Advanced Engineering Economics Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Chapter Opening Story General Motors Finances Ethanol Maker Coskata$400 million in cellulosic ethanol plant to produce 100 million gallons a year. At Issue: What would be the GM’s financial risk in investing an Ethanol project? How should GM factor the future fluctuation and uncertainty of gasoline prices into the analysis? Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Methods of Describing Project Risk Sensitivity Analysis: a procedure of identifying the project variables which, when varied, have the greatest effect on project acceptability. Break-Even Analysis: a procedure of identifying the value of a particular project variable that causes the project to exactly break even. Scenario Analysis: a procedure of comparing a “base case” to one or more additional scenarios, such as best and worst cases, to identify the extreme and most likely project outcomes. Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Example 12.1 Transmission-Housing Project by Boston Metal Company Financial Facts: Known Facts Required investment = $125,000 Project Life = 5 years Income tax rate = 40% MARR = 15% Unknown but Predictable (Most Likely Values) Unit variable cost = $15 per unit Number of units = 2,000 units Unit Price = $50 per unit Salvage value = $40,000 Fixed cost = $10,000/Yr Required: Determine the acceptability of the investment Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Sensitivity Analysis for Five Key Input Variables Deviation -20% -15% -10% -5% 0% Unit price 5% 10% 15% 20% $57 $9,999 $20,055 $30,111 $40,169 Demand 12,010 19,049 26,088 33,130 40,169 47,208 54,247 61,286 68,325 Variable cost 52,236 49,219 46,202 43,186 40,169 37,152 34,135 31,118 28,101 Fixed cost 44,191 43,185 42,179 41,175 40,169 39,163 38,157 37,151 36,145 Salvage value 37,782 38,378 38,974 39,573 40,169 40,765 41,361 41,957 42,553 $50,225 $60,281 $70,337 $80,393 Variable most sensitive to NPW – Unit price Variable least sensitive to NPW – Salvage value Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Break-Even Analysis Breakeven analysis is a tool used to determine when a business will be able to cover all its expenses and begin to make a profit from a project. Excel using a Goal Seek function Analytical Approach Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Using a Goal Seek Function in Excel PW of Inflow: 100.5650X + $44,490 PW of Outflow: 30.1694X + $145,113 NPW = 70.3956X - $100,623 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Analytical Approach The NPW: PW (15%) = 100.5650X + $44,490 (30.1694X + $145,113) =70.3956X - $100,623. Breakeven volume: PW (15%)= 70.3956X $100,623 = 0 Xb =1,430 units. PW of cash inflows PW(15%)Inflow= (PW of after-tax net revenue) + (PW of net salvage value) + (PW of tax savings from depreciation = 30X(P/A, 15%, 5) + $37,389(P/F, 15%, 5) + $7,145(P/F, 15%,1) + $12,245(P/F, 15%, 2) + $8,745(P/F, 15%, 3) + $6,245(P/F, 15%, 4) + $2,230(P/F, 15%,5) = 30X(P/A, 15%, 5) + $44,490 = 100.5650X + $44,490 PW of cash outflows: PW(15%)Outflow = (PW of capital expenditure + (PW) of after-tax expenses = $125,000 + (9X+$6,000)(P/A, 15%, 5) = 30.1694X + $145,113 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Scenario Analysis Scenario analysis is a process of analyzing possible future outcomes by considering alternative possible events (scenarios). The analysis is designed to allow improved decision-making by allowing more complete consideration of outcomes and their implications. Source: Wikipedia Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Example 12.3 Scenario Analysis Variable Considered WorstCase Scenario Most-Likely-Case Scenario Best-Case Scenario Unit demand 1,600 2,000 2,400 Unit price ($) 48 50 53 Variable cost ($) 17 15 12 Fixed Cost ($) 11,000 10,000 8,000 Salvage value ($) 30,000 40,000 50,000 PW (15%) -$5,856 $40,169 $104,295 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Constructing a Decision Tree A Company is considering marketing a new product. Once the product is introduced, there is a 70% chance of encountering a competitive product. Two options are available each situation. Option 1 (with competitive product): Raise your price and see how your competitor responds. If the competitor raises price, your profit will be $60. If they lower the price, you will lose $20. Option 2 (without competitive product): You still two options: raise your price or lower your price. The conditional profits associated with each event along with the likelihood of each event is shown in the decision tree. Conditional Profit Competitor’s price Decision Points (0.5) Events ( $60 High Our Price (0.5) -$20 Low High ) Probability Competitive Product (0.7) Market $40 High (0.2) Low No Competitive Product (0.3) Do not market Low (0.8) $10 High $100 Low $0 First Decision Point Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 $30 Second Decision Point Rollback Procedure To analyze a decision tree, we begin at the end of the tree and work backward. For each chance node, we calculate the expected monetary value (EMV), and place it in the node to indicate that it is the expected value calculated over all branches emanating from that node. For each decision node, we select the one with the highest EMV (or minimum cost). Then those decision alternatives not selected are eliminated from further consideration. Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Making Sequential Investment Decisions $60 High (0.5) $20 Set High Price $44 Market $44 (0.5) -$20 Low Competitive $20 Product (0.7) $40 High (0.2) Low $16 No Competitive Product (0.3) Do not market Low (0.8) $10 Set High Price $100 $100 Low $0 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 $30 Decision Rules Market the new product. Whether or not you encounter a competitive product, raise your price. The expected monetary value associated with marketing the new product is $44. Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Practice Problem A company is considering the purchase of a new labor- saving machine. The machine’s cost will turn out to be $55 per day. Each hour of labor that is saved reduces costs by $5. However, there is some uncertainty over the number of hours that actually will be saved. It is judged that the hours of labor saved per day will be 10, 11, or 12, with probabilities of 0.10, 0.60, 0.30, respectively. Let us define “profit” as the excess of labor-cost savings over the machine cost. Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Construct a Decision Tree -$5 0.10 $2.5 $2.5 Invest 10 11 0.60 0 12 Do not invest 0.30 $10 0 EMV = $2.5 Decision: Purchase the equipment Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI) What is EVPI? This is equivalent to asking yourself how much you can improve your decision if you had perfect information. Mathematical Relationship: EVPI = EPPI – EMV = EOL where EPPI (Expected profit with perfect information) is the expected profit you could obtain if you had perfect information, and EMV (Expected monetary value) is the expected profit you could obtain based on your own judgment. This is equivalent to expected opportunity loss (EOL). Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI) State of Nature 10 11 12 Best Strategy Don’t Buy Indifferent Buy Maximum Payoff Probability the State of Nature Occurs Expected Payoff or each State 0 0 10 0.10 0.60 0.30 0 0 3 Expected Profit with Perfect Information (EPPI): (0.10)(0) + (0.60)(0) + (0.30(10) = $3 Expected Value of Perfect Information (EVPI) = EPPI – EMV $3 - $2.5 = $0.5 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Bill’s Decision Problem – $50,000 to Invest Decision Problem: Buying a highly speculative stock (d1) with three potential levels of return – High (50%), Medium (9%), and Low (30%). Buying a very safe U.S. Treasury bond (d2) with a guaranteed 7.5% return. Seek advice from an expert? Seek professional advice before making the decision Do not seek professional advice – do on his own. Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Decision Tree for Bill’s Investment Problem - Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Expected Value of Perfect Information Decision Option Potential Return Level Probability Option1: Invest in Stock (Prior Optimal) Option 2: Invest in Bonds Optimal Choice with Perfect Information Opportunity Loss Associated with Investing in Bonds High (A) 0.25 $16,510 $898 Stock $15,612 Medium (B) 0.40 890 898 Bond 0 Low(C) 0.35 -13,967 898 Bond 0 -$405 $898 EMV EPPI = (0.25)($16,510) + (0.40)($898) + (0.35)($898) = $4,801 EVPI = EPPI – EV = $4,801 - $898 = $3,903 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 $3,903 EOL = (0.25)($15,612) + (0.40)(0) + (0.35)(0) = $3,903 Bill’s Investment Problem with an Option of Getting Professional Advice Updating Conditional Profit (or Loss) after Paying a Fee to the Expert (Fee = $200) Revised Decision Tree Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Conditional Probabilities of the Expert’s Prediction, Given a Potential Return on the Stock Given Level of Stock Performance What the Report Will Say High (A) Medium (B) Low (C) Favorable (F) 0.80 0.65 0.20 Unfavorable (UF) 0.20 0.35 0.80 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Nature’s Tree: Conditional Probabilities and Joint Probabilities Nature’s Tree Joint & Marginal Probabilities P(A,F) = P(F|A)P(A) = (0.80)(0.25) = 0.20 P(A,UF|A)P(A) = (0.20)(0.25) = 0.05 P(B,F) = P(F|B)P(B) = (0.65)(0.40) = 0.26 P(B,UF) = P(UF|B)P(B) = (0.35)(0.40) = 0.14 P(F) = 0.20 + 0.26 + 0.07 = 0.53 P(UF) = 1 – P(F) = 1 – 0.53 = 0.47 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Joint and Marginal Probabilities What the Report Will Say Joint Probabilities When Potential Level of Return is Given Favorable (F) Unfavorable (UF) Marginal Probabilities of Return Level High (A) 0.20 0.05 0.25 Medium (B) 0.26 0.14 0.40 Low (C) 0.07 0.28 0.35 Marginal Probabilities 0.53 0.47 1.00 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Determining Revised Probabilities P(A|F) = P(A,F)/P(F) = 0.20/0.53 = 0.38 P(B|F) = P(B,F)/P(F) = 0.26/0.53 = 0.49 P(C|F) = P(C,F)/P(F) = 0.07/0.53 = 0.13 P(A|UF) = P(A,UF)/P(UF) = 0.05/0.47 = 0.30 P(B|UF) + P(B,UF)/P(UF) = 0.14/0.47 = 0.30 P(C|UF) = P(C,UF)/P(UF) = 0.28/0.47 = 0.59 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Decision Making after Having Imperfect Information Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010 Contemporary Engineering Economics, 5th edition, © 2010