Default Correlations and Credit Default Swaps Cara Herlihy Mathematical Sciences Seminar: Monte Carlo Methods May 2, 2011 Herlihy 2 The economic recession of 2006 came as a shock to people all over the world. Many banks, private institutions and individuals not only lost exorbitant amounts of money but lost confidence in the economy as well. When looking back on the recession there is not one, but multiple factors that contributed to the downfall of the economy. Two financial concepts that have been repeatedly criticized for having momentous effects on the recession are Default Correlations and Credit Default Swaps. Both concepts were popular before the recession but became more popular after because of the ways in which their practices were altered due to the unforeseen circumstances of the recession. Correlation is a technique that is used in statistics to demonstrate the strength of the relationship between two variables. Default correlation pinpoints the relationship between two variables defaulting within a portfolio. More specifically, default correlation measures whether risky credit assets are more likely to default together or separately. In simpler terms, if you have a portfolio with two assets (i.e. stocks or bonds), what is the chance that the probability of asset 1 defaulting has an effect on the probability of asset 2 defaulting? If there is a high chance that the probability of the assets directly affects each other then there is a strong default correlation. If not, then the assets are considered to have a low default correlation. There are three types of default correlations that are relevant within a portfolio. Zero correlation means that the outcome of one asset defaulting has no effect on the other asset defaulting which shows that the companies are independent of each other. Positive default correlation between two assets means that if one asset defaults then the other asset is directly affected and will default as well. Negative default correlation between two assets means that if one asset defaults, then the likelihood of the other defaulting will decrease (Pareek). Herlihy 3 Default correlation are an important figure to look at, especially for investment professionals. This is because default correlation is one of three factors in determining the credit risk of a portfolio. Specifically, default correlation affects the risk-return profile of an investment in risky credit assets (Lucas). With the specified correlation, investors are able to compare the expected returns of an investment to the amount of risk undertaken to get the returns. It is a way for the investment professionals to gage if the risk they are taking is worth the losses that might ensue. In order for investors to limit their losses many have started to practice the idea of securitization. Securitization is a financial transaction in which assets are pooled and securities representing interests in the pool are issued. By taking different securities and pooling them together it creates an opportunity to sell them as interest bearing securities (Jobst). After the securities are sold, the interest and payments are paid out to the purchasers of the securities dependent upon the securities tranche. One relatively new way that investors securitize their portfolios is by structuring them as Collateralized debt obligations (CDO). A CDO is a security that is backed by a pool of bonds, loans and other assets. Some examples of the types of securities that could be found in a CDO are Asset-Backed Securities (ABS), Mortgage Backed Securities (MBS), and Real Estate Mortgage Backed Securities (RMBS). CDO’s are divided into tranches, which are then paid out in through a ‘cashflow waterfall’ (Lucas). Tranches are designed to group together a specific class of bonds that have similar levels of risk. The senior tranches receive a higher rating from credit rating agencies because they are generally safer investments. Similarly, the junior tranches receive a lower rating from the credit rating agencies because they are riskier investments. A cashflow waterfall is a payment process that determines which securities get paid out throughout Herlihy 4 the portfolio and in which order. All immediate payments to the investor, including principal and interest, must be paid to the senior tranches before payments can be made to the junior tranches. If all payments are not made to the senior tranches then the payment to the junior tranche investors will not happen (Royer). As a result of this payment process, the junior tranches are higher risk and therefore result in higher return. Collateralized debt obligations are important investment tools because they have the opportunity to be diversified. Diversifying a portfolio reduces the investment risk because it allows for the inclusions of a spread of investments with various levels of risk so that it is not solely dependent on the outcome of one security (Jobst). The concept of diversifying is often compared to the proverb ‘don’t put all of your eggs in one basket’. For instance, if you had a dozen eggs and you put all of them in one basket and that basket falls then all of your eggs break. However, if you separate your eggs into twelve different baskets and one of them happens to fall, you are still left with eleven eggs which isn’t a complete loss. Default correlations within a portfolio have an overall effect on the volatility and return of the portfolio. If the default correlation is low, then the volatility of the portfolio will decrease. This is because if the defaults of the assets are independent, the overall variation in the price over time will be small. On the other hand, if the default correlation within a portfolio is high then the volatility will increase because there is a greater chance that if one assets price changes, the others will be affected and change as well (Lucas). There are various factors that can cause a change in the rate of default correlation. One major factor is the overall state of the economy. If the economy is doing poorly and people are struggling to stay afloat, then they are more likely to default on the loans that they have. The Herlihy 5 economy affects the entire country, so if one person is going to be affected there is a greater chance that more people will be affected as well. Another factor that can cause an influx of default correlations is the state of a particular region or industry. For instance, if a major power plant is the employer of the majority of people in one town, then the town is very dependent on the well being of the plant. If the power plant were to go out of business then the probability of many people in the town defaulting on their loans would increase because they would not be receiving an income. This would greatly increase the levels of default correlations for this area because many people are being affected by the same factor. Yet another factor that could cause a change in the level of default correlation would be if there was a direct relationship between parties. For example, if there is a situation where A pays B for a loan each month but A defaults on their loan to B, then B is more likely to default on a loan to C. This is because the income B should have been collecting from A has ceased, and now B has no funds to pay C with. If there is a web between parties then one party defaulting can have a detrimental effect throughout the rest of the web. Although the concept of default correlation can be applied to any instance in which a loan is taken out, default correlations among subprime mortgages had an important role in the subprime mortgage. The sub-prime mortgage crisis started in 2006 when there was a rise in the number of sub-prime mortgage delinquencies and foreclosures that effected banks and lending institutions. In the years before the crisis, U.S. housing prices were increasing at a promising rate which resulted in many people investing in houses. Banks became more lenient with their criteria for loan qualifications which attracted borrowers that were previously unqualified. Many banks offered Adjustable-Rate mortgages that lured borrowers into loans with extremely low interest rates for a set period of time until the rate was adjusted at a later date. This encouraged Herlihy 6 borrowers to assume difficult mortgages in the hopes that the prices of their houses would continue to appreciate, and they could refinance at a later date (“Variable- Rate Mortgages”). The crisis was initially set off by the bursting of the U.S. Housing bubble in 2006. As prices of houses started to decrease, many of the interest rates on the loans were re-set higher and refinancing for the borrowers became more difficult. This led to a high rate on delinquencies on mortgages because the amounts that people were paying for their houses became more than the actual values of their homes. Many people entered themselves into foreclosure because it was better financial option than the one they found themselves in. Defaults on mortgage loans went from being completely random, to being highly correlated because of the unforeseen circumstances. An example of how default correlations played a role in the financial crisis can be shown through the effects of defaults on mortgages throughout one neighborhood. Assume there are three houses on one street of a particular neighborhood. Owner 1 defaults on his mortgage because he loses his job. As a result, his house goes into foreclosure and this in turn brings down the values of the houses in his neighborhood. Living in an area with decreasing house prices, Owner 2 feels the repercussions of Owner 1foreclosing. The price of his house depreciates and he cannot afford his mortgage payments anymore, so it is in his best financial interest to foreclose. In enters Owner 3. With both of his neighbors foreclosing, the neighborhood becomes less desirable and the prices of Owner 3’s house declines. After refinancing, Owner 3’s house is significantly less than what he anticipated it would be when he singed his adjustable- rate mortgage. As a result he cannot pay the new payment for his mortgage and he defaults on his mortgage loan. Herlihy 7 For my project I did two simulations in R-Code to ill illustrate default correlation. The first simulation I did showed the number of defaults within a portfolio having independent assets. For this simulation a binomial distribution was used because there were only two outcomes possible: whether the loan is being defaulted on or not. I set the parameters for the number of bonds to the value n, and the number of default probability to pavg. The binomial distribution section of the R Code is shown through Figure 1. The second simulation I constructed illustrated the number of defaults within a portfolio when default correlations between assets were correlated. A beta distribution is used because we are interested in the events that take place within a set interval (0,1) (Johnson and Beverlin). The minimum outcome would results from zero of the loans defaulting, and the maximum outcome would results from all of the loans defaulting. In this case, the beta distribution is used to show the variety of the defaults with an appointed value of pavg. For the correlated simulation, the result for the beta distribution placed as a variable in the binomial distribution from the independent version. The value of C, which can be any number that is greater than zero, is used as a constant to illustrate the spread of data. The beta distribution section of the R Code is shown through Figure 2. The graphs that were a result of my simulations clearly illustrate the differences between the frequencies of defaults within a portfolio for default independent examples and default dependent examples. By comparing graphs of C=1 to C=10, we can see how the value of the constant C effects the number of defaults (Figure 2.1).With a smaller number for C we can see that there is a greater variation in the spread of data for the correlated versions by observing the sporadic placements of the dots that signify number of defaults. When the value of C is increased to 10, we can see that the spread of data narrows and data becomes more focused which illustrates a dependent relationship. Herlihy 8 Another financial concept that is highly dependent on default correlations as well as highly critiqued for contributing the financial crisis is the utilization of Credit Default Swaps. Credit Default Swaps were designed to transfer the credit exposure of fixed income products between parties (Mauer, Zhang, and Zhao). In other words, it is a type of ‘insurance’ arrangement in which the buyers pays a premium at periodic intervals in exchange for a conditional payment from the issuer in the event of a default. Investors can purchase Credit Default Swaps if they think that the risk of a company defaulting is about to increase. Investors also buy Credit Default Swaps if the risk of the company defaulting is low but they wish to eliminate all possible risks. Buying a Credit Default Swap is a matter of preference and is not mandatory regardless of the level of default probability of an asset. Credit Default Swaps involves two parties that are directly affected by the risk of a third party (the reference entity) defaulting on its loan. The buyer of the Credit Default Swap agrees to pay a fixed “premium” to the seller of the contract. In return, the seller of the Credit Default Swap agrees to buy the specified bond (or loan) from the buyer at par if a ‘credit event’ occurs. In the instance of a ‘credit event’ the seller pays the buyer an amount equal to the amount they lost on their bond position. The premium that the buyer pays is calculated as the percentage of face value of the bond, and is paid at a periodic interval throughout the contract. It is important to note that the issuer is only required to pay the full amount to the buyer in the occurrence of a credit event, but not in the instances when the bond prices fluctuate (Stulz). Credit Default Swaps are often referred to as types of insurance. Although the two have similarities they also have differences which should be duly noted. The first major difference that the two have is the actual holding of the product that they wish to ‘insure’. In the case of insurance, you need direct economic exposure in order to purchase the insurance. For instance, if Herlihy 9 you want fire insurance on your house you must actually own a house in which you wish to buy the insurance on. In the case of a Credit Default Swap, you do not need to hold or own the bonds in order to buy a Credit Default Swap on them. As long as you pay a premium to the issuer they will cover you in the occurrence of a credit event. Another notable difference between the two is the fact that Credit Default Swaps are traded and insurance policies are not. Credit Default Swaps are constantly traded to shift the levels of risk that issuers take on and by doing so create a profit for people trading them. There is no legal form of trading insurance policies. Seeing that the payment from the issuer is directly dependant on the ‘credit event’ of the reference entity, it is important to clearly define specific criteria for what constitutes a credit event. Bankruptcy, failure to pay, and restructuring are three events that constitute a credit event. Restructuring is when a company changes its payment schedule on bonds. It is categorized as a ‘credit event’ because it usually puts the bondholders at a disadvantage and therefore can cause the rate of their defaults to fluctuate (Restructuring Bond Debt in the Global Marketplace). If the reference entity in question is more likely to default, then the issuer of protection will charge a higher premium rate than that of a less risky asset. The risk of the likelihood of default is shown through the bond tranches and ratings of the bonds. The value of a Credit Default Swap is open for fluctuation based on the probability of the default of the loans. At the time of purchase, the value for the protection buyer is zero. If the probability of default becomes less likely, the value of the Credit Default Swap for the buyer will decrease. This is because the buyer is essentially losing money because they are still required to make the premium payments even though the investment is less risky. If the probability of default increases the value of the Credit Default Swap for the buyer will increase. This is because if the buyer had not opted to purchase the Credit Default Swap and a credit event did occur, they Herlihy 10 would have lost a lot of money on their investment. As the risk of the rate of default increases, the premiums that the buyer is paying the issuer are well spent. Credit Default Swaps are an attractive option not only to reduce the risk of an investment but to use for an advantage on speculation within the market as well. Buyers of a Credit Default Swap benefit by receiving protection on their loans. They are no longer plagued with worry about the probability of default fluctuating because they know that they will receive full payment regardless. Sellers benefit through the income that is acquired in the occasion where Credit Default Swaps are purchased but the third party never defaults. In these instances the issuer is collecting the premiums but they have no obligation to make a payment at the end of the deal. Credit Default Swaps are also used by investors to speculate credit and hedge bond positions in order to make a profit. Credit Default Swaps are more commonly known for their negative implications than their positive ones. The term Credit Default Swap tends to go hand in hand with the term recession and is claimed as being ‘Wall Street’s Worst Invention’ (Gilani). As the result of placing the risk on the issuer of the Credit Default Swap, the lender of the loan has less incentive to monitor the loan that they approved. By shifting their risk, they can keep rewarding loans to people who have poor credentials. In addition, the shifting of risk lead to a false sense of safety among investors. For instance, when then default correlation is low and the issuer has to cover insurance for 1,000 loans if one defaults, it isn’t a big deal. However, people didn’t think about the implications if the default correlation increased. If the issuer covered the same 1,000 loans but this time they had a high default correlation, then they were taking on a large amount of risk. This could end up being a monumental disaster for the issuer if many of the reference entities within the loans default and the issuers have to make many payments. Herlihy 11 A fair Credit Default Swap premium is set to equate the present value of all premium payments to the present value of the expected default loss (Wu). The pricing of each Credit Default Swap is based on the research done by the issuer which focuses on specific information about the reference entity. A deciding factor for the pricing of a Credit Default Swap is also based on if it is a single name contract or a multi-name contract. In the case of single name contracts, the occurrence of a default on a debt will have a direct outcome. Seeing that it is only one entity either they will be able to pay their loan or not. In the event of a multi-name contract, there is more than one entity which does not lead to a direct outcome (Desrosiers). This is because some people may default on their loans while others may not, so the debt will continue making payments. As a result, the Credit Default Swaps are calculated differently based on their varying levels of entities. When looking at the effect that Credit Default Swaps had on the sub-prime mortgage crisis it is helpful to look at the ABX index. The ABX is an index of a series of Credit Default Swaps based on 20 bonds that consist of subprime mortgages. The index started in 2006 and was issued my Markit, a financial services company. Each index is released every six months and references 20 new subprime mortgage backed securities that took place prior to the 6 months in the index (Lucas). The index vintage contains individual sub-indices with tranches AAA, AA, A, BBB, BBB-. Each vintage references exposure to the same underlying 20 sub-prime mortgages. The criteria in order for the mortgage backed securities to be included in the index is strict in order to make the index as accurate as possible. The mortgage backed securities have to have a minimum of $500 million in deal size at the issuance. In addition, there is a limited number of deals within the mortgage backed securities that can be issued with the same originator. And lastly, the underlying obligation must be rated by both Standard and Poor’s and Moody’s. The Herlihy 12 index is interesting and important to investors because it reflects the price at which the Credit Default Swap on the names of the securities are trading but does not represent the actual value of the names. The ABX index is used on Wall Street as a benchmark for the performance of the subprime mortgages and is seen as a focal point for trading in the U.S. sub-prime debt markets. A decline in the ABX shows investor belief that subprime mortgage holders will suffer financial losses. An increase in the ABX index shows investor opinion for subprime mortgage holdings to perform better as investments (“ABX Marks US Subprime Mortgage Inventory at Approx. 65 Cents on the Dollar”). By using these indices it gives investors the ability to hedge risks on subprime mortgages. Similar to Credit Default Swaps, the ABX index is traded as well. Indices are traded based on price terms with a predetermined fixed-spread. Prices are quotes as a percent of par for each individual index of a given vintage. If the trade occurs at par, then the transaction is similar to the transaction of the Credit Default Swap and the buyer of the protection pays the issuer a fixed spread. However, if the trade occurs at a time when the price is not equal to par then depending on the price, one of the parties must make an upfront payment. In the event where the price is at a premium to par, then the seller of the swap must pay the buyer. In the instance where the price is discounted, then the buyer of the protection must pay the seller (“ABX Follow-up”). The ABX pricing is a window that reflects the interest of investors to buy or sell defaults based on their views of the sub-prime mortgages. Looking at the ABX price helps investors’ project cash flow models to project payment information about the securities like delinquencies, defaults and losses. Herlihy 13 The ABX prices saw a steep decline after the housing bubble burst in 2006. This was a result of the developing sub-prime mortgage crisis that deteriorated the prices of homes across the nation. For the 2006-1 index, the prices were slightly higher because securities included for this index were from the last six months of 2005 when housing prices were still appreciating (Figure 3). Correlation patterns of these prices and their changes over time offer insight into how the market perceives riskiness of the different ABX tranches. After the bubble burst and default correlations increased, confidence in the economy specifically in the sub-prime mortgage department decreased. Delinquency rates and a downgrade in the ratings on the securities are found to have a negative effect on the sub-prime mortgage pricing. (Figure 4). In terms of buying a Credit Default Swap for bonds using the ABX index, you must know the coupon, the price, and the factor of the security. The coupon is the annual payment as a percent of the amount being insured at the beginning of each year. The price is the current index value which represents an additional premium price above the coupon percentage. The factor is the portion of principal currently outstanding which is initially 1 ("Pricing ABX Index for Newbies"). In order to buy the ‘insurance’ on the day when the index comes out, you would only pay: coupon price x amount being insured x factor of 1 (because the price index is always 100 for the day). However, if you decide to buy a Credit Default Swap at a later date you will have to pay a different price for protection because the price index fluctuates (Shenn). Seeing that the ABX index was first published in 2006, we have seen the prices for protection increase dramatically as a factor of time. This is because of the high rates of delinquencies on sub-prime mortgage backed securities after the housing bubble burst. As of this point in time, we only have evidence of prices increasing as a function of time but this will not always be the case. When the recession ends and investors become more confident in the economy and start to re-invest in sub- Herlihy 14 prime mortgages, the price as a function of time is likely to decrease because there will be less delinquencies and defaults on these types of loans. For the second simulation of my project in R I elaborated on my previous code to create a rate that an issuer of a Credit Default Swap would charge a buyer. In order to do this, I took the number of defaults from my previous code and sorted them (Figure 5). By doing this it gives a better idea of how greatly the number of defaults varies between the independent and correlated versions. These groupings clearly show the extreme levels of defaults that occur when the default correlation is high (Figure 6). I then proceeded to take the 99th percentile for the number of defaults for both the independent and correlated versions. After getting these results, I created a rate for a premium based on the percentile of defaults (Figure 7). I calculated these rates through the equation: (n*rate)-d99*1 ≥ 0 which simplifies to: rate ≥ (d99/n) . This equation illustrates the rate that the issuer would need to charge in order to protect himself against a maximum loss of 1 %. When looking at the rate calculated through R, the rate I found most interesting and different from other rates was the 95th percentile rate for correlated defaults. In these simulations, the rates of the default correlated versions were much lower when compared to the 99th and 99.5th percentiles. When examining why, I believe I found the solution through looking at the data from the sort command. For the correlated versions, we often had a large number of runs with zero defaults before we resulted in a small number of runs that showed high levels of defaults resulting in right skewed data. Because of these results, only the tail end of these graphs would give us the data needed in order to charge an accurate rate for Credit Default Swaps with correlated defaults. However, the 95th percentile runs the risk of having data that does not show Herlihy 15 high default correlation. As a result, the 95th percentile (which allows a 5 % loss) is clearly too risky for an issuer dealing with high default correlations to use. Knowledge of default correlations on reference entities is necessary information in evaluating the price of a credit default swap. Without the knowledge of the impact on what a high default correlation can do to a portfolio, issuers of Credit Default Swaps would be unable to gage an appropriate rate to charge in order to make a profit. Before the recession, the relationship between default correlations and Credit Default Swaps slipped under the radar because the economy was good and the relationship between the two was causing immediate issues. However, after the recession hit the importance of both of these concepts and their relationship to each other have been extensively studied and attributed to the loss of billions of dollars. Herlihy 16 numdef<-rbinom(100,n,pavg) Figure 1 pact<-rbeta(1,c*pavg,c*(1-pavg)) numdef2[i]<-rbinom(1,n,pact)} Figure 2 C=1 C=10 Figure 2.1 Herlihy 17 Figure 3: The ABX: How Do the Markets Price Subprime Mortgage Risk? (Fender & Schneider). Figure 4: The pricing of subprime mortgage risk in good times and bad: evidence from the ABX.HE indices (Fender & Schneider). Herlihy 18 numdef<-sort(numdef) numdef2<-sort(numdef2) numdef numdef2 Figure 5 [1] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 [40] 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 [79] 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 5 6 6 6 6 [1] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 [27] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 [53] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 [79] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 2 5 13 22 29 31 60 63 Figure 6 d99<-numdef[.99*nruns] d99 d992<-numdef2[.99*nruns] d992 rate1=d99/n rate2=d992/n rate1 rate2 Figure 7 Herlihy 19 Works Cited "ABX Follow-up." Accrued Interest. 21 Feb. 2007. Web. 10 Apr. 2011. <http://accruedint.blogspot.com/2007/02/abx-follow-up.html>. "ABX Marks US Subprime Mortgage Inventory At Approx. 65 Cents On The Dollar." HOUSING DERIVATIVES. Applications and Economics for the U.S. Housing Market, 1 Mar. 2008. Web. 15 Apr. 2011. <http://housingderivatives.typepad.com/housing_derivatives/2008/03/abx-marksus-su.html>. Desrosiers, Mary Elizabeth. Prices of Credit Default Swaps and the Term Structure of Credit Risk. A Professional Master's Project. WORCESTER POLYTECHNIC INSTITUTE, May 2007. Web. 18 Apr. 2011. <http://www.wpi.edu/Pubs/ETD/Available/etd-050107-220449/unrestricted/CDSDefault_Probability.pdf>. Fender, Ingo, and Martin Schneider. "The ABX: How Do the Markets Price Subprime Mortgage Risk." Bank for International Settlements Quarterly Review (2008). Print. Gilani, Shah. "The Real Reason for the Global Financial Crisis…the Story No One's Talking About." Money Morning. Web. 18 Sept. 2008. <http://moneymorning.com/2008/09/18/creditdefault-swaps/>. Jobst, Andreas. "What Is Securitization?" Finance and Development, Feb. 2008. Web. 01 Apr. 2011. Johnson, Paul, and Matt Beverlin. Beta Distribution. Beta Distribution. Paul Johnson, University of Kansas, 11 Mar. 2006. Web. 30 Mar. 2011. <http://pj.freefaculty.org/stat/Distributions/Beta.pdf>. Lucas, Douglas. CDO Handbook. Publication. J.P. Morgan Securities, Global Structured Finance Research, 29 May 2001. Web. 22 Apr. 2011. <http://www.math.ust.hk/~maykwok/courses/MAFS521_07/JPMorganCDOHandbook.pdf>. Lucas, Douglas. Default Correlation: From Definition to Proposed Solutions. Rep. UBS CDO Research, 11 Aug. 2004. Web. 12 Apr. 2011. <http://www.defaultrisk.com/_pdf6j4/Default_Correlation_From_Dfnt_2_Prpsd_Sltns.pdf>. Herlihy 20 Mauer, David, Harold Zhang, and Feng Zhao. Subprime Mortgage Defaults and Credit Default Swaps. University of Texas at Dallas, May 2010. Web. 14 Apr. 2011. <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1615123#>. Pareek, Mukul. "Default Correlations." Riskprep - Risk Education. RiskPrep, 30 June 2010. Web. 11 Apr. 2011. <http://www.riskprep.com/all-tutorials/37-exam-3/114-default-correlations>. "Pricing ABX Index for Newbies." Quant Network - Education Resource from the Financial Capital. 2 June 2010. Web. Mar.-Apr. 2011. <http://www.quantnet.com/pricing-abx-index/>. Restructuring Bond Debt in the Global Marketplace. Publication. Gibson, Dunn & Crucher LLP., 2004. Web. 30 Apr. 2011. <http://media.gibsondunn.com/fstore/documents/pubs/Restructuring_Bond_Debt.pdf>. Royer, Mattieu. Collateralized Debt Obligations- an Overview. Rep. The Professional Risk Managers' International Assosciation. Web. 11 Apr. 2011. <http://www.prmia.org/Chapter_Pages/Data/NewYork/Royer_11_30_04.PDF>. Shenn, Jody. "Subprime Mortgage Bond Derivatives Fall After NovaStar's Loss." Bloomberg - Business & Financial News, Breaking News Headlines. Bloomberf, 21 Feb. 2007. Web. 18 Apr. 2011. <http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive>. Stultz, Renee. "Credit Default Swaps and the Credit Crisis." Journal of Economic Perspectives 2010th ser. 24.1 (2010): 73-92. Print. "Subprime Mortgage Crisis." Subprime Mortgage Crisis. 2010. Web. 1 Apr. 2011. <http://www.stat.unc.edu/faculty/cji/fys/2010/subprime-mortgage.pdf>. "Variable-Rate Mortgage." Wikipedia, the Free Encyclopedia. 15 Apr. 2011. Web. 01 May 2011. <http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Variable-rate_mortgage>. Wu, Liuren. A Primer on Credit Default Swaps. Baruch College and Bloomberg LP, 9 July 2008. Web. 13 Apr. 2011. <http://faculty.baruch.cuny.edu/lwu/papers/CDS_ov.pdf>.