Determinants of Nascent Social Entrepreneurship Ayus Praharaj 366914 August2015 Department of Applied Economics Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam Supervisor: Dr. Brigitte Hoogendoorn 1 Acknowledgement I would like to sincerely thank my supervisor, Dr. Brigitte Hoogendoorn, who has been an incessant source of inspiration for me. It is because of her constructive criticism, detailed feedback, and nuanced supervision that the quality of this thesishas reached a respectable standard. Her assistance has been crucial to the completion of this report. I would also like to extend my gratitude to my family – especially Pradip Kumar Praharaj, SunitaPraharaj and PrasanjitPraharaj – who remain instrumental in all paths of my life. They are my backbone and have provided tremendous mental support during the entire course of my Bachelor’s degree. It is only for their encouragement and support that I will be able to successfully conclude my undergraduate study with the submission of this thesis. 2 Abstract This cross-national investigation attempts to explore environmental factors that facilitate nascent social entrepreneurial activities, from a macro-level perspective. It makes use of numerous literatures as well as the institutional economics framework to test for both formal (public spending) and informal (post-materialism, education) variables. Utilizing data from the Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) report of 2009, this paper tested multiple hypotheses with the help of five regression analyses. It was concluded that public spending had no bearing on the prevalence of nascent social ventures. While education suggested a noteworthy impact only when assessed for independent effects, post-materialism consistently illustrated a statistically significant influence on the aforementioned dependent variable. These results signaled towards the importance of socially constructed norms and selfexpression value systems, rather than legislative regulations established by governmental institutions. In other words, informal institutions remained an integral element in furthering nascent social entrepreneurship, while such social start-ups did not seem to extract any benefits from changes in the formal institutional structure. Keywords: Social entrepreneurship, nascent social entrepreneurship, Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM), institutional theory. 3 Table of Contents 1. Introduction…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………… 5 2. Literature Review……………….………………………………………………………………………………………….. 9 Definition of Social Entrepreneurship……………………………………………………..………………………………………….9 (Nascent) Social Entrepreneurship and Institutional Theory.…………………………………………………………….. 12 Hypotheses Formulation……………………………………………………..……………………………………………………………. 14 3. Data and Methodology……………….……………………………………………………………………………….. 18 Sources of Data.……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 18 Methodology……………………………………………………..…………………………………………………………………………….. 20 4. Results……….…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………. 23 5. Discussion…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 28 Contribution of Results……………………………………………………….……………………………………………………………. 28 Limitations…………………………………………………………………………..…………………………………………………………… 30 6. Conclusion…………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 33 7. Bibliography………………………………………………………………………………………………………………….. 35 8. Appendices……………………………………………………………………………………………………………………. 40 APPENDIX 1: Description of Variables for Regression Models………………………………………………………………40 APPENDIX 2: Countries and respective Nascent Social Entrepreneurship rates (%)………………………………41 4 Chapter 1 Introduction As the contemporary world evolves at an ever-increasing pace, entrepreneurial activities have come to surface and, in effect, taken center stage. For instance, Mark Zuckerberg and Evan Speigel reformed the social networking arena through their inventions – Facebook and Snapchat respectively. They optimized commercial expertise to dominate the face of digital communication in the modern era. On the other hand, One World Health renewed the ideals of pharmaceutical industry by tying its objectives down with social goals and becoming the first non-profit pharmaceutical company in the United States. It aims at addressing the need of developing countries for affordable medications,to treat infectious diseases, which would otherwise be disregarded due to lack of viable markets (OECD, 2010). Entrepreneurship, as can be witnessed from the aforementioned examples, is a rather broad concept, which addresses several aspects of economics. One of its intriguing branches, i.e. social entrepreneurship, pertains to applying business techniques in an attempt to rectify societal issues such as poverty and inequality. Social entrepreneurs possess the all-important trait of engaging in direct actions rather than relying on an external entity to take the initiative (Martin & Osberg , 2007). Their ability to offer incessant solutions for burning social dilemmas of the day is esteemed and highly revered (Kerlin, 2009). As investigations exemplify the influences of social ventures1, there have been numerous propositions pertaining to increasing the number of social entrepreneurs at global, national and community levels (Babu & Pinstrup-Andersen, 2007). The popularity of diverse social enterprises is on the rise, and they have become increasingly integral to the economic as well as environmental well-being of societies (Mair & Marti, 2006; Zahra et al., 2009). However, simultaneously, several inquiries have highlighted the notion that despite a considerable upsurge in awareness, common masses still fail to grasp the concept regarding drivers of entrepreneurship, especially on a cross-national level.They possess limited understanding of 1 This paper uses “social enterprises” “social ventures” and “social entrepreneurship” interchangeably. 5 social entrepreneurial activities due to a deficiency of empirical studies (Mair & Marti, 2006; Short et al. 2009; Estrin et al., 2013; Stephan, Uhlaner & Stride, 2014). Hence, the lack of cognizance vis-à-vis factors that could potentially impact the prevalence of social enterprises alludes to a need for research onits determinants. Inspections have recently been conducted regarding drivers of social entrepreneurship, using diverse theories, to analyze the influence of pertinent variables (Hartog & Hoogendoorn, 2011; Stephan, Uhlaner & Stride, 2014). As a result, the aim of this study would be to enhance our knowledge relating to prevalence and drivers of a unique feature of social entrepreneurship, from a macro scale (country level). In other words, the attention of this investigation is channeled towards nascent social entrepreneurial activities2 solely, since there are little or no empirical research conducted on prevalence of such infant start-ups specifically.Recent probes have already indicated the possibility of environmental circumstances altering rates of nascent social enterprises (Ruvio & Shoham, 2011). Furthermore, additional research have also illustrated the need to vet nascent social entrepreneurship in order to improve our understanding about determinants for its prevalence, as academicians speculate that there could be considerable variations in patterns and reasons behind ‘organizational emergence’ (Åmo, 2014; Brush et al., 2008; Sarasvathy, 2001). Articles and journals are consumed for the purpose of drawing intuitions about the discrepancies that exist in terms of the frequency of social entrepreneurship. They are then extended to the sub-branch of nascent social entrepreneurship rates. The theory of institutional economics is leveraged to dissect probable factors that could impact the incidence of such social entrepreneurial activities. Douglas C. North (1990) is the primary contributor of institutional framework, which opines that institutionalism consists of restraints that shape human behavior. Germak and Robinson (2014) have already delved into the intrinsic factors that are of significance in determining key motivating elements, whichpropel individuals into getting involved in social entrepreneurship. So, it would be interesting to observe whether extrinsic (environmental) factors play a decisive role in the occurrence of social enterprises as well. Moreover, fresh inspections point to institutional approach as the suitable framework for analyzing effects of environmental factors on the creation and frequency of new social startups (Nicholls, 2010; Urbano et al., 2010). Therefore, overall attention will chiefly be given to 2 Nascent Entrepreneurs are individuals, who claim to have undertaken tangible steps in the past 12 months towards creating a social enterprise, which they would personally own all or part of. The social enterprise has not provided services, nor paid salaries for more than three months 6 environmental factors, which, in the context of this paper, encompass economic, social, political and cultural themes that affect the emergence and prevalence of novel social ventures (Neck et al. 2009; Townsend 2008). There will be formal and informal institutional factors involved, which will cover different aspects of individuals’ environments and in turn, provide us with insights regarding fundamentals that are key to expediting the advent of fresh social entrepreneurial activities. Hence, this gives rise to the following research question: To what extent do environmental factors impact the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship? The methodology used in this paper relates to multiple regression analyses.Five distinct models are constructed with the intention of not only examining the effect of formal and informal institutional factors as a combination, but also shedding light on their independent impacts (i.e. analysis of formal and informal factors separately) on the rates of nascent social entrepreneurial activities.Data regarding nascent social enterprises is extracted from the 2009 Global Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) report. GEM possesses national teams, which devote themselves to conducting surveys and acquiring insights about various environmental factors that might lead to changes in entrepreneurial activities (Terjesen, Lepoutre, Justo, & Bosma, 2012). Their fundamental parameter, as discoursed later in the study, is Total early-stage Entrepreneurial Activity. However, the scrutiny in this paper centers on one of its branches, nascent social entrepreneurial activity. The reasoning for selection of certain key environmental factors stems from the institutional economics approach, as could be observed from narratives provided in multiple segments of Chapter 2. Figures for independent variables are exemplified using multiple databases, namely (i) World Bank, (ii) UNESCO, (iii) World Value Survey, (iv) European Values Study, and (v) International Monetary Fund. In the course of writing this paper, not only are the determinants of social entrepreneurship addressed, but also information can be mined by legislators for enhancing the policy designing process. The outcome for formal institutionsis largely the antithesis of our expectations since public spending did not have any control over the varying rates of nascent social entrepreneurship. The informal institutional variable of education possessed a substantial bearing on the occurrence of nascent social ventures, only when tested for independent effects. It failed to establish an impact of similar importance when assessed jointly with the other variables. The second informal factor of post-materialism seemed to possess statistically significant 7 relationship with the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities overall, therefore, suggesting that societies where individuals share very close bonds would experience higher rates of nascent social entrepreneurship. This introduction is followed by the section of Literature Review, where relevant articles are discussed. Post discourses of appropriate texts, hypotheses are framed accordingly. The data mining procedure and research methodologies are elucidated in the section following Literature Review. Then, the outcomes of regression analyses are described and thoroughly discussed in the subsequent segments. The research work is then concluded by summarizing results and their implications, as well as discussing potential limitations and providing foundations for future research on the theme of (nascent) social entrepreneurship. 8 Chapter 2 Literature Review Definition of Social Entrepreneurship Definition of nascent social entrepreneurial activities stems from the interpretation of social entrepreneurship. However, there are categorical disagreements and disparities regarding the notion of social entrepreneurship, since researchers believe it could possess multiple manifestations (Mair & Marti, 2006; Short et al. 2009; Zahra et al. 2009). The concept was initially brought into the limelight by Bill Drayton, founder of Ashoka: Innovators for the Public, in the 1980s and 1990s. Charles Leadbeater in his publication, The Rise of the Social Entrepreneur, also delved into the dynamics of the terminology, upon which, the use of social entrepreneurship became increasingly common in academic research (Leadbeater, 1997; Williams et al., 2005). Even in the contemporary era, there have been a multitude of investigations with the objective of constructing an apt explanation of the term. Present-day social entrepreneurship encompasses public and private, non-profit and profit activities (Urbano et al., 2010; Zahra et al., 2009), which aim at providing relief to depressed communities from a variety of social issues, including health care and education. It has further been debated that irrespective of whether social entrepreneurial organizations implement nonprofit or for-profit legal forms, they entail a hierarchical arrangement of objectives, whereby social value takes precedence over accretion of monetary resources (Dacin et al. 2010). For instance, Bangladesh Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC) and Aravind Eye Hospital have been imperative to providing support for numerous social issues in developing countries (Daru & Gaur, 2013). BRAC channels its focus towards providing services such as rural capacity building, education, health services and micro-credit to the deprived sections in Bangladesh. Aravind Eye Hospital, on the other hand, countenances price discrimination on eye operations, in accordance with the patient’s ability to pay, in a host of countries across Asia, Africa and South America. Hence, the classification of social entrepreneurship varies with drivers and social circumstances of concern. 9 The abovementioned investigation, conducted by Daru and Gaur (2013), is chiefly macro-level as they inspect the efficacy of social entrepreneurship on a cross-national level. When conducting analysis from an international comparative perspective, social entrepreneurship has to cover regional as well as local differences in terms of what it signifies and the fashion in which it is utilized to resolve social conundrums, in order to maintain cohesion during scrutiny. Since this study is also cross-national and targets to provide quantitative outcomes, the definition of social entrepreneurship utilized in the context of this paper will be rather generalized. Sartori (1970),in the study conducted by Hartog and Hoogendoorn (2011), claimed that to extend the universal applicability of a concept, we must compromise on its specificity. Therefore, the definition that will be used throughout the course of this research is: social entrepreneurship entails individuals or organizations engaged in entrepreneurial activities with the aim of attaining social goals (Bosma & Levie, 2010; Mair & Marti, 2006). Individuals and organizations are stated separately in the aforementioned definition in order to emphasize the view that activities of individuals need not necessarily be from within an organizational context. Also, all features of the definition, namely individuals, organizations and entrepreneurial activities, will be used in their most general forms for the purpose of incorporating all possibilities. As stated previously, entities with both social and commercial motives can still be classified as social enterprises, as long as they accomplish tasks of societal relevance. Peredo and McLean (2006), for example, delineated the hybridity of social entrepreneurial organizations, adducing ventures that consist of both for-profit and non-profit constituents. This was echoed by Neck et al. (2009), as he opined the notion that individuals with amalgamations of for-profit and non-profit motives can yet be considered social entrepreneurs, as long as their actions generate social value. Thus, employing all operational terms in their broadest senses will bring about consistency in the process. However, while there remain discrepancies pertaining to its definition, there has been a robust uniformity observed amongst researchers in terms of the emergence and usefulness of social ventures, both nascent as well as mature. The last few decades witnessed an advent of social entrepreneurship, primarily expedited by countless boiling discourses regarding societal responsibility of businesses (Drayton, 2002; Leadbeater, 1997). Intermittent phases of pecuniary meltdowns have exposed the limitations of public sector as a conventional welfare mechanism, and has fuelled an escalating demand for fresh private divisions (social entrepreneurs) to take charge of burning social dilemmas (Alvord et al., 2004; Sharir & Lerner, 2006; Yunus & Weber, 2008). Furthermore, policy makers and governmental institutions in 10 developing countries have also taken an interest towards endorsing social enterprises. This has been triggered by an influx of new non-for-profit organizations and entrepreneurs, which continue to play integral roles in fighting poverty alleviation as well as other numerous societal concerns (Smith & Barr, 2007; OECD, 2010). The earlier illustrations of BRAC and Aravind Eye Hospital astutely support the aforesaid claim. Mohammad Yunus, who orchestrated the groundbreaking creation of Grameen Bank in Bangladesh, also initiated the micro-financing movement, and works towards providing loans to entrepreneurs that are rather deprived of resources. Likewise, social entrepreneurship has also enjoyed success in the developed nations, aiding the destitute communities and older generation with solutions to issues such as hunger, education, paucity of resources and environmental degradation (Babu & Pinstrup-Andersen, 2007). The overarching theme observed above is the role of diverse enterprisesin attempting to meet the unaddressed needs of masses, which could not be fulfilled by public and other private sector institutions. As notified in the introduction, this study would also exploit institutional economic theory as the framework. Institutional economics, initially coined by Walton H. Hamilton in 1919, pertains to the broader review about the role of institutions in shaping economic behavior (Hamilton, 1987). The concept of institutions is essentially cultivated into a set of authoritative rules, guidelines and constraints utilized for guiding the decision-making behavior in society (North, 2005; Scott, 2001). In other words, it argues regarding the role of environment in modeling how individuals and groups behave. A recent inspection shrewdly showcased the influence of institutional factors on the new dawn of activities with social goals (Urbano et al., 2010). Zahra et al. (2008) professed similar thoughts, typically advocating the conviction that institutions and social enterprises do possess links between them. Thus, expanding on this topic with a refined focus on the impact of environmental factors on nascent social entrepreneurship and corresponding quantitative upshots within an institutional framework, could contribute to existing literature. Moreover, it could also assist in designing policies under different environments, as policymakers would have deeper knowledge about the effect of institutions on the creation of social enterprises. The following section would explore the nexus between institutional theory, environmental factors and social entrepreneurship further. (Nascent) Social Entrepreneurshipand Institutional Theory 11 As witnessed from multiple research, social enterprises are widely viewed as discernible alternatives to governmental and other institutions, to address problems that still persist despite public sector welfare programs (Seelos & Mair, 2005; Yunus & Weber, 2008). As a result, institutional environment is the watershed that social entrepreneurs should leverage in order to invoke a desirable modification in the development of their society. Nyssens (2006) also alluded to the relevance of strongly patterned institutional forms that can advance the process of social entrepreneurial activities. In fact, ample inspections have been conducted to substantiate the influence of institutional environment over social entrepreneurship activity rates (Mair & Marti, 2009). Douglas C. North (1990, 2005), in his two studies, espoused approaches that can aid in utilizing institutional theory for the analysis of environmental factors as the catalyst behind the prevalence of social entrepreneurial activities. He was a staunch adherent of the belief that entrepreneurs adjust their actions and strategies to act on opportunities via the framework of institutions. This, in turn, demonstrates the hold of institutional environments over (social) entrepreneurial activity rates. The view was further extended to vouch for the significance of relationships between social entrepreneurs and their environment by Townsend (2008). North (1990) demarcated two separate branches of institutions, namely: formal and informal. Formal institutions comprise of laws, governmental regulations and constitutional procedures, which are directed at constructing restrictions as well as incentives for individual and organizational actions (Bruton et al. 2010). Informal institutions on the other hand, express the belief and value systems of individuals and organizations. They are rather implicit, culturally inherited and socially constructed institutions. Comparative entrepreneurship analysis, with an institutional economics framework, have primarily been conducted on formal institutions (Estrin et al., 2013), although institutional theorists have advocated for joint effects of both formal and informal branches (Carney et al. 2009). There is a lack of empirical evidence with reference to investigation about informal factors (Stephan & Uhlaner, 2010), as most explorations with respect to informal institutions have primarily been case studies, addressing diverse social needs (Dana et al., 2006; Harris, 2009). Moreover, in general, there are only a handful of quantitative enquiries designed towards inculcating institutional theory approach to examine drivers of social entrepreneurship (Urbano et al. 2010), with very little or no examinations on determinants of nascent social entrepreneurial activities solely. Thus, to answer the calls for advancement of research concerning social entrepreneurship with 12 quantitative methodologies (Dacin et al. 2011, Short et al. 2009), this study targets to build on existing examinations in order to accelerate the process of finding empirical results. Estrin, Mickiewich and Stephan (2013) for example, provided a quantitative assessment of social and commercial entrepreneurship by drawing upon formal institutional as well as social capital theories. By employing framework of institutions in their scrutiny, the likelihood of individuals partaking in social and commercial entrepreneurial activities was observed to be positively influenced by constraints on the arbitrary power of the governments in respective countries. The aforesaid institutional approach also depicted the negative influence of the independent variable, nation-level government activism, on both individual social and commercial entrepreneurship. Similarly, Stephan, Uhlaner and Stride (2014) vetted the bearing that formal and informal institutional factors had on the emergence of social entrepreneurship. Their method of inspection was in line with the ideals of institutional theorists as focus was centered on the joint effects of formal regulatory, informal cognitive and normative institutions. While examining the individual factors, it was observed that both national-level government activism and post-materialism had strongly positive effects on social entrepreneurship. The third variable, socially supportive cultures (SSC), also had a positive impact, though its relationship with social entrepreneurship was found to be rather less robust. The general picture conveyed in the course of the scrutiny was largely in favor of the belief that both informal and formal institutions did play key roles in the expediting social entrepreneurial activities. With the help of findings extracted from these studies, evidence has been procured to discourse the view that both formal and informal institutions could be pivotal environmental ingredients for comprehending key driving forces of social enterprises. As compared to the aforementioned precedents, this paper possesses certain parallels and dissimilarities. Institutional economics remains the framework, leveraging the contribution of Douglas North, which was adduced earlier to argue for its relevance in relation to the control of environmental factors on the prevalence of social entrepreneurship. However, this investigation pertains to nascent social entrepreneurship activities only. Not only is there a lack of examination concerning the impact of environmental factors on nascent social enterprises, but it is also believed that the freshness of start-up activities ostensibly discusses key features of entrepreneurship (Zahra & Wright, 2011). Furthermore, research conducted on such embryonic ventures in Israel delineated a strong correlation between environmental factors and an entrepreneur’s motivation, strategy and success (Ruvio & Shoham, 2011). Therefore, this paper would attempt to extend the existing convictions by probing the influence 13 of diverse environmental factors on nascent social entrepreneurship, within an institutional framework. Because the scrutiny only concerns nascent social entrepreneurial activities, the individuals and organizations ought to be in their infancy, and in accord with its earlier stated interpretation. While the dependent variable is different, the environmental factors utilized in this research would be fairly similar to the ones exploited in the paper of Stephan, Uhlaner and Stride (2014). This investigation, as based on the dynamics of institutional economics solely, will refer to both formal and informal institutions. Public spending, which is closely related to government activism, will represent formal institutions. For informal institutions, post-materialism will be employed in this study as well, in conjunction with education. The following section will provide insights into these environmental factors by exemplifying the rationale behind selecting them, and concluding with multiple hypotheses. Hypotheses Formulation As stated previously, in the next paragraphs, four hypotheses will be proposed on the basis of the theoretical perspective of institutional economics. The objective is to review the prevalence of nascent social enterprises as comprehensively as possible, since it is well understood that the creation of such ventures entails a complex mechanism. For that purpose, we aim to illustrate the function of variables in combinations as well as their independent effects in the section of Results. There have been instances when governments systematically retreated from the provision of public goods, resulting in undesirable market imperfections (Leadbeater, 1997; Nissan, Castaño & Carrasco, 2012; Salamon, Sokolowski & List, 2003). In those cases, the stock of resources available pertaining to public goods either remains static or dwindles steadily (Sharir and Lerner, 2006). Therefore, in order to satiate unfulfilled demands, there is a rise in the emergence of novel non-profit and social organizations, since a lack of government action fuels more demand for social entrepreneurship (Dacin et al., 2010; Mair & Marti, 2009; Zahra et al., 2009). This phenomenon described above is also known as the institutional void theory. The theory, which is an element of the institutional economics framework, suggests that any deficiencies in the endowment of public goods by formal institutions (i.e. governments, in this context), leads to higher rates of social start-ups (Baker et al., 2005). In other words, prevalence 14 of budding (nascent) social entrepreneurial activities will be fairly significant in countries where provisions of social and public services are inadequate (Cornwall, 1998). Mair, Battilana and Cardenas (2012), while scrutinizing various social enterprise profiles, also observed how a socially engaged government led to lower collective demand for social entrepreneurship. Lower social issues,as a result of efficient formal institutions, would reduce the onus that social ventures carry to meet public calls and consequently, diminish the impetus of masses to take part in activities with social goals. Estrin et al. (2013) gathered similar evidence to conclude for a negative correlation between government activism and social entrepreneurial start-ups. Thus, extending the inquiry to a macro-level analysis on multiple countries, with a channeled focus towards nascent social entrepreneurship, the formulated hypothesis is: H1: Public spending has a negative impact on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities. Another variable that can be knotted with the emergence of new and nascent social entrepreneurship is education. Ties between education and social work can be traced back to over a hundred years with schools professing the need to indoctrinate educational principles, which entailed tasks with social motives, in students (Cooke et al., 1912). The article suggested that social motives, being the controlling principle in social organizations, carry considerable weight in the lives of pupils.Contemporary studies have also illustrated positive effects of socially constructed institutions (informal) such as higher level of education on the likelihood of opening up a start-up firm (Arenius & Minniti 2005; Davidsson & Honig 2003).Åmo (2014), in an inspection concerning nascent social entrepreneurs amongst the Norwegian population, observed a predilection of better educated individuals to indulge in such activities.The aforementioned studies, though provide robust claims for education, are representative of only micro-level inquiries. From a macro-level perspective, skills and expertise gained via education can also be leveraged to guide human behavior towards activities that have potential to eradicate social ordeals and optimize utility. An article published by the British Council further argues that expertise imbibed from higher education can play a catalytic role in espousing social enterprises and sustaining the incessant process of innovation across countries (British Council, 2014). For that reason, the background of social entrepreneurs is imperative to the incidence and success of 15 fresh social entrepreneurial activities. People might be keener to launch social start-ups if they possess adequate knowledge to sustain their business (Arenius & Minniti 2005; Chen et al., 1998). Koellinger et al. (2007) also observed similar outcomes in his macro level crosssectional study across 18 nations, as nascent entrepreneurs were primarily educated and displayed animmensesense of optimism regarding their capabilities. In the instances depicted above, the culture of attaining higher education shaped behavior of individuals and countries collectively. Hence, extending the idea onto nascent social entrepreneurial arena, the corresponding hypothesis is: H2: Education has a positive impact on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities. Post-materialism is another pivotal institutional variable in determining the development of nascent social enterprises. Inglehart (2008) postulated that post-materialism is essentially the transformation of individual values, which involves swapping materialistic ideals for a belief system that is post-materialistic in nature i.e. emphasizes self-expression and quality of life. They reflect the culturally inherited foundations of countries, which in turn, constitute the aggregate of all goals that any country’s citizens consider to be of great importance (Schwartz, 2006). In accordance with the concept, if a sizeable portion of the population in a country holds values that are in line with the establishment of social start-ups, then there will be higher probabilities of individuals being motivated to partake in new activities and enterprises with social goals. Prior reviews on a nation-level perspectivehave hinted towards the view that higher degrees of post-materialism in a country also lead to greater probabilities that its citizens would engage in activities such as social entrepreneurship (Hartog & Hoogendoorn, 2011). Interestingly though, Uhlaner and Thurik (2007) established a negative relationship between post-materialism and social entrepreneurship. Post dissecting TEA into its branches, a similar association was also found for post-materialism and nascent social entrepreneurship. However, as suggested by Baumol’s argument (1990) in Hartog and Hoogendoorn (2011), due to modifications in the informal institutions of society (i.e. cultural norms, in this context), post-materialistic societies would drive up novel social entrepreneurial activities. All in all, if countries possess postmaterialistic values, then there would be a higher chance of increase in social start-up ventures. 16 Thus, as with the other hypotheses, prolonging thisview further to nascent social enterprises, the formulated hypothesis is: H3: Post-materialism has a positive impact on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities. 17 Chapter 3 Data and Methodology This section not only introduces the variables explicitly, but also aims at providing narratives about the types of data obtained and their respective sources. In addition, a clear and succinct methodology is defined, which is then leveraged in order to test the respective hypotheses. Source(s) of Data Dependent Variable With the aim of acquiring data regarding prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship, this study makes use of theGlobal Entrepreneurship Monitor (GEM) report,published in the year of 20093. The GEM report bids to provide insights on the topic of national-level social entrepreneurial activities via conducting surveys across countries. The primary objectives of GEM research, with reference to entrepreneurship, focus around establishing cross-country trends of entrepreneurial activity, along with decoding determinants and policies that could assist in inspiring similar undertakings. The GEM report of 2009 added an extra dimension to its coverage since, taking into account the escalating attention of policy makers and academicians in social entrepreneurship, it constructed a new set of questions channeled towards socially motivated activities across countries. Thus, in the course of conducting surveys across 49 different countries4, the GEM group acquired and compiled data about the percentage of individuals within the age bracket of 18-64 years, who are either in the process 3 GEM is an international research program, which began in 1999 as a joint inspection project between Babson College in the US and London Business School in the UK. Today, GEM provides data on the level of entrepreneurial activity with samples of at least 2,000 adults per country and across a total of 54 countries (GEM Report of 2009). 4 The 49 countries are as follows: Algeria, Argentina, Belgium, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Croatia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Guatemala, Hong Kong, Hungary, Iceland, Iran, Israel, Italy, Jamaica, Jordan, Korea, Latvia, Lebanon, Malaysia, Morocco, Netherlands, Norway, Panama, Peru, Romania, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Serbia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Switzerland, Syria, Uganda, the United Kingdom, United Arab Emirates, the United States, Uruguay, Venezuela, the West Bank and Gaza Strip. Data for Denmark are omitted from analysis as they employed a dissimilar data collection medium. Data for Tonga and Yemen were excluded on the grounds that their figures were too exceptional for social entrepreneurship. They are, subsequently, classified as outliers. 18 of or are expected to own (partly/wholly) own a young social enterprises. The GEM reports utilize Total early-stage Entrepreneurial Activity (TEA) as their principle measure of entrepreneurship. TEA is essentially the amalgamation of nascent entrepreneurs and owners of young firms within the surveyed sample i.e. individuals between 18 and 64 years of age. In the GEM report of 2009, they make use of an additional measure of Social early-stage entrepreneurship (SEA), which is the aggregate total of nascent and young business entrepreneurship up to 3.5 years. In that sense, the parameter of SEA is analogous to the general GEM measure of TEA. For this paper, however, the sub-branch of nascent entrepreneurs will be the sole focal point for analysis, due to reasons suggested formerly in this paper. Follow-up questions in their surveys are structured in a manner such that the acquired answers could determine as to whether individuals can be categorized as nascent or young social entrepreneurs (Lepoutre et al. 2013). Therefore, there are clearly demarcated figures available for the different phases of social entrepreneurships, one of which is nascent social entrepreneurship. Henceforth, Nascent Social Entrepreneurial Activity (expressed in percentages) from the Adult Population Survey (APS) of GEM report (2009) is used as our dependent variable (Appendix 2). The statistics are available on Table 6 of the GEM report, where social entrepreneurial activity is divided in terms of phase and gender. Independent Variables Multiple sources were opted for, so as to acquire information about the variables to be used in this inspection. Public Spending: Reports published on World Bank were exploited to extract data for the variable of public spending. It is a renowned source for collecting information regarding the public sector and thus, the variable of public spending is defined in terms of its interpretation provided by World Bank (Appendix 1). Data provided by the institution is generally presented as a percentage of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of countries, which would aid in assessing whether larger public or governmental denomination lead to dwindling social start-ups. Education: One of the specialized agencies of United Nations, UNESCO, was utilized for obtaining data on the variable of education. Furthering its intention of endorsing international collaboration through education, science and culture, UNESCO possesses a comprehensive database on themes relating to the scholastic aspect of countries. Taking 19 account of the percentage of students enrolled from primary to tertiary education seems to be an effective indicator of education, as it elucidates the degree to which students make it to advanced studies. This could, as a result, help in examining whether education levels play a role in furthering the occurrence of nascent social enterprises. In case of missing data for specific countries, figures representative of year 2007 were utilized. For the purpose of this study, they were assumed to be accurate estimates for the succeeding year. Post-materialism: Data for the variable of post-materialism was attained using a 4-item index, established by Inglehart (1997). There are two versions of the post-materialism index, namely 4-item and 12-item indices, for which, data are available in the World Value Survey (WVS). World Value Survey is a global research project, which aims at scrutinizing the evolution of value and belief systems of people over time. The 4-item index is widely employed in investigations (Moors, 2007), as it incorporates noticeably more countries as compared to its 12-item counterpart and hence, will also be used in the analysis of this study. Data for postmaterialism is obtained primarily from the fifth wave in WVS (year 2005-2009), and also the fourth wave (year 1999-2004), in case figures for countries are not available in the former version. In addition, European Values Study (EVS) was then utilized to acquire figures for a fraction of the remaining countries, for which data could not be obtained from WVS. Numbers in the analyses would refer to the percentage of individuals in each country that were classified as post-materialists. GDPper capita (control variable): A potential crucial element in explaining levels of entrepreneurial activities is the per capita income (Carree et al., 2007; Wennekers, 2005). Bosma and Levie (2010) for example, also discoursed about the ability of individuals in richer countries toserve social needs more effectively, since they are self-sufficient to begin with. Furthermore, Wennekers et al. (2005) also highlighted the variable as a predictor for nascent entrepreneurial activity rates. So, in that light, GDP per capita is included in the models as a control variable with the aim of accounting for potential confounding effects. Data regarding GDP per capita (in US dollars) will be acquired from the International Monetary Fund (IMF), where it is adjusted for purchasing power parity as well (PPP). Methodology In order to test the hypotheses, multiple linear regression analyses (Ordinary Least Squared – OLS) are adopted. A host of models are exploited to understand and detect the impact of 20 environmental factors on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship. As stated earlier, GDP per capita (in PPP) is used as a control variable since former enquiries have consistently certified the existence of fundamental relationships between the degree of economic development and a country’s corresponding level of entrepreneurial activity (Reynolds et al., 2005; Wennekers, Van Stel, Carree & Thurik, 2010). It will be used as the sole variable in our first model (Model I) in order to determine whether the effect holds true for nascent social enterprises as well: nseai= α + β1*gdpi + ut Where: nseai– Nascent social entrepreneurship gdpi– GDP per capita However, if the regression analysis fails to establish a significant relationship between the variables in Model I, the control variable of GDP per capita will be removed from the succeeding models, as the insignificance will deem it inappropriate for the role of a control variable. The subsequent regressions will be as follows (the variable of GDP per capita is written in bold to demonstrate that its presence in the succeeding models is dependent on the findings of Model I): Model II: nseai = α + β1*pubi + β2* gdpi + ut Model III: nseai = α + β1* edui + β2* gdpi+ ut Model IV: nseai = α + β1 * pmti + β2* gdpi+ ut Where: nseai– Nascent social entrepreneurship pubi– Public spending edui– Education pmti– Post-materialism gdpi– GDP per capita 21 Lastly, Model V would include all the variables to inspect the effects of concerned environmental factors as a combination. General specification of the all-inclusive model used in this research will be: nseai= α + β1*pubi + β2*edui + β3*pmti+ β4*gdpi + ut The model is representative of the regression analysis that comprises of both informal (education and post-materialism)and formal (public spending) institutional features as independent variables. This would test for three hypotheses at once, since it is a multivariate regression and encompasses all germane variables. As the software tool of STATA is utilized, regressions will be carried out with the use of robust standard errors. In the course of doing so, estimates of regression coefficients remain the same as in the routine OLS regression; however, standard error estimates would instead be more robust to the prospect of failing to meet assumptions of normality and homoscedasticity of errors. 22 Chapter 4 Results Prior to running the regressions, a correlation matrix was constructed to check whether there exist multicollinearity problems between the independent variables. Academicians have argued that cross-sectional inspections tend to aggrandize the detrimental features of multicollinearity (Mason & Perreault, 1991). Nonetheless, presence of significant correlations between independent variables could make the regression findings troublesome to interpret. Results of the matrix are delineated in Table 1, along with the mean value of nascent social entrepreneurship, which is 1.12%. This alludes to the notion that for every 100 individuals across the 49 nations considered in our inquiry; at least one would be a potential nascent entrepreneur. However, there were considerable variations observed in the sample, since figures for nascent social enterprises ranged from 0.1% in Saudi Arabia to 3.4% in Venezuela and Peru. This discrepancy, as mentioned earlier, can be attributed to different institutional structures and environmental circumstances that might prevail in those countries. There exist correlation coefficients of magnitude over 0.5 between certain independent variables, which might signal towards the possibility of existence of multicollinearity. For instance, the control variable of GDP per capita has considerably high correlations with postmaterialism and education (0.6150 and 0.6503 respectively), both statistically significant at the 1% significance level. Surprisingly, relationship between GDP per capita and public spending was not as strong in terms of magnitude (0.3082). So, governmental expenditure has no connection with the monetary strength of the country. As for the other additional observations in the correlation matrix; their correlations are rather weak. Education and post-materialism possess a correlation which is fairly fragile at 0.4115. Similarly, the correlation between public spending and education is not adequately strong (0.4158). Therefore, supplementary spending by governments could impact the behavior of future students and lead to higher enrolments in primary to tertiary education, although the influence will be weak. The final feature witnessed is the insignificant and feeble association between public spending and post-materialism. The 23 implication of the aforesaid statement is that post-materialistic cultural norms have no bearing on government spending and vice-versa. NSEA Post-materialism Education Public spending GDP per capita mean NSEA: 1.12 Table 1: Correlation Matrix NSEA 1 0.4244* 0.2906 0.0591 0.1272 Post-materialism Education Public spending GDP per capita 1 0.4115** 0.0160 0.6150* 1 0.4158** 0.6503* 1 0.3082 1 * Significant at 1% level ** Significant at 5% level. There are multiple remedies available for correcting multicollinearity (Brooks, 2008). One of the mediums is to leave the model as it is, since OLS would still be considered the Best Linear Unbiased Estimator (BLUE). Multicollinearity generally arises due to issues with variables rather than data sets and methodologies. Therefore, the model would still be appropriate for use. However, biased standard errors, as a consequence of multicollinearity, would make it troublesome to correctly interpret conclusions. Brooks (2008) thus, suggests another solution to correct for the problem, which necessitates excluding the variable responsible for multicollinearity from the model(s), GDP per capita, in this context. Yet this is not as straightforward, since one has to account for potential bias when eliminating a variable from any model. This in turn, can be checked for using Model I, as an insignificant relation between GDP per capita and the dependent variable of nascent social entrepreneurial activity would lead to the removal of the former variable, curing for any probable multicollinearity conundrums in the process. In the case of a significant link between the aforesaid two variables in Model I, appropriate measures will then be taken to address multicollinearity. From Table 2 below, it can be observed that GDP per capita does not form a significant link with nascent social entrepreneurship. The implication signals towards the ineffectiveness of the independent variable as control variable in this study. There remains a possibility that in conjunction with multiple variables, GDP per capita could strike a significant relationship with the outcome variable; however, multicollinearity might play a role in their correlation. In view of that, the control variable of GDP per capita can be dropped from the subsequent models, thus, also correcting for multicollinearity in the process. 24 Table 2: Explaining prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship using relevant independent variables (standard errors specified in parenthesis); Dependent Variable: prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship. Model Ia (0.183) 1.035* Content Intercept Model IIb 0.923 (0.464) 0.005 (0.013) Model IIIc -0.689 Model IVd (0.747) 0.484 Model Ve (0.203) 0.027 (0.774) -0.008 (0.016) 0.049** (0.021) 0.009 (0.011) Formal Factors Public Spending Informal Factors 0.060* Post-materialism 0.022** Education (0.019) (0.009) Control Variable GDP per capita 4.86E-06 (5.80E-06) Obs. (N) 48 41 38 40 30 Rsquared 0.0162 0.0035 0.0844 0.1801 0.2346 * Significant at 1% level **Significant at 5% level a Country excluded from analysis due to missing data: West Bank and Gaza b Countries excluded from analysis due to missing data: United Arab Emirates, Argentina, China, Ecuador, Panama, Saudi Arabia, Syria, Venezuela c Countries excluded from analysis due to missing data: United Arab Emirates, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Germany, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Jamaica, Malaysia, Peru, West Bank and Gaza, South Africa d Countries excluded from analysis due to missing data: United Arab Emirates, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Hong Kong, Jamaica, Lebanon, Panama, Syria, West Bank and Gaza e Countries excluded from analysis due to missing data:United Arab Emirates, Argentina, China, Ecuador, Panama, Saudi Arabia, Syria, Venezuela, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Brazil, Germany, Dominican Republic, Jamaica, Malaysia, Peru, West Bank and Gaza, South Africa, Hong Kong, Lebanon. 25 The table also provides a synopsis of the regression analyses that were carried out for the purpose of answering the hypotheses. Models II, III and IV concern Ordinary Least Squared (OLS) regressions. Model II delves into the independent effect of public spending, the formal institutional factor in this investigation, on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship. It can be observed that the explanatory factor only explains about 0.35% of the variation across countries in terms of nascent social enterprises. The findings demonstrate a weak (positive) and considerably insignificant link, failing to establish any parallels between abovementioned independent and prevalence rates of nascent social start-ups. Therefore, an alteration of public sector investment by governments would not bring about any substantial changes in the rise of social enterprises that are still in their nascence or such entrepreneurs who, in the past 12 months, have taken steps towards creating social enterprises that they would own either partly or in entirety. Model III carries out an analogous function to Model II, as it attempts to scrutinize the independent upshot of education on the same dependent variable. On this occasion, the model explains a much greater percentage (8.44%) of the variation in the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship, although it is still a substantially small fraction. The informal institutional variable of Educationseemingly possessesa statistically significant and positive bearing on the prevalence of nascent social ventures, with a correlation of 0.022. Its p-value remains lower than the 5% significance level (0.025). The inference in this case would be that educational institutions inculcate a sense of sanguinity and buoyancy in masses to begin their own social ventures in order to contribute to community. Henceforth, countries that boast of higher education levels should experience greater prevalence rates of nascent social enterprises. Model IV served a similar purpose, with post-materialism being the informal institutional variable vetted on this occasion. The R-squared value is much higher at 18.01%, which implies that the independent variable highlights larger variations of the dependent variable. Postmaterialism has a strongly significant (and positive) impact on the dependent variable, with a fairly weak correlation of 0.06 (p-value = 0.003). This indicates towards the positive influence of societies with emphasis over self-expression and quality of life, on the incidence of novel and nascent social enterprises. Lastly, Model V illustrates a multivariate regression model which includes both the aforementioned formal and informal factors. The proportion of dependent variable explained by this model (23.46%) is quite inevitably greater than all previous models. While education 26 and public spendingpossess insignificant weightages,post-materialism continues to possess a significant positive control (p-value = 0.027) over the emergence of nascent social entrepreneurship at 5% significance level. Most individuals with values of self-expression and sovereignty carry an incentive to rally the cause of stamping out social conundrums. This in turn, could be argued as a reason for larger frequency of nascent social enterprises in countries with fairly greater prevalence of post-materialism. An important element that necessitates deeper scrutiny is the disharmonized sets of countries utilized for each model. To be more precise, different groups of countries were left out in each regression due to lack of data, which could lead to less cohesion in terms of findings (discussed in the ‘Limitations’ section of ‘DISCUSSION’). Nonetheless, these discoveries lead to the repudiation of Hypothesis 1 as the formal institutional variable of public spending does not make any statistically significant difference to the emergence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities, both when tested for independent (only informal or only formal) effects (Model II) and in conjunction with theinvolved institutional variables (Model V). Hypothesis 2 can be partially accepted as education constructs a significant impact on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurship when tested independently (Model III). However, in Model V, when tested for joint effects, it does not seem to strike any significant linkage with the dependent variable of the model. Hypothesis 3 however, can be accepted as post-materialism possesses a statistically significant positive impact on the prevalence of nascent social enterprises in both Models IV and V. 27 Chapter 5 Discussion Contributions of Results According to the estimations found in this study, some informal factors might have a role to play in fuelling impetus for the creation of nascent social enterprises. While post-materialism and education (partially)showed signs of having an impression of statistical significance, the formal institutional variable of public spending did not seemingly have any command over nascent entrepreneurial activities. However, the universal validity of these conclusions might be weak and insubstantial. For instance, the aforesaid finding, which led to a partial approval of Hypothesis 2, does not imply an automatic positive impact (or an insignificant impact, when tested in conjunction with additional environmental factors) of education on accelerating rates of nascent social entrepreneurship. Inquiries conducted by Zahra et al. (2008) and Arenius & Minniti (2005) showcased how education indeed had a significant positive effect and allowed people to leverage their expertise into assembling organizations with societal goals. However, to counter such claims, Blanchflower et al. (2001) suggested a negatively inclined inspiration of education towards furthering the cause of social start-up activities. In addition, additional research has also produced conclusions similar to Model V of this study, since Lin (2000) failed to establish any significant link between education and its impact on variation in the rates of start-ups. The evidence may have been pertaining to the entire branch of social entrepreneurship; however, results could reflect outcomes for their nascent subset in the process. Therefore, contrasting reviews suggest that there might not necessarily be a clear and concrete answer to the question regarding prevalence rates of social enterprises, let alone nascent social ventures. The fact that education is no longer significant when examined with other germane variables (post-materialism in Model V) could point to the notion that other factors are of higher importance when considering infant social enterprises. Hence, policy-makers should 28 also readdress attention to other cultural elements which might trigger nascent social entrepreneurial activities. Another implication could be directed to refining focus towards the micro-level features of education, such as regional educational rates and relative nascent social entrepreneurial rates in respective areas, while retaining a strong grip over the macro-level facets. Probing the quality of infrastructure available and opportunity to social enterprise networking might aid the development of youthful pupils (British Council, 2014), to engage in socially relevant activities in the future. For that reason, espousing more suitable businesses, which could work in collaboration with educational institutions to provide fitting structure to students, is an idea that should be thoroughly inspected. Especially for developing countries, where noteworthy variations in the level of education within the geography exist, micro policies catered towards aspects discoursed above, could assist in empowering social start-ups. Macro-policies, although implemented with efficacy on certain occasions, would lose strength if nascent social entrepreneurial firms do not form the focal point of their strategies. Post-materialism, as listed above, had a significant positive impact on our dependent variable, leading up to the recognition of Hypothesis 3 in the process. Accordingly, societies which prioritized high self-expression and autonomy over materialistic qualities such as economic security, tended to experience greater rates of nascent social enterprise incidence. Inglehart (1997) believed that young affluent cohorts had higher probabilities of engaging in work with social causes, as they were more likely to cherish non-material aims. Therefore, delving into demographical (intergenerational) as well as cultural lacunas would be intriguing research topics. There could be dissimilarities observed in terms of age differences since the older generations, as considered by Inglehart, did not possess the same value systems in order to get involved in social entrepreneurial activities. So, along with the demographical change, there was a cultural shift from materialism to post-materialism, i.e. a transition from economic and physical refuge to autonomy and relative security. Inglehart (1997) anticipates these changes to take place on a global scale and possess traces in each country that experiences such a changeover in cultural mechanism. So, gaining perspective on this relationship would aid in assessment of alterations in the level of (nascent) social entrepreneurial activities. Next, the formal factor of public spending was deemed ineffective in swaying nascent social entrepreneurship entry, prompting the rejection of Hypothesis 1 in the process. The popular belief is that reducing government involvement would lead to a greater demand for social entrepreneurship and hence, a greater share of the populace joining the social enterprise creation bandwagon (Estrin et al., 2013; Mair & Marti, 2009). To be more precise, public 29 spending possessed a negative upshot on the absolute level of social enterprises. However, this viewpoint has not always been supported in empirical research. Studies using institutional framework, from a behavioral economics standpoint, have also shown support to the notion of complementary support of government and private institutions (Heutel, 2014; Stephan, Uhlaner & Stride, 2014). The potential synergy between public and private sector expenditure could extend to more lucrative options for (nascent) social entrepreneurship (Skocpol, 2008). So, there could also be instances where government and concomitant institutions work in tandem with ventures dedicated to societal causes, in order to expedite rates of nascent social entrepreneurial activities. Overall, while noteworthy positive effects were registered for the informal factors of postmaterialism and education, the formal institutional variable of public spending could not lodge a statistically significant impact on the prevalence of nascent social enterprises. Thus, policymakers should work towards designing guidelines that are culturally stimulating. Rather than refining constitutional procedures and tightening screws on government activism, creating regulations that nudge individuals as well as groups towards post-materialistic belief systems. Emphasizing on cleansing cultural values by educating masses regarding collective social welfare could perhaps enhance incidence rates of social start-ups and other similar ventures. Limitations As can be observed with virtually all investigations, this study comes with a few limitations. The first limitation would pertain to dilemmas concerning the definition of social entrepreneurship and therefore, nascent social entrepreneurship. Though a comprehensive procedure was adopted by Lepoutre et al. (2013) to measure the phenomenon, there did not exist any direct questions to explicitly identify social entrepreneurs. The concept of social entrepreneurship could allude to different models across countries, which might hamper the veracity of our findings. Additionally, dissimilar interpretations of social entrepreneurship would also reflect in the diverse definitions of nascent social entrepreneurial activities across countries. Country-level assessments would then deliver incorrect indications about differences in the prevalence rates of (nascent) social enterprises. Furthermore, acquiring solutions for this conundrum would also be troublesome, since the fact that understanding of (nascent) social entrepreneurship fluctuates through countries would hinder the search for any common 30 determinants that could potentially explain incidence rates of the phenomenon from a macrolevel perspective. Secondly, not only GEM lacks coverage as shown above, but also the methodology used by the research program to measure aspects of social entrepreneurship is inefficient. For instance, questions alluding to social and community-based intents were included in the preliminary screening; however, environmental objectives seemed to take a backseat during the whole procedure. This could advocate for the prospect of environmental social entrepreneurship, which is an instrumental aspect, being incomplete or under-represented. The numbers recorded for social entrepreneurship and its branches (i.e. nascent and young business owners) could in turn, be biased and incomplete as well. Thirdly, the sample capitalized in this research should be extended further in order to conduct analysis on a larger dataset. Factor-driven countries were relatively under-represented whereas innovation-driven economies were dominant in the sample obtained from GEM reports. Larger and more even datasets could probably reinforce the reliability of our findings.Also, it becomes problematic to institute significant effects while utilizing smaller samples, as they tend to restrict statistical power. Noteworthy results for the independent variables of post-materialism and education even within a considerably small dataset underpins the validity of our outcomes. Fourthly, when combined with the lack of harmonized data available for explanatory variables, it leads to irregularas well as fewer data points, which can be comprehended from the models used in this study (Table 2).Uneven data availability for the independent variables calls for different groups of countries to be used as per the requirement of each model. This however, could create inconsistencies and lead to lack of structure. In other words, there arises a possibility of some countries being used in one model, but dropped in others due to missing data. These minor differences could make it troublesome to reach a concrete conclusion, especially regarding the independent effects of environmental factors used in this paper, as the samples in entirety are not identical. Perhaps adopting uniform data or similar clusters of countries for all models could solve the aforementioned potential problem. The fifth limitation refers to data extraction for explanatory variables, which could have been more efficient in terms of the uniformity of sources. Data for post-materialism for instance, had to be obtained from World Value Survey (WVS) and European Values Study (EVS). This could lead to asymmetries in data as both sources possess their respective techniques of acquiring statistics regarding post-materialistic values, which in turn, could differ from one 31 another. Furthermore, figures for the sample were mined from multiple waves (fourth and fifth), which represented two different time periods. Therefore, there was a lack of consistency in the numbers attained due to missing data, which might present a false understanding of the impact of the variable on the prevalence rates of nascent social entrepreneurship across countries. This is because of the systematic risks that countries are exposed to, at various stages. For instance, a recession hit country might report materialistic values temporarily due to urgency of monetary security. However, over time, as the recession subsides, post-materialistic values might begin to surface among the populace again. So, for example, high percentages of emergence of new social start-ups in the fourth wave (1999-2004) do not imply an automatic replication of results in the fifth wave. Organized data collection from a single source would be ideal for grinding out consistent and accurate conclusions. Lastly, the methodology for analysis, in this paper, involved regression analyses (OLS), which are not effective for establishing causal relations between variables. They do enhance our understanding regarding the relationship that exists amongst relevant variables; however, do not necessarily signal causality. There could also be numerous extrinsic factors, (not taken into account due to data inaccessibility or other complexities) which might have impacted the emergence of new social start-ups. Moreover, since majority of the data for concerned variables were collected in 2009, i.e. during the economic crisis, it is difficult to predict whether our results are unbiased.This is because economic and political state of affairs could have disturbed the data, influencing the outcomes of this research in the process. Chapter 6 32 Conclusion The concept of nascent social entrepreneurship is in its infancy and possesses the prospective characteristics to entice academicians as well as policymakers. As stated at the outset, findings of quantitative research can smoothen the policy designing process, as they proffer key insights into factors that incentivize initiatives such as administering newborn enterprises that work towards alleviating societal issues. This paper delves into environmental factors that could orchestrate greater rates of nascent social ventures on a cross-country level. Hypotheses were formulated in accordance with the institutional economics approach, with data from GEM report of 2009 utilized for analysis. The propositions used in this study add to existing stream of literature that aims at discovering determinants for social entrepreneurship, from a macro-level standpoint. Using the institutional framework countenanced by Douglas North, this paper explored both formal and informal configurations, which could potentially expedite or hinder prevalence rates of nascent social entrepreneurship. The results indicated possibilities of multiple environmental institutional factors influencing the emergence of nascent social ventures to a considerable extent. However, statistically significant effects were only confined to the informal institutional elements. Postmaterialism possessed a substantial and positive influence on the prevalence of nascent social entrepreneurial activities, when tested for both independent and joint effects.The informal institutional factor of education, however,expressed significantonly when tested independently. The formal institutions, represented by public spending, did not seemingly have an impact on the advent of nascent social start-ups. While results for informal institutions are aligned with the institutional economics approach to a certain extent, formal institutions should be dissected in depth to establish a clear concrete conclusion. Further investigations are required to comprehend the relationships with higher efficacy. Perhaps addition of multiple variables to increase strength of both formal and informal institutional variables in the regression analyses would provide us with a comprehensive picture regarding incidence rates of nascent social entrepreneurship. Additionally, delving into other branches of social entrepreneurial activities, such as young business owners and social entrepreneurs in established organizations (data provided by GEM) could also provide key insights for policymakers to take collective decisions regarding policies that espouse such activities. Analyses could also be segmented demographically as well as by gender, in order to inspect different dimensions of social enterprises. Finally, micro-level analyses pertaining to 33 prevalence rates of nascent social entrepreneurial activities would serve policy-makers well, as that would provide them with granular details about the influence of each environmental institutional factor. It would offer exhaustive information on the designing procedures that they should undertake in order to ensure higher nascent social ventures on the micro-level, which could accordingly reflect in analyses across countries. Bibliography Alvord, S. H., Brown, L. D., and Letts, C. W. (2004).Social entrepreneurship and societal transformation. Journal of Applied Behavioural Science, 40(3), 260-282. 34 Åmo, B. W. (2014). Antecedents, prevalence and manifestations of social entrepreneurship. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Venturing, 6(2), 162-178. Arenius, P. and Minniti, M. (2005).Perceptual Variables and Nascent Entrepreneurship.Small Business Economics, 24(3), 233-247. Babu, S., & Pinstrup-Andersen, P. (2007). Social innovation and entrepreneurship: Developing capacity to reduce poverty and hunger. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), 541-548. Baker, T., Gedajlovic, E. & Lubatkin, M. (2005). A Framework for Comparing Entrepreneurial Processes Across Nations. Journal of International Business Studies, 36, 492-504. Baumol, W. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 893–921. Blanchflower, D.G., Oswald, A.J., and Stutzer, A. (2001). Latent entrepreneurship across nations.European Economic Review, 45 (4-6), 680-691. Bosma, N., &Levie, J. (2010).Global entrepreneurship monitor; 2009 executive report, Global Entrepreneurship Consortium. British Council. (2014, April 30). Social enterprise: the business of higher education? . Retrieved from British Council : http://www.britishcouncil.org/going-global/programme/sessions/social-enterprisebusiness-higher-education Brooks, C. (2008). Introductory Econometrics for Finance . New York: Cambridge University Press. Brush, C.G., Manolova, T.S. and Edelman, L.F. (2008). Properties of Emerging Organizations: An Empirical Test’. Journal of Business Venturing, 23(5), 547 – 66. Bruton, G., Ahlstrom, D., & Han-Lin, L. (2010). Institutional theory and entrepreneurship: Where are we now and where do we need to move in the future?.Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 34(3), 421-440. Carney, M., Gedajlovic, E., & Yang, X. 2009. Varieties of Asian capitalism: Toward an institutional theory of Asian enterprise. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 26(3), 361–380 Carree, M. A., Van Stel, A., Thurik, A. R., &Wennekers, S. (2007). The relationship between economic development and business ownership revisited. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 19(3), 281-291. Chen, C. C, Greene, P. G and Crick, A.C. (1998). Does entrepreneurial self-efficacy distinguish entrepreneurs from managers?.Journal of Business Venturing, 13(4), 295-316. Cooke, F. J. (1912). The social motive in school work. Francis Parker Yearbook, Volume 1. Chicago, IL. The Francis W. Parker School. Cornwall, J. (1998). The entrepreneur as building block for community.Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 3(2), 141-148. Dacin, M.T., Dacin, P.A., &Matear, M. (2011). Social entrepreneurship: A critique and future directions. Organization Science, 22(5), 1203-1213. 35 Dacin, P.A., Dacin, M.T., &Matear, M. (2010). Social entrepreneurship: Why we don't need a new theory and how we move forward from here. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 24(3), 3757. Dana, L. P., Anderson, R. B., and Dana, T. E. (2006). Indigenous land rights, entrepreneurship, and economic development in Canada: “Opting-in” to the global economy. Journal of World Business, 41(1), 45-55. Daru, M., & Gaur, A. (2013). SOCIAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP - A WAY TO BRING SOCIAL CHANGE. Innovative Journal of Business and Management, 26-29. Davidsson, P. and Honig B. (2003).The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs.Journal of Business Venturing, 18(3), 301-331. Drayton, W. (2002). The citizen sector: Becoming as entrepreneurial and competitive as business. California Management Review, 44(3), 120-132. Estrin, S., Mickiewicz, T., & Stephan, U. (2013). Entrepreneurship, social capital, and institutions: Social and commercial entrepreneurship across nations. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37(3): 479–504. Germak, A., & Robinson, J. (2014). Exploring the Motivation of Nascent Social Entrepreneurs. Journal of Social Entrepreneurship, 5(1), 5-21. Hamilton, W. H. (1987). The Institutional Approach to Economic Theory. In R. Albelda, C. Gunn, & W. Waller, Alternatives to Economic Orthodoxy: A Reader in Political Economy (pp. 204-212). New York: M.E. Sharpe Inc. Harris, J. D. (2009). Ethics and entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 407-418. Hartog, C. and Hoogendoorn, B. (2011): Prevalence and Determinants of Social Entrepreneurship at the Macro-Level. H201022, EIM Business and Policy Research. Heutel, G. 2014. Crowding out and crowding in of private donations and government grants. Public Finance Review, 42(2): 143–175 Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and postmodernization: Cultural, economic, and political change in 43 societies. New Jersey, USA: Princeton University Press. Inglehart, R. 2008. Changing values among western publics from 1970 to 2006. West European Politics, 31(1–2), 130–146. Kerlin, J. A. (2009). Social Enterprise: A Global Comparison. Medford : Tufts University Press. Koellinger, P., Minniti, M. and Schade, C. (2007). “I think I can, I think I can”: Overconfidence and entrepreneurial behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 28(4), 502 – 27. Leadbeater, C. (1997). The rise of the social entrepreneur. London: Demos. Lepoutre, J., R. Justo, S. Terjesen, and N. Bosma (2013).“Designing a Global Standardized Methodology for Measuring Social Entrepreneurship Activity: The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Social Entrepreneurship Study,” Small Business Economics. 40(3), 693-714. Lin, N. (2000) Inequality in Social Capital. Contemporary Sociology, 29 (6), 785-795. 36 Mair, J., &Martí, I. (2006). Social entrepreneurship research: A source of explanation, prediction, and delight. Journal of World Business, 41(1), 36-44. Mair, J. and Marti, I. (2009). Entrepreneurship in and around institutional voids: A case study from Bangladesh. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 419-435. Mair, J., Battilana, J., & Cárdenas, J. 2012. Organizing for society: A typology of social entrepreneuring models.Journal of Business Ethics, 111(3), 353–373. Martin, R., & Osberg , S. (2007). Social Entrepreneurship: The Case for Definition. Stanford Social Innovation Review, 28-39. Retrieved from Stanford Social Innovation Review. Mason, C.H., &Perreault, W.D. (1991).Collinearity, power, and interpretation of multiple regression analysis.Journal of Marketing Research, 28, 268-280. Moors, G. 2007.Testing the internal validity of the Inglehartthesis by means of a latent class choice model.ActaSociologica, 50(2): 147–160. Neck, H., Brush, C. and Allen, E. (2009).The landscape of social entrepreneurship.Business Horizons, 52(1), 13-19. Neter, J., Wasserman, W., &Kutner, M.H. (1989).Applied linear regression models (3rd ed.). Homewood, IL: Irwin. Nicholls, A. (2010). The Institutionalization of Social Investment: The Interplay of Investment Logics and Investor Rationalities. Journal of Social Entrepreneurship, 1(1), 70-100. Nissan, E., M.S. Castaño, and I. Carrasco (2012).Drivers of Non-Profit Activity: A Cross-Country Analysis.Small Business Economics. 38(3), 303-320. North, D. C. (1990).Institutions, institutional change and economic performance.Cambridge University Press, New York. North, D. C. (2005).Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Nyssens, M. (Ed.). (2006). Social enterprise: At the crossroads of markets, public policies and civil society. London: Routledge, Taylor Francis Group. OECD (2010), "Social Entrepreneurship and Social Innovation", in OECD, SMEs, Entrepreneurship and Innovation, OECD Publishing, Paris. Peredo, A. M. and McLean, M. (2006). Social entrepreneurship: A critical review of the concept. Journal of World Business, 41(1), 56-65. Reynolds, P. D., Bosma, N., Autio, E., Hunt, S., De Bono, N., Servais, I., et al. (2005).Global entrepreneurship monitor: Data collection design and implementation 1998–2003. Small Business Economics, 24(3), 205-231. Ruvio, A., & Shoham, A. (2011). A multilevel study of nascent social ventures. International Small Business Journal, 29(5), 562-579. Salamon, L.M., S.W. Sokolowski, and R, List (2003). Global Civil Society: An Overview. The Johns Hopkins Comparitive Nonprofit Sector Project. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University. Sarasvathy, S.D. (2001). Causation and Effectuation: Toward a Theoretical Shift from Economic 37 Inevitability to Entrepreneurial Contingency. Academy of Management Review, 26(2), 243 – 63. Sartori, G. (1970). Concept misformation in comparative politics. American Political Science Review, 64(4), 1033-1053. Schwartz, S. H. 2006. A theory of cultural value orientations: Explication and applications.Comparative Sociology, 5(2–3), 137–182 Scott, W. R. (2001). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, Calif., Sage Publications Seelos, C. and Mair, J. (2005). Social entrepreneurship: Creating new business models to serve the poor. Business Horizons, 48(3), 241-246. Sharir, M. and Lerner, M. (2006).Gauging the success of social ventures initiated by individual social entrepreneurs.Journal of World Business, 41(1), 6-20. Short, J. C., Moss, T. W., & Lumpkin, G. T. (2009). Research in social entrepreneurship: Past contributions and future opportunities. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 3(2), 161-194. Skocpol, T. 2008. Bringing the state back in: Retrospect and prospect. Scandinavian Political Studies, 31(2): 109–124. Smith , B., & Barr, T. (2007). Reducing Poverty Through Social Entrepreneurship . In J. A. Stoner, & C. Wankel, Innovative Approaches to Reducing Global Poverty (pp. 27-41). Information Age Publishing, Inc. . Stephan, U., &Uhlaner, L. M. (2010). Performance-based vs.socially supportive culture: A crossnational study of descriptivenorms and entrepreneurship. Journal of International BusinessStudies, 41(8): 1347–1364. Stephan, U., Uhlaner, L., & Stride, C. (2014). Institutions and social entrepreneurship: The role of institutional voids, institutional support, and institutional configurations. Journal of International Business Studies, 308-331. Tan, W., Williams, J.,&Tan, T. (2005) Defining the ‘Social’ in ‘Social Entrepreneurship’: Altruism and Entrepreneurship.The International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal.1(3), 353-365. Terjesen, S., Lepoutre, J., Justo, R., & Bosma, N. (2012). Global Entrepreneurship monitor: 2009 Report on Social Entrepreneurship. Global Entrepreneurship Research Association (GERA). Retrieved from http://www.gemconsortium.org/assets/uploads/1349344229GEM_2009_Social_Entrepreneurship_ Report.pdf Townsend, D. M. (2008). Perceived institutional ambiguity and the choice of organizational form in social entrepreneurial ventures. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 32(4), 685-700. Uhlaner, L., & Thurik, A. R. (2007). Postmaterialism influencing total entrepreneurial activity across nations. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 17(2), 161-185. Urbano, D., Toledano, N. and Soriano, D. (2010).Analyzing Social Entrepreneurship from an Institutional Perspective: Evidence from Spain.Journal of Social Entrepreneurship, 1(1), 54-69. Wennekers, S., Van Stel, A., Carree, M., &Thurik, A. R. (2010). The relationship between entrepreneurship and economic development: Is it U-shaped? Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 6(3), 167-237. 38 Wennekers, S., Van Stel, A., Thurik, A. R., & Reynolds, P. D. (2005). Nascent entrepreneurship and the level of economic development.Small Business Economics, 24(3), 293-309. Yunus, M., & Weber, K. (2008).Creating a World without Poverty: Social Business and the Future of Capitalism. New York: Public Affairs. Zahra, S. A., Gedajlovic, E., Neubaum, D. O., & Shulman, J. M. (2009). A typology of social entrepreneurs: Motives, search processes and ethical challenges. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 519-532. Zahra, S. A., Rawhouser, H. N., Bhawe, N., Neubaum, D. O., &Hayton, J. C. (2008).Globalization of social entrepreneurship opportunities.Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 2(2), 117-131. Zahra, S.A. & Wright, M. (2011).Entrepreneurship’s next act.Academy of Management Perspectives, 25(4), 67–83. Appendices APPENDIX 1: Description of Variables for Regression Models 39 Dependent Independent Variables Variable Control Variable Variable Description Source Nascent Social Entrepreneurial Activity (NSEA) Nascent Entrepreneurs are individuals, who claim to have undertaken tangible steps in the past 12 months towards creating a social enterprise, which they would personally own all or part of. The social enterprise has not provided services, nor paid salaries for more than three months. GLOBAL ENTREPRENEURSHIP REPORT (2009) Public Spending Expense is cash payments for operating activities of the government in providing goods and services as a percentage of gross domestic product. This includes compensation of employees (such as wages and salaries), interest and subsidies, grants, social benefits, and other expenses such as rent and dividends. WORLD BANK (http://data.worldbank.org/topic/public-sector) Post-materialism The degree to which the population of a society are willing to adopt non-materialistic values such as self-expression and autonomy, over materilistic ones such as economic security. WORLD VALUE SURVEY(http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/) & EUROPEAN VALUES STUDY(http://www.europeanvaluesstudy.eu/) Education The (gross) percentage of students enrolled from primary to tertiary education, both sexes. UNESCO(http://data.uis.unesco.org/) GDP per capita Gross domestic product per capita adjusted for purchasing power parities in US dollars. INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND(http://www.imf.org/external/index.htm) APPENDIX 2: Countries and respective Nascent Social Entrepreneurship rates (%) 40 Country Name United Arab Emirates Argentina Belgium Bosnia and Herzegovina Brazil Switzerland Chile China Colombia Germany Dominican Republic Algeria Ecuador Spain Finland France United Kingdom Greece Guatemala Hong Kong SAR, China Croatia Hungary Iran, Islamic Rep. Iceland Israel Nascent Social Entrepreneurship (%) Country Name 2,40 2,20 1,00 0,60 0,20 2,40 1,70 1,40 2,70 0,50 0,80 0,80 0,40 0,40 1,20 1,60 0,80 1,30 0,10 0,20 1,30 2,00 1,00 2,30 0,90 41 Nascent Social Entrepreneurship (%) Italy 0,80 Jamaica 1,20 Jordan 0,30 Korea, Rep. 0,40 Lebanon 0,40 Latvia 1,40 Morocco 0,30 Malaysia 0,20 Netherlands 0,50 Norway 0,60 Panama 0,90 Peru 3,40 Romania 1,30 Russian Federation 0,40 Saudi Arabia 0,10 Serbia 0,40 Slovenia 1,30 Syrian Arab Republic 0,70 Uganda 0,70 Uruguay 1,90 United States 2,90 Venezuela, RB 3,40 West Bank and Gaza 0,20 South Africa 1,20