EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES Overview and policy issues Outline Types of ER regimes Advantages and disadvantages of fixing/floating Choice of ER regime Empirical Evidence on Exchange Regimes Classifying ER regimes HARD PEGS INTERMEDIATE FLOATING • Currency union • Basket peg • Managed float • Dollarization • Crawling peg • Free float • Currency board • Band Hard pegs Dollarization Currency union Use another country’s currency as sole legal tender E.g. Ecuador, El Salvador, Panama Share same currency with other union members E.g. Euro area, ECCU, CFA franc zone Currency board Legally commit to exchange domestic currency for specified foreign currency at fixed rate E.g. Hong Kong(1983), Estonia(1992), Lithuania (1994), Bulgaria(1997), Bosnia and Herzegovina, Argentina (until 2001) Intermediate regimes Conventional (soft) peg Band Pegged exchange rate within horizontal bands (>±1%) E.g. Denmark (2.25%), Tonga (5%), Hungary (15%) Crawling peg Single currency peg (e.g. Malaysia, Nepal, Namibia) Currency basket peg (e.g. Malta, Fiji, Latvia) Backward or forward looking E.g. Bolivia Crawling band Symmetric or asymmetric E.g. Belarus (5%), Israel (22%) Floating Managed floating No preannounced path for the exchange rate Management by sterilized intervention or interest rate (monetary) policy E.g. Thailand, Indonesia, Mongolia, Singapore, Brazil Independently floating E.g. U.S., Japan, EMU ER arrangements of IMF members (as of July 2005) No separate legal tender Currency board 41 7 Peg (including de facto pegs) Horizontal band Crawling peg 40 5 5 Crawling band Managed floating Independently floating 1 54 34 ...Not as simple as it sounds... de jure vs. de facto exchange rate Distinction between what countries declare as their official de jure regime, and their actual de facto exchange rate practices. (Reinhart and Rogoff 2004) de jure: what the countries say they do de facto: what they actually do Countries listed in the official IMF classification as managed floating, 53 percent turned out to have de facto pegs, crawls or narrow bands. How to distinguish ‘Hard Peg’ and “Floating” from ‘Intermediate’? Is the fixed ER policy an institutional commitment rather than merely a declared policy? YES Hard Peg NO Intermediate Is there an explicit target around which the CB intervenes? YES Intermediate NO Floating The Impossibility Trinity 1. 2. 3. A country must give up one of three goals: Exchange rate stability (by Hard Peg) Monetary Independence Financial Market Integration (absence of capital control) Advantages of fixed ER 1. 2. Provide a nominal anchor for monetary policy Reduce transactions costs and exchange rate risk int’l trade & investment Disadvantages of fixed ER Loss of monetary policy autonomy Loss of exchange rate as a shock absorber =>Consequences for output and employment Loss of lender of last resort (?) Danger of speculative attacks and crashes Loss of seigniorage revenue (in the case of dollarization) No Monetary Policy Autonomy Under Fixed ER with Perfect Capital Mobility Interest rate, i LM Monetary policy cannot stimulate output (on the other hand, fiscal policy is very effective in stimulating output) i0 i1 0 • BP 1 • IS Y0 Y1 Output, Y Perfect capital mobility Real Shocks Not Absorbed (but magnified) Under Fixed ER Adverse real shock would tend to lower activity and interest rates, leading to pressure to depreciate; CB must sell reserves and contract money supply, worsening the fall in output Interest rate, i LM i0 i1 0 2 • • BP 1 • IS Y2 Y1 Y0 Output, Y Perfect capital mobility The Debacle of Argentina’s Peg 60.0 160,000 50.0 140,000 40.0 120,000 30.0 100,000 20.0 80,000 10.0 60,000 - 40,000 (10.0) 20,000 (20.0) 1993Q1 1994Q1 1995Q1 1996Q1 Growth 1997Q1 1998Q1 Interest rates 1999Q1 Debt 2000Q1 2001Q1 Advantages of flexible ER 1. 2. Monetary Policy independence (discretionary policy) Automatic adjustment to trade shocks Monetary Policy Under Floating ER with Perfect Capital Mobility Under flexible ER, monetary policy is very effective in stimulating output (on the other hand, fiscal stimulus leads to appreciation and loss of competitiveness) Think Short x Long run though (and the role of expectations) Interest rate, i LM i0 i1 2 0 • 1 • BP • IS Y0 Y1 Y2 Output, Y Perfect capital mobility Real Shocks Absorbed (and offset) Under Floating ER Real adverse shock (like a fall in external demand) would lower output and interest rates, leading to a depreciation and output recovery due to higher exports and lower imports Interest rate, i LM i0 i1 0 • 1 BP • IS Y1 Y0 Output, Y Perfect capital mobility Disadvantages of flexible ER Exchange rate uncertainty Need to find a less obvious anchor => Consequences for inflation Danger of speculative (irrational?) bubbles Irrational Bubble? Brazil: Daily Exchange Rate in 2001 2.9 2.7 2.5 2.3 2.1 1.9 1.7 ec D ov N O ct Se p g Au l Ju n Ju ay M Ap r ar M Fe b Ja n 1.5 Macroeconomic Stability: Exchange Rate Arrangements or Policy Discipline? • The accession countries maintain a wide diversity of exchange rate regimes, from a currency board arrangement (Estonia) to floating regimes (Poland and the Czech Republic). Hungary's system, a preannounced crawling peg, had a band of 2.25 percent on either side until May 2004. • Estonia has come close to achieving the EU inflation level with its currency board, as has the Czech Republic with its floating regime. Poland has followed approximately the same path of disinflation with a wide-band crawling peg, and Hungary with a narrow-band crawling peg Macroeconomic Stability: Exchange Rate Arrangements or Policy Discipline? What have countries done in the 1990s? 62% (98) No. of countries as % of total 70 60 50 40 30 20 16% (25) 34% (63) 24% (45) 42% (77) 23% (36) 10 0 Hard Peg Intermediate 1991 Source: Fischer (2001) 1999 Floating The bipolar view The intermediate ER regimes are no longer feasible (Summers 1999, Eichengree 1999, Fisher 2001) The # of independent currencies in the world is declining. Lack of theoretical foundation Lessons from soft pegs Long-lived (adjustable) pegs are the exception, not the rule. Exits are often involuntary, the result of a speculative attack. Greater international capital mobility has increased the likelihood of speculative attacks. Pegs can only be maintained if the authorities are prepared to subordinate all other economic policy goals to the exchange rate commitment, otherwise exit is inevitable. Source: Bubula and Otker-Robe (2004) Choice of ER regime Criteria (old and new): Structural characteristics of economy Nature of shocks to which economy is exposed Objective function of national authorities Other considerations (1) Structural characteristics What makes a country more suited for fixed rather than flexible ER? (OCA criteria) Size and openness Labor mobility Wage and price flexibility Fiscal redistribution mechanisms Diversity in production Financial development (2) Nature of shocks Nominal or real? Domestic or external? Temporary or permanent? Symmetric or asymmetric? With or without capital mobility? (3) Objective function Real output stability BOP, competitiveness Price stability, inflation Political objectives e.g. desire for integration (4) Other considerations Credibility of monetary policy Need of inflation tax Adequacy of reserves Strength and regulation of financial system Rule of law Who might be suited to a hard peg? Small open economies whose trade is dominated by a single low-inflation partner Symmetric real shocks Flexible labor market and/or migration Access to fiscal policy as a counter-cyclical tool Countries with low credibility of domestic monetary policy and a high degree of currency substitution Important to have a healthy financial sector and/or access to external credit lines Who might be suited to floating? Economies that are affected by mostly idiosyncratic macroeconomic shocks and have relatively inflexible labor markets Countries with an independent central bank that is credible and able to implement counter-cyclical monetary policy Countries with well-developed capital markets Who might be suited to an intermediate regime? Countries that perceive official ER announcements to have large benefits and low costs BUT are vulnerable to asymmetric shocks that are best addressed by monetary policy Evidence on Exchange Rate Regimes ER regimes and inflation Sample of developing countries (Annual percentage change, median of group) Source: WEO (Oct. 1997) Do hard pegs lower inflation? Source: Ghosh et al (1997). Do hard pegs induce greater fiscal discipline? Inflation (% per year, log scale) Argentina 10000 1000 100 10 1 0.1 1971 5 Fiscal deficit (% of GDP) 4 3 2 1 0 -1 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 Source: IMF, WEO 1981 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1991 2001 Public debt (% of GDP) 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 Does ER variability discourage trade? Study Coverage Results Coes (1981) Brazil, 1965-74 Yes Brada & Mendez (1988) 30 developed & emerging economies, 1973-77 Mixed Caballero & Corbo (1989) 6 emerging economies Yes Paredes (1989) Chile & Peru Yes Medhora (1990) W. African Monetary Union No Savides (1992) 62 developed & emerging economies, 1973-86 Yes (unexpected variability only) Grobar (1993) 10 emerging markets, 1963-85 Yes, mostly Frankel & Wei (1993) 63 countries, 1980, 1985, 1990 Mixed Arize, Osang & Slottje (2000) Paiva (2003) 13 emerging economies, 1973-96 Brazil, 1990-2002 Yes Yes Do currency unions encourage trade? Partial effect of CU on trade, all else constant Tijt = β1Dij + β2(YiYj)t + ΣkβkZijt + γCUijt + uijt Most estimates are positive, Histogram of γ estimates, -2<γ<2 Source: Rose (2004) ... economically large, and statistically significant Histogram of γ estimates, 0<γ<1.2 Does floating afford greater monetary policy autonomy? “Fear of floating” Source: Calvo & Reinhart (2002) Fear of Floating The fear of floating stems from the costs of exchange rate volatility Calvo and Reinhart (2002): many countries that claim to have floating exchange rates do not in practice allow the rate to float freely, but use interest rate and intervention policies as the means of smoothing exchange rate fluctuations. The greater the dependence on foreign currency borrowing, the greater fear of floating (Hausmann and others, 2000) ER regimes and growth Sample of developing countries (Annual percentage change, median of group) Source: WEO (Oct. 1997) ER regimes and growth Impacts on Growth Using a de jure classification, Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2003) find: Developing countries—less flexible exchange rate regimes are associated with slower growth and greater output volatility; Developed countries—regimes do not appear to have any significant impact on growth Which ER regime is best for growth? Average per capita growth rates Ghosh, Gulde & Wolfe (2000) 3.1% Currency board 1.7% Float Levy-Yeyati & Sturzenegger (2002) Fix Regular peg 0.9% 2.0% Intermediate Float 1.2% 1.0% IMF classification Reinhart & Rogoff (2002) Limited flexibility 1.9% Managed float Peg Free float 0.5% 2.2% Levy-Yeyati & Sturzenegger (2002) 1.9% Float Fix 1.5% 1.4% Intermediate 1.0% Own classification Summary of empirical evidence There is some evidence that hard pegs lower inflation There is mixed evidence on hard pegs and fiscal discipline There is some evidence that a common currency increases trade and integration and exchange rate volatility discourages trade and investment There is strong evidence that the extent of monetary policy autonomy under floating ER is limited in practice There is mixed evidence on exchange rate regimes and growth Conclusion Whatever the ER regime is, it must be consistent with macroeconomic policy objectives Role of fiscal and monetary discipline Role of capital controls The choice of ER regime is likely to be of second-order importance to the development of good fiscal, financial, and monetary institutions in producing macroeconomic success