of security: I am not looking for an alternative; you can't find the solution of a problem in the solution of another problem raised at another moment by other people. You see, what I want to do is not the history of solutions, and that's the reason why I don't accept the word alternative. My point is not that everything is bad, but that everything is dangerous, then we always have something to do. The hope is that in the interpretation of the most pressing dangers of late modernity we might be able to construct a form of security based on the appreciation and articulation rather than the normalization or extirpation of difference. Nietzsche transvalues both Hobbes's and Marx's interpretations of security through a genealogy of modes of being. His method is not to uncover some deep meaning or value for security, but to destabilize the intolerable fictional identities of the past which have been created out of fear, and to affirm the creative differences which might yield new values for the future. Originating in the paradoxical relationship of a contingent life and a certain death, the history of security reads for Nietzsche as an abnegation, a resentment and, finally, a transcendence of this paradox. In brief, the history is one of individuals seeking an impossible security from the most radical "other" of life, the terror of death which, once generalized and nationalized, triggers a futile cycle of collective identities seeking security from alien others--who are seeking similarly impossible guarantees. It is a story of differences taking on the otherness of death, and identities calcifying into a fearful sameness. Vote neg and Reject the Aff’s security discourse – abandoning the attempt to eradicate insecurity is a prerequisite to meaningful political engagement. Neocleous 8 [Mark, Professor of the Critique of Political Economy at Brunel University, Critique of Security, p. 185-186] The only way out of such a dilemma, to escape the fetish, is perhaps to eschew the logic of security altogether – to reject it as so ideologically loaded in favour of the state that any real political thought other than the authoritarian and reactionary should be pressed to give it up. That is clearly something that can not be achieved within the limits of bourgeois thought and thus could never even begin to be imagined by the security intellectual. It is also something that the constant iteration of the refrain ‘this is an insecure world’ and reiteration of one fear, anxiety and insecurity after another will also make it hard to do. But it is something that the critique of security suggests we may have to consider if we want a political way out of the impasse of security.¶ This impasse exists because security has now become so all-encompassing that it marginalises all else, most notably the constructive conflicts, debates and discussions that animate political life. The constant prioritising of a mythical security as a political end – as the political end – constitutes a rejection of politics in any meaningful sense of the term. That is, as a mode of action in which differences can be articulated, in which the conflicts and struggles that arise from such differences can be fought for and negotiated, in which people might come to believe that another world is possible – that they might transform the world and in turn be transformed. Security politics simply removes this; worse, it removes it while purportedly addressing it. In so doing it suppresses all issues of power and turns political questions into debates about the most efficient way to achieve ‘security’, despite the fact that we are never quite told – never could be told – what might count as having achieved it. Security politics is, in this sense, an anti-politics,141 dominating political discourse in much the same manner as the security state tries to dominate human beings, reinforcing security fetishism and the monopolistic character of security on the political imagination. We therefore need to get beyond security politics, not add yet more ‘sectors’ to it in a way that simply expands the scope of the state and legitimises state intervention in yet more and more areas of our lives.¶ Simon Dalby reports a personal communication with Michael Williams, coeditor of the important text Critical Security Studies, in which the latter asks: if you take away security, what do you put in the hole that’s left behind? But I’m inclined to agree with Dalby: maybe there is no hole.142 The mistake has been to think that there is a hole and that this hole needs to be filled with a new vision or revision of security in which it is re-mapped or civilised or gendered or humanised or expanded or whatever. All of these ultimately remain within the statist political imaginary, and consequently end up re-affirming the state as the terrain of modern politics, the grounds of security. The real task is not to fill the supposed hole with yet another vision of security, but to fight for an alternative political language which takes us beyond the narrow horizon of bourgeois security and which therefore does not constantly throw us into the arms of the state. That’s the point of critical politics: to develop a new political language more adequate to the kind of society we want. Thus while much of what I have said here has been of a negative order, part of the tradition of critical theory is that the negative may be as significant as the positive in setting thought on new paths.¶ For if security really is the supreme concept of bourgeois society and the fundamental thematic of liberalism, then to keep harping on about insecurity and to keep demanding ‘more security’ (while meekly hoping that this increased security doesn’t damage our liberty) is to blind ourselves to the possibility of building real alternatives to the authoritarian tendencies in contemporary politics. To situate ourselves against security politics would allow us to circumvent the debilitating effect achieved through the constant securitising of social and political issues, debilitating in the sense that ‘security’ helps consolidate the power of the existing forms of social domination and justifies the short-circuiting of even the most democratic forms. It would also allow us to forge another kind of politics centred on a different conception of the good. We need a new way of thinking and talking about social being and politics that moves us beyond security. This would perhaps be emancipatory in the true sense of the word. What this might mean, precisely, must be open to debate. But it certainly requires recognising that security is an illusion that has forgotten it is an illusion; it requires recognising that security is not the same as solidarity; it requires accepting that insecurity is part of the human condition, and thus giving up the search for the certainty of security and instead learning to tolerate the uncertainties, ambiguities and ‘insecurities’ that come with being human; it requires accepting that ‘securitizing’ an issue does not mean dealing with it politically, but bracketing it out and handing it to the state; it requires us to be brave enough to return the gift.143 Extra links Mapping destroys intimacy with the ocean and turns renders it as a mere conceptual device for human purposes. Anderson and Peters 14 Dr Kimberley Peters Lecturer in Human Geography BSc (hons) Human Geography and Planning (Cardiff University) MA Cultural Geography (Royal Holloway, University of London) PhD (Royal Holloway, University of London) Filling the Watery Void The second key aim of this volume is to continue challenging the aforementioned and long standing configuration of the ocean as an empty space, established through processes of industrial and postindustrial capitalism. Moreover this book seeks to address the use of the sea as a mere conceptual device for understanding alternative socio-cultural and political phenomena, instead positioning the sea as a ‘an element of nature itself’ (Steinberg 2001: 167). As such, the chapters which follow each demonstrate the ways in which ocean is ‘filled’: through its own elemental composition, with morethanhuman life, with floating and sunken materialities, and with a range of human significance. Such an approach takes inspiration from non-Western perspectives of the water world. If we turn away from our modern, terrestro-centric view, we can begin to see how ‘other’ cultures conceive of the seas and oceans as practiced, embodied and lived spaces. For example, anthroplogist Bronislaw Malinowski demonstrates the importance of rituals at sea for societies on the Trobriand Islands in the Western Pacific region (1922). Here the land functions as a connection point whilst the ocean is encultured as a significant ritualized space, made meaningful through the ‘Kula’ system of gift-giving. Kula exchanges involve the sea-based exchange of two types of item (armshells and necklaces) between ‘Kula partners’ (Young 1979: 163). Articles are moved from island to island by seagoing canoes, and as such, seafaring has been integral to the custom, culture, and ceremony of the Trobriand people (Young 1979: 1723). Thus despite Western culture’s willingness to reduce the water world to an empty space, many ‘indigenous’ cultures refute this essentialism. As Raban notes, drawing on David Lewis’ discussion of Polynesian mariners, We, the Navigators (1994): the open sea could be as intimately known and as friendly to human habitation as a familiar stretch of land to those seamen who lived on its surface, as gulls do, wave by wave.... the stars supplied a grand chain of paths across the known ocean, but there was often little need of these since the water itself was as legible as acreage farmed for generations. Colour, wind, the flight of birds, and telltale variations of swell gave the sea direction, shape, character. (Raban 1999: 94) According to Raban, this intimate knowing of water worlds was supplanted in the West by the advent of modern technology, starting with the use of a compass and sextant and extending through to twenty-first century exploitation of satellite telemetry and geographical positioning systems. For Raban, ‘the arrival of the magnetic compass caused a fundamental rift in the relationship between man [sic] and sea’ (1999: 95). Possession of a compass, rendered obsolete a great body of inherited, instinctual knowledge, and rendered the sea itself - in fair weather, at least - as a void, an empty______ rendered obsolete a great body of inherited, instinctual knowledge, and rendered the sea itself - in fair weather, at least - as a void, an empty space to be traversed by a numbered thumb line. (1999: 97) Neo-lib K The aff’s development/exploration project reproduces neoliberalism in oceanic space – they commodify ocean ecology and frame human interaction with the sea as selfinterested utility maximization Mansfield 3 Professor of Geography at OSUhttp://ac.els-cdn.com/S0016718503001155/1-s2.0-S0016718503001155-main.pdf?_tid=466f9680-feea-11e3-923900000aab0f26&acdnat=1403976970_0c59874c8e1a5e3d758a032a84310f4fv To the extent that neoliberalism, with its calls for letting ‘‘the market’’ address myriad social and economic woes, has become the dominant model for political economic practice today, it should be expected that environmental governance, too, would be shaped by the neoliberal imperative to deregulate, liberalize trade and investment, marketize, and privatize (see Agnew and Corbridge, 1995; Overbeek, 1993; Peck, 2001), and evidence of neoliberal approaches to the environment is easily found (e.g. Anderson and Leal, 2001). On the one hand, primary sector industries such as agriculture, forestry, and fisheries are increasingly shaped by efforts to liberalize international trade through reducing tariffs and non-tariff ‘‘trade barriers’’ such as domestic subsidies. On the other hand, environmental governance itself is increasingly oriented toward market-based, rather than state-led, approaches: a prime example are emissions trading schemes as solutions to pollution, such as those proposed for reducing greenhouse gases that contribute to global warming. The rationale for this neoliberal turn in environmental governance is that market mechanisms will harness the profit motive to more innovative and efficient environmental solutions than those devised, implemented, and enforced by states. In what ways, then, is neoliberalism and the environment any different from neoliberalism more generally? Are market-based approaches to the natural environment simply spillover from the larger trends of deregulation, reductions in social services, free trade, and structural adjustment? Or does the history of environmental regulation, both in general and in specific arenas, affect the development of neoliberal environmental governance? In this paper, I address these questions by analyzing the development of neoliberalism in the oceans, and in particular in ocean fisheries. Examining the ways that past policy orientations toward fisheries have influenced the development of neoliberal approaches to ocean governance, I contend that neoliberalism in the oceans centers specifically around concerns about property and the use of privatization to create markets for governing access to and use of ocean resources. Within the Euro – American tradition that has shaped international law of the sea, the oceans (including the water column, seabed, and living and mineral resources) were long treated as common property––the “common heritage of mankind” (Pardo, 1967)––open to all comers with the means to create and exploit oceanic opportunities. Although historically there has also been continual tension between this openness of access and desire for territorialization (especially of coastal waters), treating the oceans as a commons is consistent with the idea that oceans are spaces of movement and transportation, which have facilitated mercantilism, exploration, colonial expansion, and cold war military maneuvering (Steinberg, 2001).1 Oceans have also long been sites for resource extraction, yet it has not been until recent decades that new economic desires and environmental contradictions have contributed to a pronounced move away from open access and freedom of the seas. New technologies for resource extraction combined with regional overexploitation have contributed to conflicts over resources, to which representatives from academia, politics, and business have responded by calling for enclosing the oceans within carefully delimited regimes of property rights, be those regimes of state, individual, or collective control.At the center of this new political economy of oceans, as it has evolved over the past 50 years, has been concern about “the commons,” and the extent to which common and open access property regimes contribute to economic and environmental crises, which include overfishing and overcapitalization. As such, the question of the commons has been at the center of numerous, seemingly contradictory approaches to ocean governance and fisheries regulation. Thus, the first argument of the paper is that neoliberal approaches in fisheries cannot be treated simply as derivative of a larger neoliberal movement that became entrenched starting in the 1980s. Instead, examining trajectories of neoliberalism in fisheries over the past half century reveals that the emphasis on property and the commons has contributed to a more specific dynamic of neoliberalism operating in ocean fisheries and, therefore, to distinctive forms of neoliberalism. To be clear, it is not the emphasis on property in itself that ties this history into neoliberalism, but rather the particular perspective that links property specifically to market rationality. The underlying assumption of all the approaches to property discussed in this paper is that market rationality (i.e. profit maximization) is natural. Given this, property rights harness this rationality to the greater good, while a lack of property rights inevitably leads to economic and environmental problems. It is this set of assumptions that underlies the neoliberal emphasis on privatization and marketization. But this assumption of market rationality is not necessarily a dimension of property in general; property can involve multiple types of arrangements, with different goals and outcomes (Rose, 1994). For example, to the extent that control over access to resources and places can be about protecting traditional livelihoods, assigning property rights can actually challenge purely market-based approaches to resource use. One example relevant to the case study in this paper is the “Community Development Quota” program for communities of Native Alaskans in the Bering Sea region of the North Pacific (Holland and Ginter, 2001; Tryon, 1993). This program guarantees these communities a set percentage of the annual fish catch, with the goal of providing economic and social benefits. These community development quotas are not divorced from markets––and native communities do lease these quotas on the open market––yet property in this context is about providing economic protection for a marginalized group of people. This contrasts to neoliberal approaches, in which property is the basis for rational decision making and market efficiency, not economic protection. My claim here, however, is that fisheries scholars and managers have focused on using property rights specifically to harness supposedly natural market-oriented behavior; in this sense, the development of property rights in fisheries is tied into the neoliberal focus on markets as the central form of governance. Thus, privatization and marketization are not the same thing, yet in neoliberal approaches they are tied together through the presumption that private property rights are necessary for markets to work, and that markets are necessary for optimal economic and environmental behavior (see Section 2.1). At the same time, the difficulty of defining property rights in fisheries has contributed to unique forms of neoliberal privatization and ma Spatial planning reproduces neoliberalism – the aff’s mapping imposes neoliberal subjectivity on oceanic actors, reducing them to rational utility-maximizers – that erases recognition of existing oceanic inequality and prioritizes the zoning priorities of the socially privileged Olson 10 (Julia Olson, department member of Northeast Fisheries Science Center, “Seeding nature, ceding culture: Redefining the boundaries of the marine commons through spatial management and GIS,” Geoforum, 2010) These mappings and transformations happen within broader spatial imperatives that are fundamentally reshaping the ocean. The majority of the world’s fisheries are estimated to be fully exploited, overexploited or depleted (FAO, 2007). Political conflict over fisheries pit the many fishermen arguing that fisheries are rebounding against the many fisheries scientists and environmentalists arguing otherwise; many resource-users have demanded a greater voice in the very process of knowledge production, and efforts at co-management, cooperative research, and traditional ecological knowledge point to potential directions such involvement may produce. Yet conventional arguments about the tragedy of the commons finger the rational, self-interested resource user—economic man of neoclassical economic theory—operating in a socio-ecological environment of incorrect institutional norms and economic incentives. With too many fishermen chasing too few fish in an open sea, such understandings seek privatizing, neoliberal solutions to fisheries dilemmas—solutions many advocates fear destroy fishing communities and cultures. While this hegemony of bio-economics in fisheries management has been maintained, as St. Martin (2001) argues, through a geographic imagination that places the rationalist and self-interested “economic man” in a spatially homogenous commons,2 the increasing efforts to use area-specific forms of fisheries management signal the potential for a “paradigm shift” from individuals to communities and ecosystems, in which the “promise of GIS” hinges especially on the integration of social and biological data ( St. Martin, 2004). Though the actual practice of ecosystem-based management is still taking shape, its recognition of connections and multiple spatial scales, as well as its use for local knowledge in time and space, may be a way to involve people as members of social groups (rather than simply individuals) more integrally in the management process ( St. Martin et al., 2007 and Clay and Olson, 2008). The actual implementation of ecosystem-based fisheries management, some argue, should happen through a planned system of “ocean zoning” that replaces the patchwork of ad hoc, uncoordinated regulations whose goals have been decoupled from a broader notion of the ecosystem that concerns itself as much with sustaining fisheries as “the nonfisheries benefits of marine ecosystems to society” (Babcock et al., 2005, p. 469). As marine biologist Elliot Norse has written, because the ocean has many competing users—“shipping, defense, energy production, telecommunications, commercial fishing, sportfishing, recreational diving, whale watching, pleasure boating, tourism and coastal real estate development”—whose conflicts can lead to resource degradation, zoning provides a solution for it “is a place-based ecosystem management system that reduces conflict, uncertainty and costs by separating incompatible uses and specifying how particular areas may be used” (2002, pp. 53–54). Such a comprehensive system of zoning is envisioned as a more rational “system of finely specified spatial and temporal property rights” (Wilen, 2004). The 2003 Pew Report also mentions “implement[ing] ecosystem-based planning” in the same breath as zoning, for fisheries management, it argues, should more fully consider context: “incompatible” user conflicts that affect target species (2003, p. 47). Economists who promote zoning as a way to “account for spatial and intertemporal externalities” picture it reaching its rational equilibrium through the market, rationing numbers of users in search of a “rent-maximizing equilibrium” (Sanchirico and Wilen, 2005, p. 25), and ultimately creating property rights (Holland, 2004) and stewardship (US Commission on Ocean Policy, 2004, p. 64). Yet while ocean zoning is seen as something of a new solution for marine conflicts, the model of terrestrial zoning upon which it is based is hardly without its critics. Proponents of smart growth, new urbanism, and mixed-use communities have pointed to the myriad problems—including sprawl, traffic, pollution, loss of farmland, and so on—created by separating the activities of daily life. The view that zoning will end conflict assumes that such conflicts center only on doing different things in the same place, while creating zones of “use-priority” areas begs the question of whose values will dictate a given zone’s “most important” activities. As such, conflict may simply be displaced from the ocean to places where policies are crafted or where their impacts are lived. Indeed scholars have long noted how zoning laws are colored by cultural ideas (for example, public versus private/domestic space) that are distinctly bourgeois, raced and gendered and thus favor certain groups of people (Ritzdorf, 1994, Perin, 1977 and LiPuma and Meltzoff, 1997). Some economists have also been critical of marine zoning’s creation of “divided” property rights that do not fully consider “the opportunity costs of foregone production” that might otherwise “maximize joint wealth” ( Edwards, 2000, p. 4). In other words, the “economic benefits” of zoning cannot be assumed for “it is an empirical question whether ocean wealth would be improved” (ibid, p. 7). A focus on aggregate wealth though leaves unanswered the effect of an initially unequal distribution of wealth on the prices and outcomes in a market-based economy, as well as the changes in subjectivity and practices that the neoliberalization of resource economies and identities can engender. The impact is massive environmental destruction and social inequality – imposition of neoliberal landscapes on local landscapes produces fast capitalist extraction and causes displacement and dehumanization Nixon ‘11 (Rob, Rachel Carson Professor of English, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Slow Violence and the Environmentalism of the Poor, pgs. 17-18) In the global resource wars, the environmentalism of the poor is frequently triggered when an official landscape is forcibly imposed on a vernacular one." A vernacular landscape is shaped by the affective, historically textured maps that communities have devised over generations, maps replete with names and routes, maps alive to significant ecological and surface geological features. A vernacular landscape, although neither monolithic nor undisputed, is integral to the socioenvironmental dynamics of community rather than being wholly externalized-treated as out there, as a separate nonrenewable resource. By contrast, an official landscape-whether governmental, NGO, corporate, or some combination of those-is typically oblivious to such earlier maps; instead, it writes the land in a bureaucratic, externalizing, and extraction-driven manner that is often pitilessly instrumental. Lawrence Summers' scheme to export rich-nation garbage and toxicity to Africa, for example, stands as a grandiose (though hardly exceptional) instance of a highly rationalized official landscape that, whether in terms of elite capture of resources or toxic disposal, has often been projected onto ecosystems inhabited by those whom Annu Jalais, in an Indian context, calls "dispensable citizens.'?" I would argue, then, that the exponential upsurge in indigenous resource rebellions across the globe during the high age of neoliberalism has resulted largely from a clash of temporal perspectives between the short-termers who arrive (with their official landscape maps) to extract, despoil, and depart and the long-termers who must live inside the ecological aftermath and must therefore weigh wealth differently in time's scales. In the pages that follow, I will highlight and explore resource rebellions against developer-dispossessors who descend from other time zones to impose on habitable environments unsustainable calculations about what constitutes the duration of human gain. Change is a cultural constant but the pace of change is not. Hence the temporal contests over how to sustain, regenerate, exhaust, or obliterate the landscape as resource become critical. More than material wealth is here at stake: imposed official landscapes typically discount spiritualized vernacular landscapes, severing webs of accumulated cultural meaning and treating the landscape as if it were uninhabited by the living, the unborn, and the animate deceased. The ensuing losses are consistent with John Berger's lament over capitalism's disdain for interdependencies by foreshortening our sense of time, thereby rendering the deceased immaterial: The living reduce the dead to those who have lived; yet the dead already include the living in their own great collective. Until the dehumanization of society by capitalism, all the living awaited the experience of the dead. It was their ultimate future. By themselves the living were incomplete. Thus living and dead were interdependent. Always. Only a uniquely modern form of egoism has broken this interdependence. With disastrous results for the living, who now think of the dead as the eliminated.40 Hence, one should add, our perspective on environmental asset stripping should include among assets stripped the mingled presence in the landscape of multiple generations, with all the hindsight and foresight that entails. Against this backdrop, I consider in this book what can be called the temporalities of place. Place is a temporal attainment that must be constantly renegotiated in the face of changes that arrive from without and within, some benign, others potentially ruinous. To engage the temporal displacements involved in slow violence against the poor thus requires that we rethink questions of physical displacement as well. In the chapters that follow, I track the socioenvironmental fallout from developmental agendas whose primary beneficiaries live elsewhere; as when, for example, oasis dwellers in the Persian Gulf get trucked off to unknown destinations so that American petroleum engineers and their sheik collaborators can develop their "finds." Or when a megadam arises and (whether erected in the name of Some dictatorial edict, the free market, structural adjustment, national development, or far-off urban or industrial need) displaces and disperses those who had developed through their vernacular landscapes their own adaptable, if always imperfect and vulnerable, relation to riverine possibility. Paradoxically, those forcibly removed by development include conservation refugees. Too often in the global South, conservation, driven by powerful transnational nature NGOs, combines an antidevelopmental rhetoric with the development of finite resources for the touristic few, thereby depleting vital resources for long-term residents. (I explore this paradox more fully in Chapter 6: Stranger in the Eco-village: Race, Tourism, and Environmental Time.) In much of what follows, I address the resistance mounted by impoverished communities who have been involuntarily moved out of their knowledge; I address as well the powers transnational, national, and local-behind such forced removals. My angle of vision is largely through writers who have affiliated themselves with social movements that seek to stave off one of two ruinous prospects: either the threatened community capitulates and is scattered (across refugee camps, placeless "relocation" sites, desperate favelas, and unwelcoming foreign lands), or the community refuses to move but, as its world is undermined, effectively becomes a community of refugees in place. What I wish to stress here, then, are not just those communities that are involuntarily (and often militarily) relocated to less I want to propose a more radical notion of displacement, one that, instead of referring solely to the movement of people from their places of belonging, refers rather to the loss of the land and resources beneath them, a loss that leaves communities stranded in a place stripped of the very characteristics that made it inhabitable. hospitable environs, but also those affected by what I call displacement without moving. In other words, Alternative text: the judge should vote negative to endorse an ethic of social flesh An ethic of social flesh foregrounds embodied interdependence, substituting an ecological view of relationships for the aff’s commodity thinking – only the alternative can produce ethical institutional decisionmaking Beasley & Bacchi 7 (Chris, Prof. of Politics @ University of Adelaide, Carol, Prof. Emeritus @ University of Adelaide, “Envisaging a new politics for an ethical future: Beyond trust, care and generosity -- towards an ethic of `social flesh'”, Feminist Theory, 2007 8: 279) The political vocabulary of social flesh has significant implications for democratic visions. Because it conceptualizes citizens as socially embodied – as interconnected mutually reliant flesh – in a more thoroughgoing sense than the languages of trust, care, responsibility and generosity, it resists accounts of political change as making transactions between the ‘less fortunate’ and ‘more privileged’, more trusting, more caring, more responsible or more generous. Social flesh is political metaphor in which fleshly sociality is profoundly levelling. As a result, it challenges meliorist reforms that aim to protect the ‘vulnerable’ from the worst effects of social inequality, including the current distribution of wealth. A political ethic of embodied intersubjectivity requires us to consider fleshly interconnection as the basis of a democratic sociality, demanding a rather more far-reaching reassessment of national and international institutional arrangements than political vocabularies that rest upon extending altruism. Relatedly, it provides a new basis for thinking about the sorts of institutional arrangements necessary to acknowledge social fleshly existence, opening up ‘the scope of what counts as relevant’ (Shildrick, 2001: 238). For example, it allows a challenge to current conceptualizations that construct attention to the ‘private sphere’ as compensatory rather than as necessary (Beasley and Bacchi, 2000: 350). We intend to pursue the relationship between social flesh and democratic governance in future papers. Conclusion In this paper we focus on various vocabularies of social interconnection intended to offer a challenge to the ethos of atomistic individualism associated with neo-liberalism and develop a new ethical ideal called ‘social flesh’. Despite significant differences in the several vocabularies canvassed in this paper, we note that most of the trust and care writers conceive the social reform of atomistic individualism they claim to address in terms of a presumed moral or ethical deficiency within the disposition of individuals. Hence, they reinstate the conception of the independent active self in certain ways. Moreover, there is a disturbing commonality within all these accounts: an ongoing conception of asymmetrical power relations between ‘strong’ and ‘weak’, ‘carers’ and ‘cared for’, ‘altruistic’ and ‘needy’. While widely used terms like trust and care clearly remain vocabularies around which social debate may be mobilized, and hence are not to be dismissed (see Pocock, 2006), we suggest that there are important reasons for questioning their limits and their claims to offer progressive alternative understandings of social life. In this setting, we offer the concept of social flesh as a way forward in rethinking the complex nature of the interaction between subjectivity, embodiment, intimacy, social institutions and social interconnection. Social flesh generalizes the insight that trusting/caring/ altruistic practices already take place on an ongoing basis to insist that the broad, complex sustenance of life that characterizes embodied subjectivity and intersubjective existence be acknowledged. As an ethico- political starting point, ‘social flesh’ highlights human embodied interdependence. By drawing attention to shared embodied reliance, mutual reliance, of people across the globe on social space, infrastructure and resources, it offers a decided challenge to neo-liberal conceptions of the autonomous self and removes the social distance and always already given distinction between ‘strong’ and ‘weak’. There is no sense here of ‘givers’ and ‘receivers’; rather we are all recognized as receivers of socially generated goods and services. Social flesh also marks our diversity, challenging the privileging of normative over ‘other’ bodies. Finally, because social flesh necessarily inhabits a specific geographical space, environmentalist efforts to preserve that space take on increased salience (Macken, 2004: 25). By these means, the grounds are created for defending a politics beyond assisting the ‘less fortunate’. Social flesh, therefore, refuses the residues of ‘noblesse oblige’ that still appear to linger in emphasis upon vulnerability and altruism within the apparently reformist ethical ideals of trust/respect, care, responsibility and even generosity. In so doing it puts into question the social privilege that produces inequitable vulnerability and the associated need for ‘altruism’. Vital debates about appropriate distribution of social goods, environmental politics, professional and institutional power and democratic processes are reopened. Neo-lib K link 1nc shell The aff’s development/exploration project reproduces neoliberalism in oceanic space – they commodify ocean ecology and frame human interaction with the sea as self-interested utility maximization Mansfield 3 Professor of Geography at OSUhttp://ac.els-cdn.com/S0016718503001155/1-s2.0-S0016718503001155-main.pdf?_tid=466f9680-feea-11e3-923900000aab0f26&acdnat=1403976970_0c59874c8e1a5e3d758a032a84310f4fv To the extent that neoliberalism, with its calls for letting ‘‘the market’’ address myriad social and economic woes, has become the dominant model for political economic practice today, it should be expected that environmental governance, too, would be shaped by the neoliberal imperative to deregulate, liberalize trade and investment, marketize, and privatize (see Agnew and Corbridge, 1995; Overbeek, 1993; Peck, 2001), and evidence of neoliberal approaches to the environment is easily found (e.g. Anderson and Leal, 2001). On the one hand, primary sector industries such as agriculture, forestry, and fisheries are increasingly shaped by efforts to liberalize international trade through reducing tariffs and non-tariff ‘‘trade barriers’’ such as domestic subsidies. On the other hand, environmental governance itself is increasingly oriented toward market-based, rather than state-led, approaches: a prime example are emissions trading schemes as solutions to pollution, such as those proposed for reducing greenhouse gases that contribute to global warming. The rationale for this neoliberal turn in environmental governance is that market mechanisms will harness the profit motive to more innovative and efficient environmental solutions than those devised, implemented, and enforced by states. In what ways, then, is neoliberalism and the environment any different from neoliberalism more generally? Are market-based approaches to the natural environment simply spillover from the larger trends of deregulation, reductions in social services, free trade, and structural adjustment? Or does the history of environmental regulation, both in general and in specific arenas, affect the development of neoliberal environmental governance? In this paper, I address these questions by analyzing the development of neoliberalism in the oceans, and in particular in ocean fisheries. Examining the ways that past policy orientations toward fisheries have influenced the development of neoliberal approaches to ocean governance, I contend that neoliberalism in the oceans centers specifically around concerns about property and the use of privatization to create markets for governing access to and use of ocean resources. Within the Euro – American tradition that has shaped international law of the sea, the oceans (including the water column, seabed, and living and mineral resources) were long treated as common property––the “common heritage of mankind” (Pardo, 1967)––open to all comers with the means to create and exploit oceanic opportunities. Although historically there has also been continual tension between this openness of access and desire for territorialization (especially of coastal waters), treating the oceans as a commons is consistent with the idea that oceans are spaces of movement and transportation, which have facilitated mercantilism, exploration, colonial expansion, and cold war military maneuvering (Steinberg, 2001).1 Oceans have also long been sites for resource extraction, yet it has not been until recent decades that new economic desires and environmental contradictions have contributed to a pronounced move away from open access and freedom of the seas . New technologies for resource extraction combined with regional overexploitation have contributed to conflicts over resources, to which representatives from academia, politics, and business have responded by calling for enclosing the oceans within carefully delimited regimes of property rights, be those regimes of state, individual, or collective control.At the center of this new political economy of oceans, as it has evolved over the past 50 years, has been concern about “the commons,” and the extent to which common and open access property regimes contribute to economic and environmental crises, which include overfishing and overcapitalization. As such, the question of the commons has been at the center of numerous, seemingly contradictory approaches to ocean governance and fisheries regulation. Thus, the first argument of the paper is that neoliberal approaches in fisheries cannot be treated simply as derivative of a larger neoliberal movement that became entrenched starting in the 1980s. Instead, examining trajectories of neoliberalism in fisheries over the past half century reveals that the emphasis on property and the commons has contributed to a more specific dynamic of neoliberalism operating in ocean fisheries and, therefore, to distinctive forms of neoliberalism. To be clear, it is not the emphasis on property in itself that ties this history into neoliberalism, but rather the particular perspective that links property specifically to market rationality. The underlying assumption of all the approaches to property discussed in this paper is that market rationality (i.e. profit maximization) is natural. Given this, property rights harness this rationality to the greater good, while a lack of property rights inevitably leads to economic and environmental problems. It is this set of assumptions that underlies the neoliberal emphasis on privatization and marketization. But this assumption of market rationality is not necessarily a dimension of property in general; property can involve multiple types of arrangements, with different goals and outcomes (Rose, 1994). For example, to the extent that control over access to resources and places can be about protecting traditional livelihoods, assigning property rights can actually challenge purely market-based approaches to resource use. One example relevant to the case study in this paper is the “Community Development Quota” program for communities of Native Alaskans in the Bering Sea region of the North Pacific (Holland and Ginter, 2001; Tryon, 1993). This program guarantees these communities a set percentage of the annual fish catch, with the goal of providing economic and social benefits. These community development quotas are not divorced from markets––and native communities do lease these quotas on the open market––yet property in this context is about providing economic protection for a marginalized group of people. This contrasts to neoliberal approaches, in which property is the basis for rational decision making and market efficiency, not economic protection. My claim here, however, is that fisheries scholars and managers have focused on using property rights specifically to harness supposedly natural market-oriented behavior; in this sense, the development of property rights in fisheries is tied into the neoliberal focus on markets as the central form of governance. Thus, privatization and marketization are not the same thing, yet in neoliberal approaches they are tied together through the presumption that private property rights are necessary for markets to work, and that markets are necessary for optimal economic and environmental behavior (see Section 2.1). At the same time, the difficulty of defining property rights in fisheries has contributed to unique forms of neoliberal privatization and ma Spatial planning reproduces neoliberalism – the aff’s mapping imposes neoliberal subjectivity on oceanic actors, reducing them to rational utilitymaximizers – that erases recognition of existing oceanic inequality and prioritizes the zoning priorities of the socially privileged Olson 10 (Julia Olson, department member of Northeast Fisheries Science Center, “Seeding nature, ceding culture: Redefining the boundaries of the marine commons through spatial management and GIS,” Geoforum, 2010) These mappings and transformations happen within broader spatial imperatives that are fundamentally reshaping the ocean. The majority of the world’s fisheries are estimated to be fully exploited, overexploited or depleted (FAO, 2007). Political conflict over fisheries pit the many fishermen arguing that fisheries are rebounding against the many fisheries scientists and environmentalists arguing otherwise; many resource-users have demanded a greater voice in the very process of knowledge production, and efforts at co-management, cooperative research, and traditional ecological knowledge point to potential directions such involvement may produce. Yet conventional arguments about the tragedy of the commons finger the rational, self-interested resource user—economic man of neoclassical economic theory—operating in a socio-ecological environment of incorrect institutional norms and economic incentives. With too many fishermen chasing too few fish in an open sea, such understandings seek privatizing, neoliberal solutions to fisheries dilemmas—solutions many advocates fear destroy fishing communities and cultures. While this hegemony of bio-economics in fisheries management has been maintained, as St. Martin (2001) argues, through a geographic imagination that places the rationalist and self-interested “economic man” in a spatially homogenous commons,2 the increasing efforts to use area-specific forms of fisheries management signal the potential for a “paradigm shift” from individuals to communities and ecosystems, in which the “promise of GIS” hinges especially on the integration of social and biological data ( St. Martin, 2004). Though the actual practice of ecosystem-based management is still taking shape, its recognition of connections and multiple spatial scales, as well as its use for local knowledge in time and space, may be a way to involve people as members of social groups (rather than simply individuals) more integrally in the management process ( St. Martin et al., 2007 and Clay and Olson, 2008). The actual implementation of ecosystem-based fisheries management, some argue, should happen through a planned system of “ocean zoning” that replaces the patchwork of ad hoc, uncoordinated regulations whose goals have been decoupled from a broader notion of the ecosystem that concerns itself as much with sustaining fisheries as “the non-fisheries benefits of marine ecosystems to society” (Babcock et al., 2005, p. 469). As marine biologist Elliot Norse has written, because the ocean has many competing users—“shipping, defense, energy production, telecommunications, commercial fishing, sportfishing, recreational diving, whale watching, pleasure boating, tourism and coastal real estate development”—whose conflicts can lead to resource degradation, zoning provides a solution for it “is a place-based ecosystem management system that reduces conflict, uncertainty and costs by separating incompatible uses and specifying how particular areas may be used” (2002, pp. 53–54). Such a comprehensive system of zoning is envisioned as a more rational “system of finely specified spatial and temporal property rights” (Wilen, 2004). The 2003 Pew Report also mentions “implement[ing] ecosystem-based planning” in the same breath as zoning, for fisheries management, it argues, should more fully consider context: “incompatible” user conflicts that affect target species (2003, p. 47). Economists who promote zoning as a way to “account for spatial and intertemporal externalities” picture it reaching its rational equilibrium through the market, rationing numbers of users in search of a “rent-maximizing equilibrium” (Sanchirico and Wilen, 2005, p. 25), and ultimately creating property rights (Holland, 2004) and stewardship (US Commission on Ocean Policy, 2004, p. 64). Yet while ocean zoning is seen as something of a new solution for marine conflicts, the model of terrestrial zoning upon which it is based is hardly without its critics. Proponents of smart growth, new urbanism, and mixed-use communities have pointed to the myriad problems—including sprawl, traffic, pollution, loss of farmland, and so on— created by separating the activities of daily life. The view that zoning will end conflict assumes that such conflicts center only on doing different things in the same place, while creating zones of “usepriority” areas begs the question of whose values will dictate a given zone’s “most important” activities. As such, conflict may simply be displaced from the ocean to places where policies are crafted or where their impacts are lived. Indeed scholars have long noted how zoning laws are colored by cultural ideas (for example, public versus private/domestic space) that are distinctly bourgeois, raced and gendered and thus favor certain groups of people (Ritzdorf, 1994, Perin, 1977 and LiPuma and Meltzoff, 1997). Some economists have also been critical of marine zoning’s creation of “divided” property rights that do not fully consider “the opportunity costs of foregone production” that might otherwise “maximize joint wealth” ( Edwards, 2000, p. 4). In other words, the “economic benefits” of zoning cannot be assumed for “it is an empirical question whether ocean wealth would be improved” (ibid, p. 7). A focus on aggregate wealth though leaves unanswered the effect of an initially unequal distribution of wealth on the prices and outcomes in a marketbased economy, as well as the changes in subjectivity and practices that the neoliberalization of resource economies and identities can engender. The impact is massive environmental destruction and social inequality – imposition of neoliberal landscapes on local landscapes produces fast capitalist extraction and causes displacement and dehumanization Nixon ‘11 (Rob, Rachel Carson Professor of English, University of Wisconsin-Madison, Slow Violence and the Environmentalism of the Poor, pgs. 17-18) In the global resource wars, the environmentalism of the poor is frequently triggered when an official landscape is forcibly imposed on a vernacular one." A vernacular landscape is shaped by the affective, historically textured maps that communities have devised over generations, maps replete with names and routes, maps alive to significant ecological and surface geological features. A vernacular landscape, although neither monolithic nor undisputed, is integral to the socioenvironmental dynamics of community rather than being wholly externalized-treated as out there, as a separate nonrenewable resource. By contrast, an official landscape-whether governmental, NGO, corporate, or some combination of those-is typically oblivious to such earlier maps; instead, it writes the land in a bureaucratic, externalizing, and extraction-driven manner that is often pitilessly instrumental. Lawrence Summers' scheme to export rich-nation garbage and toxicity to Africa, for example, stands as a grandiose (though hardly exceptional) instance of a highly rationalized official landscape that, whether in terms of elite capture of resources or toxic disposal, has often been projected onto ecosystems inhabited by those whom Annu Jalais, in an Indian context, calls "dispensable citizens.'?" I would argue, the exponential upsurge in indigenous resource rebellions across the globe during the high age of neoliberalism has resulted largely from a clash of temporal perspectives between the short-termers who arrive (with their official landscape maps) to extract, despoil, and depart and the long-termers who must live inside the ecological aftermath and must therefore weigh wealth differently in then, that time's scales. In the pages that follow, I will highlight and explore resource rebellions against developer-dispossessors who descend from other time zones to impose on Change is a cultural constant but the pace of change is not. Hence the temporal contests over how to sustain, regenerate, exhaust, or obliterate the landscape as resource become critical. More than material wealth is here at stake: imposed official landscapes typically discount spiritualized vernacular landscapes, severing webs of accumulated cultural meaning and treating the landscape as if it were uninhabited by the living, the unborn, and the animate deceased. The ensuing losses are consistent with John Berger's lament over capitalism's disdain for interdependencies by foreshortening our sense of time, thereby rendering the deceased immaterial: The living reduce the dead to those who have lived; yet the dead already include the living in their own great collective. Until the dehumanization of society by capitalism, all the living awaited the experience of the dead. It was their ultimate future. By themselves the living were incomplete. Thus living and dead were interdependent. Always. Only a uniquely modern form of egoism has broken this interdependence. With disastrous results for the living, who now think of the dead as the eliminated.40 Hence, one should add, our perspective on environmental asset stripping should include among assets stripped the mingled presence in the landscape of multiple generations, with all the hindsight and foresight that entails. Against this backdrop, I consider in this book what can be called the temporalities of place. Place is a temporal attainment that must be constantly renegotiated in the face of changes that arrive from without and within, some benign, others potentially ruinous. To engage the temporal displacements involved in slow violence against the poor thus requires that we rethink questions of physical displacement as well. In the chapters that follow, I track the socioenvironmental fallout from developmental habitable environments unsustainable calculations about what constitutes the duration of human gain. agendas whose primary beneficiaries live elsewhere; as when, for example, oasis dwellers in the Persian Gulf get trucked off to unknown destinations so that American petroleum engineers and their sheik collaborators can develop their "finds." Or when a megadam arises and (whether erected in the name of Some dictatorial edict, the free market, structural adjustment, national development, or far-off urban or industrial need) displaces and disperses those who had developed through their vernacular landscapes their own adaptable, if always imperfect and vulnerable, relation to riverine possibility. Paradoxically, those forcibly removed by development include conservation refugees. Too often in the global South, conservation, driven by powerful transnational nature NGOs, combines an antidevelopmental rhetoric with the development of finite resources for the touristic few, thereby depleting vital resources for long-term residents. (I explore this paradox more fully in Chapter 6: Stranger in the Eco-village: Race, Tourism, and Environmental Time.) In much of what follows, I address the resistance mounted by impoverished communities who have been involuntarily moved out of their knowledge; I address as well the powers transnational, national, and local-behind such forced removals. My angle of vision is largely through writers who have affiliated themselves with social movements that seek to stave off one of two ruinous prospects: either the threatened community capitulates and is scattered (across refugee camps, placeless "relocation" sites, desperate favelas, and unwelcoming foreign lands), or the community refuses to move but, as its world is undermined, effectively becomes a community of refugees in place. What I wish to stress here, then, are not just those communities that are involuntarily (and often militarily) relocated to less I want to propose a more radical notion of displacement, one that, instead of referring solely to the movement of people from their places of belonging, refers rather to the loss of the land and resources beneath them, a loss that leaves communities stranded in a place stripped of the very characteristics that made it inhabitable. hospitable environs, but also those affected by what I call displacement without moving. In other words, Alternative text: the judge should vote negative to endorse an ethic of social flesh An ethic of social flesh foregrounds embodied interdependence, substituting an ecological view of relationships for the aff’s commodity thinking – only the alternative can produce ethical institutional decisionmaking Beasley & Bacchi 7 (Chris, Prof. of Politics @ University of Adelaide, Carol, Prof. Emeritus @ University of Adelaide, “Envisaging a new politics for an ethical future: Beyond trust, care and generosity -- towards an ethic of `social flesh'”, Feminist Theory, 2007 8: 279) The political vocabulary of social flesh has significant implications for democratic visions. Because it conceptualizes citizens as socially embodied – as interconnected mutually reliant flesh – in a more thoroughgoing sense than the languages of trust, care, responsibility and generosity, it resists accounts of political change as making transactions between the ‘less fortunate’ and ‘more privileged’, more trusting, more caring, more responsible or more generous. Social flesh is political metaphor in which fleshly sociality is profoundly levelling. As a result, it challenges meliorist reforms that aim to protect the ‘vulnerable’ from the worst effects of social inequality, including the current distribution of wealth. A political ethic of embodied intersubjectivity requires us to consider fleshly interconnection as the basis of a democratic sociality, demanding a rather more far-reaching reassessment of national and international institutional arrangements than political vocabularies that rest upon extending altruism. Relatedly, it provides a new basis for thinking about the sorts of institutional arrangements necessary to acknowledge social fleshly existence, opening up ‘the scope of what counts as relevant’ (Shildrick, 2001: 238). For example, it allows a challenge to current conceptualizations that construct attention to the ‘private sphere’ as compensatory rather than as necessary (Beasley and Bacchi, 2000: 350). We intend to pursue the relationship between social flesh and democratic governance in future papers. Conclusion In this paper we focus on various vocabularies of social interconnection intended to offer a challenge to the ethos of atomistic individualism associated with neo-liberalism and develop a new ethical ideal called ‘social flesh’. Despite significant differences in the several vocabularies canvassed in this paper, we note that most of the trust and care writers conceive the social reform of atomistic individualism they claim to address in terms of a presumed moral or ethical deficiency within the disposition of individuals. Hence, they reinstate the conception of the independent active self in certain ways. Moreover, there is a disturbing commonality within all these accounts: an ongoing conception of asymmetrical power relations between ‘strong’ and ‘weak’, ‘carers’ and ‘cared for’, ‘altruistic’ and ‘needy’. While widely used terms like trust and care clearly remain vocabularies around which social debate may be mobilized, and hence are not to be dismissed (see Pocock, 2006), we suggest that there are important reasons for questioning their limits and their claims to offer progressive alternative understandings of social life. In this setting, we offer the concept of social flesh as a way forward in rethinking the complex nature of the interaction between subjectivity, embodiment, intimacy, social institutions and social interconnection. Social flesh generalizes the insight that trusting/caring/ altruistic practices already take place on an ongoing basis to insist that the broad, complex sustenance of life that characterizes embodied subjectivity and intersubjective existence be acknowledged. As an ethico-political starting point, ‘social flesh’ highlights human embodied interdependence. By drawing attention to shared embodied reliance, mutual reliance, of people across the globe on social space, infrastructure and resources, it offers a decided challenge to neo-liberal conceptions of the autonomous self and removes the social distance and always already given distinction between ‘strong’ and ‘weak’. There is no sense here of ‘givers’ and ‘receivers’; rather we are all recognized as receivers of socially generated goods and services. Social flesh also marks our diversity, challenging the privileging of normative over ‘other’ bodies. Finally, because social flesh necessarily inhabits a specific geographical space, environmentalist efforts to preserve that space take on increased salience (Macken, 2004: 25). By these means, the grounds are created for defending a politics beyond assisting the ‘less fortunate’. Social flesh, therefore, refuses the residues of ‘noblesse oblige’ that still appear to linger in emphasis upon vulnerability and altruism within the apparently reformist ethical ideals of trust/respect, care, responsibility and even generosity. In so doing it puts into question the social privilege that produces inequitable vulnerability and the associated need for ‘altruism’. Vital debates about appropriate distribution of social goods, environmental politics, professional and institutional power and democratic processes are reopened. Extra links Ocean mapping reproduces a neoliberal approach towards oceans – the plan’s spatial mapping commodifies the marine environment, allowing statistical visualization of hidden ocean life to accelerate consumption Olson 10 (Julia Olson, department member of Northeast Fisheries Science Center, “Seeding nature, ceding culture: Redefining the boundaries of the marine commons through spatial management and GIS,” Geoforum, 2010) The inability to fix resources in space has been at the heart of many understandings of common property. Mobile resources such as fish have given rise to particularly intractable common-pool problems, for their mobility implies a lack of “excludability (or control of access). That is, the physical nature of the resource is such that controlling access by potential users may be costly and, in the extreme, virtually impossible” (Feeny et al., 1990, p. 3). Not only do fish move but, at least in conventional accounts, so do mobile fishermen, ever seeking highest profit in a rationalist movement through space (e.g. Sanchirico and Wilen, 1999). There are of course fissures in this story, even for such seemingly mobile resources as fish. While rotational management is argued particularly appropriate for semi-sedentary species such as scallops (e.g. Hart, 2003), others similarly contend that locally diverse sub-species, like populations of cod in Norway that follow the ebb and flow of particular fjords and inlets, necessitate more locally-based science and management (e.g. Jorde et al., 2007). Fishermen too, while often portrayed as opportunistically mobile, may have multiple rationalities that inform their fishing practices, including their spatial decision-making (Olson, 2006). My point here is not to counter movement with an equally mythical lack of movement, but rather to ask how forms of resource use—here especially, fishing or farming the ocean—involve culturally constructed subjectivities, networks of social relations, and spatially grounded knowledge and practice. In the case of contemporary fisheries management, these subjectivities, relations, and knowledge and practice are now increasingly mediated through technologies like GIS. While mapping and counter-mapping have become more intertwined with stories of common property in general, the case of fisheries poses a double sort of enigma, for not only is there the issue of mobility and excludability in space but there is also the question of visualization, or lack thereof. In Hardin’s classic account of the tragedy of the commons, for example, he asked that we “Picture a pasture open to all” (1968: 1244, italics added), where the herders, herds, and resource degradation are palpable and countable. For fisheries management however, this has not been such an easy task. The inability to see what is happening has in part structured the orientation of both fisheries management and biology: stock assessment is a statistical exercise in estimating hidden populations, while management tries to reconcile its strategies around fishermen who might cheat without being seen. Fisheries management, however, has recently begun to take a distinctly visual turn through the use of GIS and other spatial techniques for understanding and monitoring where different resources are and how they are used—not only supporting policy analyses from habitat classification and protection of essential fish habitat, to the social and economic impacts of closed areas ( Meaden, 2000, NOAA, 2004 and St. Martin, 2004), but also coupled to increasing interest in spatially-based methods of management. What tends to be missing, however, is an appreciation of arguments raised within geography and other social sciences that critique the use of GIS as technologically or socially neutral, or which have conversely grappled with how to use GIS for qualitative and critical approaches to social knowledge.1 The presumed neutrality and objectivity of GIS in fisheries management has not only assumed a sense of “space that is broadly taken for granted in Western societies—our naïvely assumed sense of space as emptiness” (Smith and Katz, 1993, p. 75), but has also tended to privilege universal understandings. Thus while the fishery management process has begun to incorporate spatially sensitive analyses into its development of area-based management, such incorporation has utilized neoliberal constructions of the typical fisherman that are challenged by more nuanced notions of fishing and resource dependence. New directions in the mapping of scallops that focus on crucial habitat and life cycle issues, for example, promise changes both in the science underlying fisheries management and in management itself by better directing fishing effort to particular places and by better understanding the conditions for resource enhancement through seeding, which at first glance recalls the warnings from early GIS critics that digital maps would serve to create or reinforce relations of power through the discovery of new things or people to exploit (Schuurman, 2000, p. 580). Yet as this reframing of resources from fishing to farming intersects with an increasing interest in aquaculture (where the idea of farming is obviously more explicit), it becomes clear that while ideas about property can be more easily enrolled into neoliberal discourses that commodify resource relations, transformations from fishing to farming also enable alternative projects through their articulation with cultural practices and processes. This includes the differential spatial practices of often smaller-scale fishermen as well as community-based interests in scallop seeding, who have sought—quite literally—to sow the seeds of community stability and, in the process, resist and redefine the terms of neoliberal market logic. This paper thus considers the differing worldviews, practices, and spatialities among and between so-called highliners and small-scale fishermen, fishers and farmers of scallops, different resource-users and the scientists who map them, and the radically new forms of economic practice and sustainability that inhere, potentially, in different uses and forms of maps and spatial knowledge, looking in particular at US Federal management of Sea Scallops, a Canadian example of a private-state partnership, and community-based seeding efforts in Downeast Maine. Neoliberal spatial planning ensures error replication because it reduces the ocean to human representations of it – be suspicious of their impacts because they reduce ecological relations to commodity relations Steinberg 13 (Philip E. Steinberg 13 – PhD from Clark University & Professor of Critical Geography at Florida State University , “Of the seas: metaphors and materialities in maritime regions”, Atlantic Studies: Global Currents, Volume 10, Number 2, 4/29/2013) Ocean region studies have their origins in an explicit questioning of the assumption that the landbased region is the appropriate scope for conducting social analysis. In History departments, in particular, where academic positions are routinely connected with a specific region and a specific era (e.g. nineteenth-century Latin Americanist), scholars who have sought to define regions by oceans of interaction rather than continents of settlement and governance have had to directly challenge the disciplinary establishment.36 And yet, the regionalization of the sea itself is rarely interrogated. As Martin Lewis demonstrates, the boundaries, definitions, and namings of ocean regions have been highly variable (and, at times, quite arbitrary).37 Likewise, the lines that divide ocean regions on a contemporary legal map of the sea defining territorial waters, contiguous zones, exclusive economic zones, the High Seas, etc. hide as much as they obscure. From the Papal Bull of 1493 that purportedly divided the ocean between Spain and Portugal to the zones ascribed to the ocean by the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS), the history of the ocean is filled with attempts to mark off its spaces, if not as claimable territory then at least as zones where certain activities, by certain actors, are permitted and others are prohibited. And yet, even when the locations of the lines are clear and communicated (which, in fact, is often not the case), their meanings are worked out only through social practices. In particular, because the ocean is characterized by overlapping zonations (from the legal regions prescribed by UNCLOS to cultural understandings of regional seas to zones of geophysical interactivity and animal migrations), efforts at understanding an ocean event or image by ‘‘locating’’ it in an ocean region are likely to rest on simplified notions of the relationship between boundaries and events. More often than not, the definition and boundaries of an ocean region are defined by how it is practiced through the reproduction of a regional assemblage, and not the other way around.38 In short, just as oceanregion-based studies must take heed of the uniquely fluvial nature of the ocean that lies at the center of an ocean region, so they must also account for the fluidity of the lines that are drawn around and within the region. Again, this is not a problem unique to maritime regions; many pages in geography textbooks have been written that expound on where the boundaries of a specific region are (or where they should be), while more enlightened scholars have stressed that such questions cannot be answered objectively. Nonetheless, here too the ocean is an extreme case: lines drawn in and around ocean regions often take on an out- sized level of authority because they are so self-evidently divorced from the matter that is experienced by those who actually inhabit the environment. In the ocean, humans’ ability to physically transform space through line drawing is exceptionally limited.39 Therefore, lines in the ocean speak not with the authority of a geophysicality that cannot be fully grasped but with the authority of a juridical system that conceivably can.40 The danger, then, is that the maritime region, although born out of a critique of the idea that the world consists of stable, bounded places where ‘‘society’’ is an explanatory variable, could itself emerge as an organizing trope that, through geographic shorthand, obscures the contested and dynamic nature of social processes and functions. As an ‘‘inside-out’’ version of the continental region, such a maritime region, like the faux-heterotopic cruise ship critiqued by Harvey, would reverse our sense of the elements and highlight some social processes (connections, migrations) over others (state-formation, settlement), but it would fall short of a fundamental epistemological revolution. ‘‘And what,’’ to quote Harvey again, ‘‘is the critical, liberatory and emancipatory point of that?’’41 Geographers have long struggled with this problem: How can the region be employed as a concept for understanding interactions and processes (within and across its borders) without assigning it existential, pre-social properties of explana- tion? In their attempts at finding solutions, geographers have turned to a range of philosophical and mathematical approaches. Some have emphasized the ways in which space is co-constitutive with time while others have sought to adopt a topological perspective in which scale (and the attendant property of spatiality) is always both internal and external to the object being ‘‘located,’’ so that different scales cannot be ordered in a hierarchical, stable manner.42 There are potentially fruitful overlaps between this dynamic approach to space (and borders and regions) and the Lagrangian approach to fluid dynamics outlined in the previous section of this paper. In both instances, scholars abandon attempts at finding stable metrics that can fix and organize spaces and the activities that transpire within and instead turn their attention to the processes that are continually constructing spatial patterns, social institutions, and socio-natural hybrids. As I have 162 P.E. Steinberg Downloaded by [Harvard Library] at 06:57 15 July 2014 discussed, this approach is particularly pertinent to the study of ocean regions. By turning to the fluidity of the ocean that lies in the middle of the ocean region, we can gain new perspectives not just on the space that unites the region but on space itself and how it is produced (and reproduces itself) within the dynamics of spatial assemblages. Looking at the world from an ocean-region-based perspective thus becomes a means not just for highlighting a new series of global processes and connections, but a means for transforming the way we view the world as a whole. Link to cap Kannen et al. 13 (Andreas Kannen, is scientist in the department ‘Human Dimension of Coastal Areas’ in the Institute for Coastal Research at Helmholtz-Zentrum Geesthacht, Germany “Renewable Energy and Marine Spatial Planning: Scientific and Legal Implications” The Regulation of Continental Shelf Development: Rethinking International Standards. COLP Series, 2013) Aside from conflicts with other demands for using sea space, the main consequence of offshore wind farming is that it creates large-scale fixed structures in an environment that has so far been largely devoid of such structures. it also creates demand for marine spatial planning, which is increasingly called upon I to allocate sea uses to maximize spatial efficiency, reduce conflicts between sea uses and maintain the ecological integrity of the environment, which is discussed in the next section of this paper. One of the underexposed sconsequences of offshore wind farming is that it is changing the way of thinking about sea space altogether.35 Industrial uses such as offshore wind farming essentially regard the sea as an extension of the main- land, as free space that is available for development as long as the technology to do so is available and affordable. This is in line with the marine spatial planning perspective, which also regards the sea as space to be allocated and used, I albeit as sustainably, efficiently and conflict-free as possible. This “industrialization of the sea", however, marks an inescapable turning point in that the formerly ‘empty’ sea is now visibly built on. This fundamental re-casting of the sea as just another available space forces humans to re-evaluate some of the more traditional images we hold of the sea such as that of the sea as a largely natural place.“ An important question is how compatible an industrial perspective such as offshore wind is with these other views of the sea, and how compatible the rational spatial perspective is with more emotional views of the sea as a place. A recent study from Scotland has shown that fishermen’s perspective on the sea is distinctly not spatial, but place-based as they report a particular sense of belonging to the sea and responsibility for it.” A study on the German West coast of Schleswig-Holstein has also shown tht place-based perspectives play an important role in generating sense of place. Asked about their spontaneous associations with the sea, local residents name aspects as diverse as the physical environment, wildlife, nature, fishing, recreation, summer sun, sea food, land reclamation, storm surges, pollution, vastness or a sense of freedom. Aesthetic perspectives, informal recreational benefits derived from being by the sea and symbolic meanings associated with the sea were found to be particularly important in generating a sense of well-being. Imperialism K link Abstract spatiality and mapping is codeterminate with the functioning of the sovereign and imperial order Steinberg 09 (Philip E., Ph.D., Professor of Geography at Durham University, “Sovereignty, Territory, and the Mapping of Mobility: A View from the Outside” Published in June 18, 2009 in Annals of the Association of American Geographers, Volume 99, Issue 3, pages 467-495, http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/00045600902931702#.U8hY2fldV0o, CH) As Sack (1986) notes, at an advanced stage of territoriality, space is viewed so abstractly that it becomes “conceptually emptiable” (and fillable) by an authority looking down from above. Combining Sack’s image with Giddens’s (1985) depiction of the state as a power container, the territorial state can be conceived of as a container that can be emptied and filled, and the contents of which can be rearranged across its points in space. From this perspective, places are perceived of as distinct, but relative, points on the global grid that achieve social character as groups of people transform their local nature. Eventually, these societies evolve into states that are “filled in” and “developed” through the location of production activities at fixed points within these state-areas (Bohannan 1964; Soja 1971, 1980; Burch 1994; Steinberg and McDowell 2003). A key concept here, as stressed by Sahlins (1989), is that the rise of the territorial state is characterized not simply by the construction of its bounded territory as a homogenous administrative zone (as Sahlins charges that Allies` [1980] and Gottman [1973] emphasize), but that the territorial state constructs its space as a differentiated set of points that are amenable to being plotted (and thus manipulated and rationalized) against an abstract spatial grid (see also T. Mitchell 1991). Historically, the development of technologies and institutions for performing cadastral mapping and land surveying stand out as mechanisms through which the state has achieved a “bird’s-eye” view over territory as a means toward achieving social control over people (Bohannan 1964; Kain and Baigent 1992; Vandergeest and Peluso 1995; Edney 1997; Scott 1998; Biggs 1999). Thus, Biggs (1999) locates the origins of the territorial state in national surveying efforts of the seventeenth century. As surveyors mapped royal domains, they graphically noted each village’s affiliation. What had been thought of as a personal relationship came to be expressed as a territorial relationship, and, at the same time, surveyors imposed a grid of abstract space over the domain to facilitate mapping. Eventually, these two phenomena associated with surveying converged in an example of what Pickles (2003) calls “overcoding”: The abstract, geometric space of the map came to define the lived in space of the state, and the territorial relationship between land and sovereign came to be seen as predicating the personal relationship between individual and sovereign. Other scholars have further illustrated the relationship between the way that we hierarchically map space and the way that we hierarchically organize social relationships. Knowledge of space is a crucial tool for control, and the technologies of mapping (and the underlying assumptions about society and space that enable modern mapping), joined with hierarchical systems for drawing lines and assigning names, play a crucial role in constructing instruments of sovereign domination (Akerman 1984, 1995; Carter 1987; Buisseret 1992; Ryan 1996; Edney 1997; Brotton 1998; Burnett 2000; Craib 2000; Hakli¨ 2001; Harley 2001; Pickles 2003; Jacob 2006).4 In short, these scholars emphasize the key role that the ordering of space plays in the construction of state territoriality. This is an important advance over a perspective that simply looks at the bounding of space, but, as Strandsbjerg (2008) notes, these scholars of the cartographic origins of modern state sovereignty still tend to analyze the state as an isolated unit. Given that the modern institution of sovereignty necessarily exists within a system of sovereign units, a study of the modern state (or a story of its origins) that works only from the perspective of the inward-looking aspect of sovereignty cannot be complete. As Taylor (1995) asserts, the starting point of political geography (and political history) must be a theory of the states rather than a theory of the state. In a similar vein, geographies and histories of territoriality (or the ordering of space) must examine not just the “emptiable” and “fillable” space constructed inside the territories of sovereign states but also the spaces ontheoutsidethataredesignatedasnotbeingamenable to this organization of space. Otherwise, any study of state territoriality risks falling into the “territorial trap” wherein states are viewed as internally coherent units, existing ontologically prior to the overall ordering of the state system, and wherein cross-border processes can be viewed only as “international relations” among these preexisting states (Agnew 1994; see also Sparke 2005). I am asserting here that the same “mapping” of space that permits (and is expressed by) the surveying of a national border to define an inside also defines an outside by making possible the conceptualization of a world of equivalent states existing next to each other in relative space. Indeed, for Walker (1993) and Bartelson (1995) , the discursive and material division of the world into insides and outsides is perhaps the fundamental act of sovereignty. The outside is not simply the residual space remaining after declaring an inside. If that is the prevailing image of the outside, it is an image that is itself constructed in tandem with the construction of a particular image of the inside. For instance, the discourse of “containment” that prevailed during the Cold War was based on the idea of the state as a container set against a potentially threatening environment, even though this environment (or outside) was itself the territory of other sovereign states that were constructing similar discourses about themselves and their neighbors ( Chilton 1996). Similarly, throughout the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, the dominant image of the ocean as an “outside” beyond the universe of state-civilizations provided a pretext for banning all social actors operating from this outside space. Yet this representation of the ocean was itself a construction of, and within, a system: The idealization of the ocean as the ultimate outside, beyond civilization, bolstered the construction of the rest of the world—the universe of territorial states—as sovereign insides (Thomson 1994; Steinberg 2001). At the global scale, this division of the world into “insides” that matter and “outsides” that serve to facilitate development of the “insides” typically is achieved through reference to geophysical properties. In particular, the division of the world into fundamental elements—land and sea—is viewed as the originary act of the modern socio-spatial order (Schmitt 2006b). Connery thus directs attention specifically to changing representations of the sea as a means toward understanding the political division and appropriation of land: “The triumph of a particular oceanic signification is coterminous with the universalization of land concepts, a signification that, thanks to the liquid element itself, leaves no borders, furrows, or markings” (Connery 2001, 177).