Running Head: THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS Track 11 Undergraduate Student Interactive Session The Federal Reserve and the Global Financial Crisis: How the Federal Reserve Created and Cured the Crisis, 2001-2011 1 THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 2 Abstract Easy credit monetary policies of the United States Federal Reserve, implemented to fight the recession in 2001, led to artificially low interest rates, which led to the creation of bad assets. When trust in those assets was lost, the world was plunged into a financial crisis that only the Federal Reserve and other central banks around the world had the ability to fix. The Federal Reserve was forced to inject billions of dollars into the global economy during the crisis and trillions more after the crisis to keep the global economy stable, all to combat its bad policies from a decade earlier. The Federal Reserve, while it may not need to be more regulated, needs to be more aware of its effects on the global economy in the future. THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 3 The Federal Reserve and the Global Financial Crisis Introduction In a lecture at George Washington University in March 2012, then Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke said, “Central banks, as they have for a number of centuries, can help calm a financial panic” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 64). The period of 2007-2009 experienced less of a financial panic and more of an all out global financial crisis. Central banks around the world needed to do more than simply calm the crisis, they needed to take actions to fight it. This action, necessitated by a crisis caused by failures of U.S. mortgage backed securities, was to create a retaining wall of money to keep the global economy from failing. A combination of Federal Reserve and other central banks’ policies before 2007 led to the mass creation and selling of risky U.S. mortgage backed securities around the world. The crisis began in Europe in 2007 when the actual security of mortgage backed securities was called into question. Trust was lost across Europe, simply because it bore the most risk by buying the bulk of the questionable securities. Central banks assured banks that there would be a free flow of cash to ensure they were “awash in liquidity” (Irwin, 2013, p. 128). The U.S. entered a recession at the end of 2007. Eventually, mortgage backed securities failed investment banks in the U.S. in 2008. To fight this, the Fed cut interest rates and lent money to ensure that funds still flowed around the economy. Then in late 2008, the global economy was on the brink of collapse. The Federal Reserve, the lender of last resort to the U.S., became the lender of last resort to the world. Over $580 billion were loaned to foreign banks by December 2008. To ensure liquidity of banks and other institutions after the crisis, the Federal Reserve began a program of buying large-scale assets in March 2009. A second purchase of large-scale THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 4 assets began in November 2010 (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 102). These have been referred to as Quantitative Easing 1 (QE1) and Quantitative Easing 2 (QE2), respectively. QE1 and QE2 have effectively kept both short term and long term interest rates low, creating “greater confidence in the financial markets” and “promoted growth and recovery.” These actions of the Federal Reserve, and other central banks, essentially saved the global economy from destruction. While the Fed cured the crisis, its causes can be traced back to the policies of the Fed of the early 2000s. In essence, the Federal Reserve had to fix a global crisis which it had inadvertently caused. The Boom The Federal Reserve, led by Chairman Alan Greenspan, began to lower the interest rates and expand the supply of money in 2001, both to combat the recession of that year. The amount of money in circulation rose at a rate “above 10 percent, and remained above 8 percent entering the second half of 2003” (White, 2009, p. 116). Simultaneously, the Federal Reserve lowered the Federal Funds Rate from 6.25 percent at the beginning of 2001 to 1.75 percent at the end of 2001 (White, 2009, p. 116). The rate was lowered even further, reaching a low of 0.98 percent by 2003 (Table 1). This supply of loanable funds began a decrease in real interest rates in the United States. Because of this, 30 year mortgage rates began to fall. Also, because the Federal Reserve lowered short-term rates, adjustable-rate mortgages “became increasingly cheap relative to 30-year-fixedrate mortgages” (White, 2009, p.118). The amount of new mortgages with adjustable rates doubled by 2005 (White, 2009, p. 118). Low rates led to a demand for houses, which increased the prices of existing houses (White, 2009, p. 119). By 2006, the average cost of a house was five times as much as the average income in the U.S., having “increased by about 130 percent” THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 5 since the late 1990’s (Irwin, 2013, p. 99; Bernanke, 2013a, p. 41). Housing prices around the world were also rising. It has been estimated that “the value of all housing in the developed world” rose “to $70 trillion in 2005, from $30 trillion just five years earlier” (Irwin, 2013, p. 100). By 2005, there was what Bernanke called, a “global savings glut,” meaning that there was an excess of money in the global economy (Bernanke, Bertaut, DeMarco, Kamin, 2011b, p. 1). This abundance in global liquidity was a result of the increases in global supplies of money. The glut not only contributed to keeping rates low, but created a demand for safe investments (Bernanke et al., 2011b, p. 1). To meet demand, financial institutions began to bundle several mortgages and sell them to investors at increasing amounts. These mortgage backed securities had very low risk because the bundles were seen as diverse, with the odds of many simultaneous mortgage defaults being very low. At least it seemed so at the time (Irwin, 2013, p. 102). The amount of mortgaged backed securities that were issued skyrocketed. In 2005, $901 billion worth of securities were issued, “up from $36 billion a decade earlier” (Irwin, 2013, p. 102). 55 percent of these United States securities were sold to foreign investors, with the “most prominent source being Europe” (Bernanke, 2011b, p. 8-9). The Crisis in Europe, 2007 On August 9, 2007, the financial crisis was triggered when “the large French bank BNP Paribas temporarily halted redemptions from three of its funds because it could not reliably value the assets” backed by mortgages (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 6). This caused financial institutions around the world to doubt the value and credit rating of similar assets. In Europe, a loss of trust transpired, leading to “a sudden hoarding of cash and cessation of inter-bank lending” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 6). This “contraction in the supply of short-term funds caused overnight interest rates in THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 6 Europe to shoot up,” prompting a “liquidity injection” of €94.8 billion by the European Central Bank (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 6). The Federal Reserve also injected funds and lowered the Federal Funds Rate (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 12-13). Even with these injections and adjustments, the trust problems and credit issues “worsened through the late fall 2007 and early winter 2008” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 12). A contributing factor to the problems was that many “European banks needed dollar funding as opposed to euro funding” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 92). Those European banks held “dollar assets and they [made] loans to support trade, which is often done in dollars, so they needed dollars” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 92). Because of this, on December 12, 2007, the Federal Reserve did a swap “with the European Central Bank and the Swiss National Bank of $20 billion and $4 billion, respectively” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 13). Those central banks then lent those dollars out to the European banks that needed them, thereby “easing dollar funding pressures around the world” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 93). On the same day as the currency swaps, the Federal Reserve announced the creation of the Term Auction Facility (TAF), a “way to get reserves to banks that needed them” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 14). TAFs made sure that dollars made it to “U.S. affiliates of European banks” (Irwin, 2013, p. 131). The first TAF was on December 20, 2007, with the Federal Reserve lending $20 billion, the bulk of which went to banks from Europe (Table 2). Both the currency swaps and the TAF were to ensure that there was a free flow of funds in Europe. Crisis Hits the United States, 2007-2008 Although the United States’ economy had survived the early months of the crisis, “by December 2007, the nation was officially in recession,” and by March 2008, the problems that hit Europe, hit the United States (Irwin, 2013, p. 132). Bear Stearns, an investment bank, relied THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 7 “on lenders being willing to extend them credit against solid collateral” (Irwin, 2013, p. 132). However, its “business of packaging mortgages into securities” began to fall apart when investors doubted whether “the assets Bear had on its books were worth what it claimed they were” (Irwin, 2013, p. 132). By March 13, 2008, Bear Stearns was on the brink of collapse. It had “$14.2 trillion of notional value in derivative contracts—futures, options and swaps—outstanding with thousands of counterparties” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 17). If Bear Stearns failed, the prices of those securities would collapse, affecting the entire financial system (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 17). To prevent this, the Federal Reserve invoked Article 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act, allowing it “to make loans to any individual, partnership, or corporation” (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 17). On March 14, the Federal Reserve made a loan to Bear Stearns worth $12.9 billion. The loan was repaid on March 17. By the next weekend, a deal was brokered for Bear Stearns. The Federal Reserve would take on “$30 billion worth of mortgage-backed securities” and J.P. Morgan would buy the rest (Cecchetti, 2008, p. 17-18). The Federal Reserve also allowed other investment banks to borrow directly. By September 2008, the problems that hurt Bear Stearns hit the investment bank Lehman Brothers. However, this was different, in that Lehman Brothers was insolvent and no one was willing to take it over (Irwin, 2013, p. 143). Lehman Brothers, who filed for bankruptcy protection, was failed by mortgage backed securities. American International Group (AIG), “an insurance company with a $1 trillion balance sheet,” was also failing because of mortgage backed securities. As mortgage backed securities lost value, global holders wanted AIG to assure it could cover the losses. It had neither the assets nor the ability to secure a loan. As a result, along with Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy, the Dow THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 8 Jones Industrial Average fell 504 points (Irwin, 2013, p. 145). To Bernanke and other officials at the Federal Reserve, because AIG had been “so interconnected with both the U.S. and the European financial systems and global banks,” its failure “would have been basically the end” of the global economy (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 85). To keep the financial system going, the Federal Reserve began to loan out trillions of dollars to firms in the United States, as well as firms around the world (Irwin, 2013, p. 151). By December 10, 2008, the Federal Reserve loaned $580 billion to foreign banks (Irwin, 2013, p. 154). To ensure that the funds circulated, interest rates were lowered to historic lows of nearly zero percent (Irwin, 2013, p. 163-164). Central banks around the world did the same (Irwin, 2013, p. 161-162). To keep the global financial system from completely failing, central banks created a retaining wall of money through inflation. It held. Government Recovery Programs and More Actions from the Federal Reserve, 2008-2012 The United States Congress passed legislation called the Troubled Assets Relief Program, or TARP, on October 3, 2008. TARP was established to help bring “more democratic legitimacy” to the financial responses to the crisis (Irwin, 2013, p. 157). The Federal Reserve could not keep bailing out insolvent institutions. Rather, it was a task that Congress and President Bush’s administration needed to undertake. TARP served to loan money by buying toxic assets from banks that had become insolvent as a result of losses from mortgage-backed securities. In all, TARP would be worth about $700 billion. By loaning this amount of money, banks and other financial institutions could remain solvent and maintain proper liquidity, therefore keeping markets secure (Blinder, 2014, p. 179). Only about $430 billion of the $700 billion that TARP allocated was actually loaned. Although originally passed to loan money to banks to cover mortgage-backed securities losses, THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 9 TARP money was also used for other asset guarantees, the auto-industry bailout, and to cover foreclosures (Blinder, 2014, p. 205). Alan S. Binder, in his book “After the Music Stopped,” wrote that TARP is exemplified as potentially one of the most successful economic policy innovations (Blinder, 2014, p. 177), and characterized it as a “smashing success” on justification of having a net cost to taxpayers of only $32 billion (Blinder, 2014, p. 205). In December 2008, the Federal Reserve created the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, or TALF, which fulfilled TARP’s initial purpose of buying troubled assets (Blinder, 2014, p. 206). TALF served to loan money to institutions that would be willing to buy troubled assets up to $200 billion. The U.S. Treasury also promised $20 billion in TARP money. By February 2009, the Fed increased the loan amount to $1 trillion (Blinder, 2014, p. 207). TALF loans started in March 2009, but would only total $70 billion. However, that same month, the Federal Open Market Committee promised it would buy $1.75 trillion worth of Treasury securities, GSEs, and mortgage-backed securities (Blinder, 2014, p. 207). These purchases would come to be known as Quantitative Easing 1. The first Quantitative Easing was done in part because regular monetary policies were no longer applicable. Interest rates could not be cut further but the economy still needed credit. QE started as, what the Fed called, large-scale assets purchases, or LSAPs (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 102). The LSAPs included the Treasury securities, GSEs, and mortgage-backed securities, all of which were guaranteed by the Federal government (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 102). The second Quantitative Easing was initiated in November 2010. This QE was another LSAP. In total, QE1 and QE2 “increased the Fed’s balance sheet by more than two trillion dollars” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 102). By buying the assets, the Federal Reserve reduced “the available supply of those securities” which forced investors “to settle for a lower yield” THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 10 (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 104). To pay for these purchases, the Federal Reserve credited “the bank accounts of the people” who sold the assets, with those accounts being counted as “reserves that the banks would hold with the Fed” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 105). Increases in credit at the end of 2011 were more currency swaps between the Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank “in an attempt to try to reduce strains in Europe” (Bernanke, 2013a, p. 104). To provide dollar funding in Europe, the Federal Reserve lowered “the pricing on the existing temporary U.S. dollar liquidity swap arrangements” that were established during the crisis (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2011). Conclusion In response to the crisis, the U.S. Congress passed a reform bill known as The DoddFrank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act in an attempt to reduce the severity of any future financial crisis. Dodd-Frank, as it is more commonly referred to, overhauled the regulation of financial institutions in the United States, implementing more rules and more oversight. However, the legislation did not have any major affect on the Federal Reserve, even though the blame for the crisis rests on the Federal Reserve. Easy credit monetary policies, which were implemented to fight the recession in 2001, led to artificially low interest rates, which led to the creation of bad assets. When trust in those assets was lost, the global economy was plunged into a crisis that only the Federal Reserve and other central banks around the world had the ability to fight. The Federal Reserve was forced to inject billions of dollars into the global economy during the crisis and trillions more after the crisis to keep the global economy stable, all to combat its bad policies from a decade earlier. The Federal Reserve, while it may not need to be more regulated, needs to be more aware of its effects on the global economy in the long run. THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 11 References Bernanke, Ben S. (2013a). The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis: Lectures by Ben S. Bernanke. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bernanke, B. S., Bertaut, C., DeMarco, L. P., Kamin, S. (2011b). International Capital Flows and the Returns to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003-2007. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers, (1014). Retrieved from http://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/2011/1014/ifdp1014.htm. Blinder, Alan S. (2014). After the Music Stopped: The Financial Crisis, the Response, and the Work Ahead. New York, NY: Penguin Books. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2011). Press Release, November 30, 2011. Retrieved from http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20111130a.htm. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2013). Term Auction Facility (TAF) [data file]. Retrieved from http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_taf.htm. Caravalho, C., Eusepi, S., and Grisse, C. (2012). Policy Initiatives in the Global Recession: What Did Forecasters Expect?. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, 18(2), 1-10. Cecchetti, S. G. (2008). Crisis and Responses: the Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis of 2007-2008. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, (14134). Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w14134. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. (2014). Effective Federal Funds Rate [data file]. Retrieved from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/FEDFUNDS. Federal Reserve Bank in the St. Louis. (2014). M2 Money Stock [data file]. Retrieved from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/M2 THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS 12 Gokhale, J. (2009). Financial Crisis and Public Policy. Policy Analysis, (634), 1-24. Irwin, Neil. (2013). The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire. New York, NY: Penguin Press. White, L. (2008). Federal Reserve Policy and the Housing Bubble. Cato Journal, 29(1), 115-125. THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS Table 1 Effective Federal Funds Rate Date FFR 2001-07-01 3.77 2001-08-01 3.65 2001-09-01 3.07 2001-10-01 2.49 2001-11-01 2.09 2001-12-01 1.82 2002-01-01 1.73 2002-02-01 1.74 2002-03-01 1.73 2002-04-01 1.75 2002-05-01 1.75 2002-06-01 1.75 2002-07-01 1.73 2002-08-01 1.74 2002-09-01 1.75 2002-10-01 1.75 2002-11-01 1.34 2002-12-01 1.24 2003-01-01 1.24 2003-02-01 1.26 2003-03-01 1.25 2003-04-01 1.26 2003-05-01 1.26 2003-06-01 1.22 2003-07-01 1.01 2003-08-01 1.03 2003-09-01 1.01 2003-10-01 1.01 2003-11-01 1.00 2003-12-01 0.98 2004-01-01 1.00 2004-02-01 1.01 2004-03-01 1.00 2004-04-01 1.00 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. (2014). Effective Federal Funds Rate [data file]. Retrieved from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/FEDFUNDS 13 THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS Table 2 Term Auction Facility Data Loan Data Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Dec 20 2007 Borrower 14 Borrower City Loan Amount Interest Rate in Millions CITIBANK NA NEW YORK 10.0 4.650 NORINCHUKIN BK NY BR NEW YORK 10.0 4.650 BANK OF NOVA SCOTIA NY AGY NEW YORK 14.7 4.650 LANDESBANK HESSEN-THURIN NY BR NEW YORK 1,900.0 4.650 LLOYDS TSB BK PLC NY BR NEW YORK 205.9 4.650 WESTLB AG NY BR NEW YORK 2,000.0 4.650 TORONTO-DOMINION BK NY BR NEW YORK 250.0 4.650 BAYERISCHE LANDESBANK NY BR NEW YORK 1,000.0 4.650 WESTPAC BKG CORP NY BR NEW YORK 90.0 4.650 ARAB BKG CORP NY BR NEW YORK 200.0 4.650 SOCIETE GENERALE NY BR NEW YORK 39.2 4.650 MIZUHO CORPORATE NY BR NEW YORK 700.0 4.650 INTESA SANPAOLO SPA NY BR NEW YORK 5.9 4.650 BANCO SANTANDER SA NY BR NEW YORK 191.4 4.650 DRESDNER BK AG NY BR NEW YORK 2,000.0 4.650 DZ BK AG DEUTSCHE ZENTRA NY BR NEW YORK 2,000.0 4.650 MITSUBISHI UFJ TR & BKG NY BR NEW YORK 25.0 4.650 BAYERISCHE HYPO VEREINS NY BR NEW YORK 100.0 4.650 BANK TOK-MIT UFJ NY BR NEW YORK 200.0 4.650 SUMITOMO MITSUI BKG NY BR NEW YORK 800.0 4.650 NATIXIS NY BR NEW YORK 500.0 4.650 NORDEA BK FINLAND PLC NY BR NEW YORK 50.0 4.650 DEXIA CREDIT LOCAL NY BR NEW YORK 2,000.0 4.650 LANDESBK BADEN WUERTTEMB NY BR NEW YORK 2,000.0 4.650 DEPFA BK PLC NY BR NEW YORK 198.0 4.650 WACHOVIA BK NA CHARLOTTE 25.0 4.650 BANK OF MONTREAL CHICAGO BR CHICAGO 475.0 4.650 FIRST TN BK NA MEMPHIS 1,000.0 4.650 BNP PARIBAS HOUSTON AGY HOUSTON 1,400.0 4.650 BNP PARIBAS SF BR SAN FRANCISCO 600.0 4.650 FIRST NB OF NV RENO 10.0 4.650 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. (2013). Term Auction Facility (TAF) [Data file]. Retrieved from http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform_taf.htm THE FEDERAL RESERVE AND THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS Table 3 M2 Money Stock Date 2007-01-01 2007-07-01 2008-01-01 2008-07-01 2009-01-01 2009-07-01 2010-01-01 2010-07-01 2011-01-01 2011-07-01 2012-01-01 Value in Billions 7157.5 7373.9 7625.1 7903.8 8341.7 8435.6 8508.3 8679.1 8937.2 9493.7 9821.5 Federal Reserve Bank in the St. Louis. (2014). M2 Money Stock [data file]. Retrieved from http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/M2 15