From kolkhoz to holding: Rural Russia and external modernisation Dr. Jouko Nikula Aleksanteri institute University of Helsinki Three Russias Russia’s population can be divided into three roughly equal in size segments, each consisting of about one third of Russians. 1.The most advanced segment of the population is dispersed among the country’s largest cities (counting only cities with populations over a million, this group accounts for 22% of the population); 2. The semi-periphery includes smaller and medium cities where Soviet values predominate 3. The periphery – the traditional, disengaged population of Russia’s towns and villages The rural Russia – 3rd Russia A vast peripheral territory of villages, semi-urban villages and small towns with third of Russia’s population. Mainly depopulated small towns and semi-urban villages with an elderly population A higher concentration in Central Russia, the north-west, industrial areas ion the Urals and Siberia. Villages are most common in the south of Russia and the north Caucasus, where 27% of the country’s rural population is concentrated. In many regions the only villages that survive are those on the outskirts of cities; their population is younger, more mobile and better off, since many of them commute to the city to work. Involvement in the shadow economy teaches people independence from the state, and those who are dependent – pensioners, public sector workers – have no energy or resources to either leave Enterprises and community in Soviet society The soviet (agricultural) enterprise was not just an enterprise, but a basic unit of the (soviet) society and a basis for social and economic power All employees were members in the same labor collective, which offered not only work and wages, but also a wide variety of benefits and services such as medical care, housing, communal services (heating, roads, water supply, etc). Enterprises crucially important also for the communities where they operated Russian Agricultural Reform-The initial situation 1960 1970 1980 1990 The share of collective farms of land 99 98 98 98 The share of private owners of land 1 2 2 2 The share of collective farms of the value of production n.a 69 71 74 The share of collective farms of grain production 99 99 100 100 The share of collective farms of potato production 37 35 35 34 Russian Agricultural Reform Began already in late 1980’s when new legislation gave possibilities to start private enterprises and farms In January 1991 land de-nationalisation and land reform The lands of former kolkhozes and sovkhozes were distributed by means of certificates of ownership to unspecified land plots to their former employees. Together with land reform began also structural re-organisation of agricultural enterprises and promotion of private farmers’ sector development. Russian Agricultural reform - Reorganisation of agricultural enterprises ◦ Workers got chance to choose the form of ownership of the enterprise, ◦ Received shares of the proprerty and land of the enterprise ◦ Were granted a right to use them as they wished – to invest them in partent enterprise, start their own farm, sell them to other shareholders ◦ Got a right to leave the enterprise without any special permit More than 12 000 000 new land-owners in Russia with virtual ownership – no legislation on landownership until 2001. A large part of collective farms adopted insider privatisation method, where only the employees of the enterprise had a possibilities to get shares As a result most of the enterprises became closed jointstock companies (ZAO) where share-holders cannot sell their shares to outsiders before offering them to other share-holders Main aims of the land reform The elimination of state monopoly in land ownership; The re-distribution of lands between different agricultural stakeholders for equal development of different organizational forms of agriculture Creation of conditions for establishment of land market and emergence of private land owners Aims of the reorganisation were: Boost effectivity of agricultural production Reduce subventions for agriculture Modernize the sector Close and merge unprofitable farms Promote the development of family farming alongside large-scale production BUT The middle class people were also committed to large-scale production The value of their education, professional status, income and modern way of life all depended on a work organisation based on large-scale production Most of the rural workers in Russia did not have financial recourses or knowledge to start farms. In 2011 only 2% of certificate holders registered their land rights officially (Rosstat, 2011). State withdrawal and it’s consequences Radical reduction of agricultural subventions Ending of price controls Non-coherent economic policy Sky-rocketing inflation Consquences: Opening of ”price-scissors” Rapid indebtedness Practical non-monetization of economy -10 -15 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 0 I-IX 2005 -5 1990 1985 Growth Rate of GAO (Gross agricultural output) 10 5 Consequences and reactions The growth of barter relations due to demonetization and debts. Continuation of soft-budget constraints i.e, debt-settling or even supporting loss-making and indebted farms No investments in agriculture – decapitalisation of production Symbiotic relationship between large farms and house-hold plots Continuation of system of negotiation and bargaining at enterprise level Farms structure GAO shares by type of farms, % 0% 4% Enterprises 31% Households Farmers 45% 51% 69% 1990 2000 Trends in agriculture since 2000 Putin’s agricultural policy: promote vertical integration State intervention in grain market and greater use of tariffs and quotas Rural projects and programs since 2006 ( rural development programs, credit systems and investments to rural housing, medical care) Introduction of selective subvention policy Developments in late 2000’s Government support for agriculture increased with the launch in 2006 of a two year National Project for agri-food sector development and its continuation through a five-year state programme in 2008–2012. All-Russian Agricultural Census (2006) showed that private farmers own about 30 million hectares or 13 percent of agricultural land in Russia The rest is controlled by large farm enterprises, the successors of the collective and state farms, and increasingly by agroholdings, both domestic and foreign In 2009 that of the 12 million land shareholders, only 400 000 owners had been able to convert their shares to private property. More than 90 percent of privately owned land is owned as land shares, not as physical plots of land Russian agriculture today Agriculture represents: ◦ 4.8 % of Russia’s total GDP (together with food industry approx. 10 %) ◦ 9.8 % of total employment Fairly low rate of growth: 2.7% a year on average 50 % of the total output of the food industry is concentrated in two districts, the Central Federal district (33 percent) and the Privolzhskiy district (17 percent). Grain (wheat) and processed oilseeds (sunflower) make up the largest exports Russia is still a net importer of foodstuffs. New structure of producers Three types of farms: 1) Agricultural enterprises – mostly heirs of kolkhozes and sovkhozes - 27 000 farms - 11-12,000 hectares of land, 2) Family farms - 285 000 farms - 103-108 hectares of land 3) Household plots - 22 800 000 plots/units - 0.51 hectares of land Source: Russian Agricultural Census 2006 The distribution of land, cattle and production according to types of farms in Russia 1990-2009 (%) Indicator Farm type 1990 1995 2000 2005 2009 Agicultural Corporate 98 90 87 80 71 land farms 2 5 6 10 16 Peasant farms 0 5 7 10 13 Corporate 83 70 60 52 17 29 38 44 Peasant farms 0 1 2 4 Corporate 74 50 45 45 45 26 48 52 49 47 0 2 3 6 8 Household plots Cattle farms Household plots Total output farms Household plots Peasant farms The key features of development The large-scale production develops through vertical integration and external investments Simultaneous existence of hyper-large capitalist farms and “decaying social farms” Huge regional differences in the level of development of agriculture, well-being and many structural features The key features of development A large share of rural population still dependent on plot farming as one principal source of income (wage worker society underdeveloped) The share of family farms has remained very low throughout 2000’s. Appearance of international megafarms Russian regime? Dual structure with strong large farms and strong household production continues Plot-farming as a ”social necessity” declines while its role as a commercial activity remains Modernisation of agriculture in the hands of agroholdings – investments in technology and product innovations (Serova 2010) ”State capitalism” – a merger of public and private interests? 22 Key issues The fate of ”social farms”, former sovkhozes and kolkhozes (inefficient, indebted) Simultaneous labor shortage (skilled workers) and labor surplus (unskilled) Obstacles to migration (housing, labor market services, poverty) Very weak financial basis of local administrations The interdependency of agricultural enterprises and local administrations Conflicting tendencies of development of postkolkhozes A large share still unprofitable ( 55 % – 80 %) Symbiotic relationship between (post)kolkhozes and house-hold plots ◦ A way to compensate low wages ◦ A way to keep specialists and skilled labour ◦ The dilemma between social and economic sides of the enterprise (employment vs. efficiency) Conflicting tendencies of development of post-kolkhozes Among the most successful enterprises clear turn towards ”normal business” ◦ specialization and cutting unprofitable production ◦ reduction of labor ◦ introduction of monetary relations between enterprise and community and enterprise and workers (detachment from social nature of the enterprise) ◦ investments in new technologies ◦ trainings for the core labor Post-kolkhoz, features of labour organization A strong ideal of Taylorist labour principles . A high level of standardization is pursued by splitting of the production process in numerous small and separated tasks. The labour force is characterized by high levels of specialization and a stark division between white and blue collar employees. The management style in the farm enterprise is very topdown with a close surveillance on workers, who are expected to be to be obedient and hard working. Extensive standardization difficult to achieve and shortages requires flexibility and improvisation of the workers (Dunn 2008). The regular payment of workers is more an exception than a normality and informal support acts as the real incentive for workers. Supporters of post-kolkhoz A large part of the local governments and the rural population (see e.g. Nikulin 2011). Local governments try to maintain at least part of the control over farm enterprises provide social security and sufficient employment Population: secure livelihoods, due to high job security and socio-economic support and Soviet knowledge infrastructure Maintenance of household plot farming as a safety-net Example 1:Failed adaptation, exhaustion of resources Former sovkhose from Karelia, specialized in milk and potato production Went bankrupt in 2002 Was bought by agricultural machine dealer Made ambitious investment program for renewal of technology Rapid increase in productivity Got support from Karelian government Example 1:Failed adaptation, exhaustion of resources . No increases in wages No reduction of labour Lack of skilled workers Lasting problem with alcoholism Continued to help workers with plotfarming Continued to maintain infrastructure (roads, sewage, etc.) Reasons for failure: Bad management a) owners distant and not agricultural producers but spare-part sellers, b) on-site manager without decision-making powers (production manager only) Wrong products – unprofitable and yielding more losses than income Loss of key specialists (low-wages, no prospects, better jobs available in city) Example 2:Successful transformation Cattle farm from Nizhny-Novgorod One of the biggest farms in the region 3000 head cattle with 7400 hectars of land Director of the farm main owner (76 % of shares) Provides seeds and products for shareholders as a payment for land shares Clear specialization to milk and wheat Example 2:Successful transformation Rents lands from neighbouring farms Paternalism towards local community: Financial assistance in medical treatment, weddings, funerals Transport services, maintains schools, kindergartens, culture club and home for elderly people Paid higher education for local children Example 2:Successful transformation Reasons for success: ◦ ◦ ◦ ◦ Good economic management Appropriate product profile Good relations to regional political leaders Educated specialists Agro-holdings Behind their appearance high indebtness of the agricultural companies Also weak physical and institutional infrastructure promoted the formation of agroholdings Fear of social consequences of mass bankruptcies and diminished food security Developed rapidly in specific sectors, like sugar, grains or pork Situation in late 2011: 250 private companies with more than 15500000 hectares of land Agro-holdings Rouble devaluation made agriculture profitable target of investments External investors from energy sector, food processing Take-overs of insolvent enterprises Radical reorganization of enterprises (management practices, labor, production, etc.) Specialization of production, investments and renewal of production capacities 1800000 1600000 Land distribution by the nature of mother company (hectares) 1= Diversified agribusiness, 2= Food industry, 3= Conglomerates 4= Unidentified, 5= Inputs supply, 6= Agricultural trade, 7= Agriculture, 8=Banking and finance Source: Rylko 2012 1400000 1200000 1000000 800000 600000 400000 200000 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Agroholdings – features (2011) Represent 8 % of all farms in Russia Employ 9 % of total agricultural employment Produce 15 % of total agricultural production Control 8 % of all agricultural land Concentrated to Central Black soil (Belgorod, Orel) and Volgograd areas where agroholdings control over 45 % of land Agroholdings Cutting labor costs by using the latest technology (GSP-operated combines, feeding and milking robots, etc.) Productivity as the key priority Listed in stock-exchanges Owners mainly urban and interests in subsidies, privileges, land-conversion, tax evasion, etc. Production and economy clearly differentiated – farm enterprise only a production-oriented unit Stricter labor organisation and less benefits Work organization Agroholding is very hierarchically organized; the private top-management and the shareholders vs. workers and local community leaders (similar characteristics with the latifundia) A high reliance on cheap labour. The primary focus of the agroholding farm model is reducing costs, especially labour costs by increasingly replacing labour by machinery The management continues to function according to traditional lines, it is top-down and strictly detached from the workers Management The property and labour regime has become stricter than before as limits have been set for the use of the enterprise’s resources. Salary is becoming more important motivation for labour. The fear to lose one’s job is also an important motivation Effects Bring in new technologies into agriculture Effective in lobbying support Improves clearly productivity Strong partners in making Russia as the key player in world grain markets But, diminishes the farm enterprise autonomy, increases bureaucracy and monitoring Supporters of agroholdings The rural and urban elites who have gained high positions within the agroholding-system All agribusiness enterprises, like machinery- and seed traders and financial institutions Make profit from the importance of technology and financial capital Consequences of development of Agroholdings – case from Belgograd area A clear decrease in a standard of living of peasants, reasons: Reduction of workplaces and unemployment growth especially among youth. Low wages in Agroholdings. The average salary in agroholding is no more than 12-14 thousand rubles (250-300 euro) Low wages and low demand of villagers’ skills in the city. Sharp decrease in efficiency of house-hold plot economy Dwindling peasant economy Tight work schedule in agroholdings does not allow work in house-hold plots. Restrictions and a ban on animal husbandry and poultry farming for members of families of those peasants who are working in agroholdings with similar production profile (for sanitary reasons). No help is available to house hold plots from the enterprise Stricter control over the use of the resources of agroholdings Positive (and negative) results ◦ Rural dwellers willing to start independent business activity due to lack of any support of businessmen and farmers in household plot farming ◦ Essential social and mental changes, such as; decrease in alcoholism and theft, growth of a personal responsibility, ◦ At the same time growing atomization of the population and gradual dissolution of former community relations Example 3: Cooperative based agro-holding in Nizhny-Novgorod region Trade 70 shops, mainly in the country side, restaurant, cafés Processing bread-baking plant, mill, sausage factory, fishprocessing factory, lemonade factory, milk plant Agriculture 2 enterprises bought after bankruptcy Management chart Cooperative enterprise The board of the agro-holding Director Manager of dairy farm Manager of meat farm Manager of dairy Manager of slaughter house Manager of bakery Dairy farm (SPK) Coopearative shops (80) Fish factory (OOO) Bakery (OAO) Grain farm (SPK) Slaughter house (OAO) Soft drinks factory (OAO) Production cooperative Material and land shares evenly distributed between workers Before integration to agro-holding: 1500 hectares of land 60 heads of livestock After 3000 hectares 1800 heads Production cooperative 220 workers Average wage is 4000 rubles (about € 100), including: ◦ Constant monthly wage – 50% ◦ Premium bonuses – 50% Modernisation of equipment New vegetable cultures cultivated Elite livestock breeds purchased Training of workers and specialists: new technologies and equipment Regular wage payments Tight control on discipline and use of equipment Reasons for success Good relations with local and regional administrations Cooperation also with research institutes from different regions and local machinery companies Contacts with advanced agricultural enterprises in Moskovskaya Oblast’ Most part of transactions with District administration are mediated by the agroholding Family farms Produce only some 8 % of all agricultural production Weak development not only due to small size but because hostile political economy towards them ◦ Market structures and subventions biased towards large scale production (supplies, technology); soviet legacy and current concentration of production ◦ Private farmers not well networked ◦ Starting a farm means losing all the benefits and possible services from large-scale farm ◦ Banks not willing to lend money –interest rates high ◦ Bureaucratic obstacles: registration, obligation to hire workers (accountant) Household plots Produce nearly 50 % of agricultural production Predominantly for subsistence purposes Examples of successful and large-scale plots-> a way to evade taxes Benefit from symbiosis with large enterprises (technology, input supply) Importance declines along the economic growth (alternative employment) INTERNATIONAL LAND ACQUISITION The global scale of the phenomenon: ◦ The International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) : 15-20 million hectares of agricultural land are subject to transactions or negotiations since 2006. ◦ This is equivalent to all the agricultural land in France, or one fifth of the arable land in the EU. ◦ UN: 30 million hectares by 2009. Getting land in Russia Foreigners cannot own land (individuals or firms or Russian firms with foreign majority) Leasing possible – 49 years Investing to Russian subsidiary which can own land Renting most popular – lot of land and low rents Motives for investing in Russia Short-term: The abundance of unused and underutilized land Low land prices Little competition The potential to increase yields Infrastructure (Black Earth region, Siberia) Financial crisis Long-term: Water resources Global climate change Obstacles: Export barriers Insecure property rights and bureaucracy INTERNATIONAL LAND ACQUISITIONS IN RUSSIA Major foreign investors in RUSSIA Company Country of origin Ha Area of operation AGRICO Ltd Russia /Israel 100.000 ha Stavropol Territory Agro Invest Brinky The Netherlands 3 poultry farms Leningrad region Agro-Invest (Black Earth Farming) Sweden 300 000 ha regions of: Kursk, Voronezh, Lipetsk, Tambov, Samara and Ryazan Agromarket Trade, CJSC USA 100 000 ha Krasnodarsk and Stavropol regions. Agroservice, MTS Estonia 11 994 ha n.a. Agrowill Group, JSC Lithuania 40 000 ha Penza region Alpcot Agro Sweden 490 000 ha regions: Voronezh, Volgograd, Tambov, Lipetsk, Kursk and Kurgan Centre Capital Russia, UK 65 000 ha Moscow region Chernozemye agrocompany UK 60 000 ha Lipetsk region Chinese companies China 80 400 ha Far East of Russia DK Rus Invest Denmark 10 000 ha Saratov region Ekoniva, group of companies Russia, Germany 121 000 ha Central regions Heartland Farms Penza Russia, UK 27 000 ha Penza region Hyundai Heavy Industry South Korea 50 000 ha Far East of Russia Ivolga-Holding, LLC Kazakhstan 666 850 ha Far East of Russia Wimm-Bill-Dann PepsiCo USA 20 250 ha Moscow region RAV Agro-Pro Russia, UK, USA, Israel 150 000 ha Voronezh region Redland Farms Swiss / Sweden 180 000 ha n.a. Sucden France 75 000 ha Penza region, Krasnodar Territory, Lipetsk region Trigon Agri Denmark 144 000 ha Penza region, Samara region The rented land holdings of Trigon A/S (total land bank 181 000 ha) The business strategy of Trigon A/S Focus on large-scale farming clusters Acquire land next to road, rail and storage infrastructure Set up operations next to regional population centres Use primarily highest capacity Western manufactured machinery Use Russian language speaking management teams Selectively implement international best practice Develop integrated commodities production, storage and trading operations Production clusters in geographically diversified areas allowing for weather hedge Expansion of agricultural land portfolio in the Black Earth region (Source: Trigon_Agri_Company_Presentation_2010_10_21.pdf) IMPLICATIONS The possible negative consequences throughout the world Irrational / irresponsible use of land (degradation) Use of agricultural land for other purposes (speculation, construction) Unemployment / employment decline Loss of peasant ownership of the land, the degradation of rural residents – not very relevant in Russian context (large-scale production history) In Russia support for foreign investment – provide employment and maintain services (local administrations and population) For investors interests in efficiency and profitability Potential positive consequences Investment growth in the economy Agricultural development through new technologies and management New standards in agribusiness High competition leads to higher quality of products and services High wages for workers (skilled) in the agricultural enterprises Promotion of education and social support for rural residents THANK YOU !