Chapter 17 Monopoly McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved. Main Topics Market power Monopoly pricing Welfare effects of monopoly pricing Distinguishing monopoly from perfect competition Nonprice effects of monopoly Monopsony Regulation of monopolies 17-2 Market Power In many situations, competition is not intense A firm has market power when it can profitably charge a price that is above its marginal cost Most firms have some market power, though it may be very slight Depends on whether their competitors’ products are close substitutes Two market structures in which firms have market power: A monopoly market has a single seller An oligopoly market has a few, but not many, producers Determining what is and is not a monopoly market can be trickier than simple definitions might suggest 17-3 How Do Firms Become Monopolists? Firms get to be monopolists in various ways: Government grants a monopoly position to a firm (cable TV companies in local communities, drug patents) Economies of scale (concrete supply in a small town) Being first to produce a new product (iPod) Owning all of an essential input (De Beers diamond producer) Many of these ways of initially capturing market power tend to erode over time 17-4 Figure 17.1: Scale Economies and Monopoly Monopolist can make a profit because AC lies below the demand curve at some quantities Two firms cannot make positive profits AC lies above Dhalf for all quantities 17-5 Monopoly Pricing Monopolist will choose the price that maximizes its profit, given the demand for its product Whenever the firm’s profit-maximizing sales quantity is positive, marginal revenue equals marginal cost at that sales quantity Marginal cost curve applies as usual Need to examine the shape of the marginal revenue curve Recall that a firm’s marginal revenue curve captures the additional revenue it gets from the marginal units it sells, measured on a per-unit basis 17-6 Marginal Revenue for a Monopolist An increase in sales quantity (DQ) changes revenue in two ways Firm sells DQ additional units of output, each at a price of P(Q), the output expansion effect Firm also has to lower price as dictated by the demand curve; reduces revenue earned from the original (Q-DQ) units of output, the price reduction effect The overall effect on marginal revenue is: DP Q MR PQ DQ So the price reduction effect makes the monopolist’s marginal revenue less than price 17-7 Figure 17.2: Marginal Revenue and Price 17-8 Sample Problem 1 (17.2): Suppose that Noah and Naomi have a monopoly in the garden bench market. Their weekly demand is D(P) = 500 – 4P. What is their marginal revenue when they sell 100 garden benches a week? Graph their inverse demand and marginal revenue curves. Monopoly Profit Maximization When a monopolist maximizes its profit by selling a positive amount, its marginal revenue must equal its marginal cost at that quantity If marginal revenue exceeded marginal cost the firm would be better off selling more If marginal revenue were less than marginal cost the firm would be better off selling less Two-step procedure for finding the profit-maximizing sales quantity Step 1: Quantity Rule Identify positive sales quantities at which MR=MC If more than one, find one with highest profit Step 2: Shut-Down Rule Check whether the quantity from Step 1 yields higher profit than shutting down 17-10 Figure 17.4: Monopoly Profit Maximization 17-11 Markup A monopolist facing a downward sloping demand curve will set its price above marginal cost Firm in a perfectly competitive market sets price equal to marginal cost, meaning that the firm has no market power Extent to which price exceeds marginal cost is a measure of monopolist’s market power A firm’s markup, price-cost margin, or Lerner index equals the difference between its price and its marginal cost, as a percentage of its price P MC 1 d P E 17-12 Markup A monopolist’s markup at its profit-maximizing price always equals the reciprocal of the elasticity of demand, times negative one The less elastic the demand curve, the greater the firm’s markup over its marginal cost When demand is less elastic, raising the price is more attractive because fewer sales are lost This also implies that demand must be elastic at the profit-maximizing price 17-13 Sample Problem 2 (17.4): Suppose KCC has faces an annual demand function Q = 16,000 – 200P, where P is the price, in dollars, of a cubic yard of concrete and Q is the number of cubic yards sold per year. Its marginal cost of $20 per cubic yard and an avoidable fixed cost of $100,000 per year. What is its profit-maximizing sales quantity and price? Welfare Effects of Monopoly Pricing By charging a price above marginal cost, the monopolist makes consumers worse off than under perfect competition Consumers who buy the product pay more for it Some who would have bought it under perfect competition will not buy it at the higher price Welfare effects of monopoly pricing: Firm gains Consumers lose Deadweight loss incurred Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing is the amount by which aggregate surplus falls short of its maximum possible level, which is attained in a competitive market 17-15 Figure 17.5: Welfare Effects of Monopoly Pricing 17-16 Distinguishing Monopoly from Perfect Competition Existence of more than one firm in a market does not guarantee perfect competition How can we tell whether multiple firms in a market are behaving like price takers or colluding and acting like a monopoly? Easy to answer if we could observe marginal costs and compare to price Monopolists and perfectly competitive industries behave differently in responses to changes in demand and changes in costs 17-17 Response to Changes in Demand Monopolist’s profit-maximizing price depends on elasticity of demand Price in perfectly competitive market depends on level of demand If elasticity of demand changes but level of demand does not, provides a way to distinguish between market structures Can investigate this through data collection over time and statistical analysis 17-18 Figure 17.7: Response to a Change in Demand 17-19 Response to Changes in Cost How do monopolies and perfectly competitive markets differ in their response to changes in costs? Consider the case of a marginal cost increase by a given amount at every level of output Example: a specific tax, T, on firms The pass-through rate is the increase in price that occurs in response to a small increase in marginal cost, measured per dollar of increase in marginal cost In a competitive market, the pass-through rate is never greater than one The monopolist’s pass-through rate depends on the shape of the demand curve Can be greater than one with a constant-elasticity demand curve 17-20 Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Product Quality Product quality is a decision firms make Raising a product’s quality increases the consumer’s willingness to pay Producing a higher-quality product usually costs more The firm must decide whether the extra benefit is worth the extra cost How does the quality provided by a monopolist compare to the level that would maximize aggregate surplus? If different consumers value quality differently, the monopolist may not choose to offer the quality that maximizes aggregate surplus May over- or under-produce quality 17-21 Product Quality: Car Wash Example Suppose the only car wash in town is deciding whether to provide hand washing Without hand washing the firm maximizes profit by selling 100 washes at $15 each, profit is $1,000 Hand washing costs $5 more per wash Consumers whose willingness to pay is above $22 value a car wash $15 more if done by hand All other consumers value a hand wash $5 more With hand washes, firm’s profit-maximizing quantity is 100 washes at $20 each, with profit of $1,000 Aggregate surplus: Without hand washes: $1,500 With hand washes: $1,800 Firm is indifferent between providing and not providing the higher quality product If cost of hand washing were $5.01, monopolist would choose not to provide it even though aggregate surplus would be greater with it 17-22 Figure 17.9: Monopolist and Product Quality 17-23 Sample Problem 3 (17.20): The only gas station in a small town sells both regular and premium gasoline. The weekly demand functions for the two gasolines are: QReg = 10,000 – 1,000PReg +50PPrem and QPrem = 350 + 50PReg – 100PPrem where the quantities are measured in gallons and prices in dollars per gallon. Are these products substitutes or complements? If the price of regular gas is $3.00 per gallon, its marginal cost is $2.95, and the marginal cost of premium is $3.05, what is the profit-maximizing price of premium gas? Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Advertising Spending on advertising is another important decision for many firms Because the monopolist’s marginal cost is less than the price, each additional sale increases its profit Firms in perfectly competitive markets have no individual incentive to advertise Each firm perceives itself as capable of selling as much as its desires at the market price Marginal benefit of advertising equals the increase in sales times the firm’s profit on additional sales At the profit-maximizing level of advertising, this marginal benefit must equal the extra dollar expended For a monopolist, the ratio of the amount spend on advertising to the firm’s total sales revenue, the advertising-sales ratio, equals the advertising elasticity divided by the elasticity of demand, times negative one 17-25 Nonprice Effects of Monopoly: Investments Firms can also make investments in an effort to become a monopolist Example: cable TV firms lobbying government officials to award them franchises If firms compete to become a monopolist, they will spend up to the full monopoly profit less avoidable fixed costs If spend on socially wasteful things (e.g., golf outings for local officials) the loss from monopoly may be larger than deadweight loss and include all monopoly profit Rent seeking is socially useless effort devoted to securing a monopoly position Welfare effects of monopoly need not always be so bad Expenditures firms make to gain monopoly positions can be socially valuable (e.g., R&D spending in the search for patentable drugs) 17-26 Monopsony Market power isn’t limited to the sellers of a product: it also can be held by buyers A monopsony market has a single buyer Analysis of monopsony parallels the analysis of monopoly A monopsonist faces an upward-sloping supply curve By lowering the quantity he buys, can pay less Monopsonist can think either in terms of what price to pay or in terms of how many units to employ 17-27 Marginal Expenditure A monopsonist’s marginal expenditure, ME, is the extra cost per marginal unit of an input Consider a small city in which the hospital is the only employer of nurses The hospital’s marginal expenditure has two parts The input expansion effect: the marginal nurse costs W Given the upward-sloping supply curve, the hospital must increase the wage by (DW/DQ) to hire another nurse Since the hospital must pay Q nurses this higher wage, the wage increase raises nursing costs by (DW/DQ) Q So ME is larger than W since the total effect is: ME W DW / DQQ 17-28 Monopsony Profit Maximization The monopsonist’s profit-maximizing choice equates its marginal benefit with its marginal cost Maximizes its profit by choosing the quantity at which its demand and ME curves cross Result is lower price and quantity than if the firm was a price taker Can solve for the equilibrium algebraically by setting marginal benefit equal to marginal expenditure and solving for quantity 17-29 Figure 17.10: Monopsony Profit-maximizing outcome: Occurs where marginal expenditure curve crosses the demand curve Firm hires 200 nurses Wage is $50,000 Deadweight loss is red-shaded area 17-30 Welfare Effects of Monopsony Pricing Like with monopoly, monopsony price setting creates deadweight loss Monopsonist uses too little of the input Potential net benefits from the input are lost Deadweight loss is created between the marginal benefit and market supply curves See the red-shaded region in Figure 17.10 Can compute the dollar value of the deadweight loss using algebra 17-31 Sample Problem 4 (17.15): The Happyland Hospital is a monopsonist employer of nurses in the small city of Happyland. The supply function of nurses is S(W) = 0.1W – 100, where W is the nurses’ weekly wage. What is the hospital’s marginal expenditure, ME? If the hospital’s marginal benefit is $2,000 per week no matter how many nurses it hires, what is the profitmaximizing number of nurses for the hospital to hire? What will the nurses’ wage be? What is the deadweight loss? Regulation of Monopolies Deadweight loss from monopoly pricing provides a justification for government intervention Government actions that keep prices closer to marginal cost can protect consumers and increase economic efficiency Intervention can take many forms Antitrust legislation (see Chapter 19) Direct regulation of prices Price regulation not common in U.S. today More prevalent in the past Still used for electricity, natural gas, local telephone service More common in some other countries 17-33 Why Are Some Monopolies Regulated? Regulation arises out of political pressure and economic concern about market dominance When governments create monopolies they may then regulate them to deal with the negative consequences May create a monopoly to ensure that goods are produced at least cost A market is a natural monopoly when a good is produced most economically through a single firm Average cost falls as quantity increases Second firm may enter but this would cause costs to rise Government can designate one firm to be the provider Institute price regulation to protect consumers 17-34 Figure 17.11: A Natural Monopoly 17-35 First-Best vs. Second-Best Price Regulation Under regulation, ideally prices will be set at the competitive price Price at which demand and supply curves intersect Aggregate surplus will be maximized First-best solution to problem of price regulation Two problems with achieving this lead to second-best regulation Regulator may not know the firm’s marginal costs First-best solution would cause the monopolist to lose money If P < AC Best the regulator can do is set a price that makes aggregate surplus as large as possible, allow the firm to break even Set P = AC 17-36