Chapter 5: Investment Decisions I. Introduction Hi, this is Luke Froeb of Vanderbilt University’s Owen School of Management. I am the author of Managerial Economics: A Problem Solving Approach, along with Brian McCann. This lecture is designed to supplement Chapter 5: Investment Decisions. (Pause to create separation.) II. Opening Anecdote: In the summer of 2007—before the credit bubble burst Bert Mathews thought about purchasing a 48-unit apartment building in downtown Nashville. At the time, the building was 95% occupied and generated $550,000 in annual profit. His investors were expecting a 15% return on their capital and the bank had offered to loan him 80% of the purchase price at an interest rate of 5.5%. Bert had to figure out if purchasing the building was a good idea. He did this by determining how much he could afford to pay, and still give his investors a decent rate of return. So, he computed his cost of capital as a weighted average of equity and debt << 0.2 x (15%) + 0.8 x (5.5%) = 7.4%. >> <<INSERT GRAPHIC OF EQUATION with WEIGHTED AVERAGE OF BANK RATE AND EQUITY RATE, SHOW VISUALLY WHERE THE WEIGHTS AND THE RATES COME FROM>> With a capital cost equal to 7.4%, Bert could afford to pay $7.4 million for the building. In other words, the profit earned by the apartment, $550,000, equals 7.4% of the $7.4 million purchase price. (Add a visual equation in the video: $550,000/$7.4 Million=7.4%) At this point, Mr. Mathews decided not to buy the building. In retrospect, the summer of 2007 was not a good time to invest in real estate. A year later, the building’s occupancy had fallen from 95% to 90% and annual profit fell from $550,000 to $500,000. It was also harder to get a loan. Now the bank was willing to loan him only 65% of the purchase price, and at a rate of 7.5%. This raised his cost of capital to 10.125% (show equation on screen as 0.35 x (15%) + 0.65 x (7.5%) = 10.125%) which meant he could only offer $4.5 million. The owners rejected his offer as too small. What does this story mean? Beyond the obvious effect of the interest rates on real estate prices, it also illustrates the relevant costs and benefits of investment decisions, the topic of chapter 5. III. How to determine whether investments are profitable Let’s start by trying to figure out which investments are profitable. At the most basic level, all investments offer a trade-off between current sacrifice and future gain. In economics, we use the term “discount rate” to describe the price at which you are willing to trade current for future dollars. If you require a high return to entice you to invest in a project, you have what we call a “high discount rate.“ You have encountered this tradeoff before: when you put money in a savings account, it grows at a compound rate of interest. If the interest rate is 10%, then one dollar invested today will be worth $1.10 after a year, worth $1.21 after two years, and worth $1.33 after three years, and so on. $1 (1.10)= $1.10 $1 (1 .10)3= $1.21 $1 (1 .10)3= $1.33 There is a useful rule of thumb here called the 10-7 rule. At a ten percent rate of interest, your money will double after seven years; and at a seven percent rate of interest, you money will double after ten years. Discounting is the opposite of compounding. If someone offers to pay you $1.10 after one year, the current or present value of that promise depends on your discount rate. If it is 10%, then $1.10 next year is worth $1 this year. Similarly, the present value of $1.21 after two years is $1, as is the present value of $1.33 after three years; and so on. $1 = $1.10/(1.10) $1 = $1.21/(1 + 0.10)2 $1 = $1.33/(1 + 0.10)3 Discounting payoffs that occur k periods in the future can be computed recursively, by discounting future payoffs one period at a time, until you get to the present. The formula which represents this discounting is simple, Present value=future value/(1+r)k To illustrate how we use discounting to determine whether a project will earn enough money to cover the cost of capital, let’s consider two projects, both of which require an initial investment of $100. Project 1 returns $115 at the end of the first year. Project 2 returns $60 at the end of the first year and $60 at the end of the second year. So which project should you invest in? Looking at total return—which is like looking at accounting profit instead of economic profit—you might be tempted to choose project 2. But this would be wrong. What you want to do is compute the present discounted value of each project. To do this we discount all future inflows and outflows to the present. This is the equivalent of expressing costs (which occur in the present) and benefits (which occur in the future) in equivalent units so we can compare them. Lets say that your cost of capital is 14%. We discount the future payouts at 14% to compare their value to the initial investment. This means that the inflow after year 1 must be divided by 1.14 and the inflow after year 2 must be divided by 1.14 squared. Applying this to both projects shows that only the first project earns a positive profit. INSERT THE TABLE FROM THE BOOK. {use some moving graphics to show the algebra} The NPV rule tells you whether an investment project will earn enough to cover the cost of capital. Projects with positive NPV create economic profit, which means they earn a return higher than the company’s cost of capital. The bottom line is that you should invest only in projects with a positive NPV. <<INSERT Graphic of NPV RULE from BOOK>> IV. Break-even analysis In your finance courses you will learn that NPV analysis is the “correct” way to evaluate investment decisions. But many managers use short cuts, like break-even analysis. In fact, in a recent study, over half of CFOs used payback periods as their decision tool. To evaluate the profitability of investments, CFOs calculate how many months it would take for an investment to break even, or payback the initial investment. Break-even analysis is easier to do than NPV analysis and it produces simple, intuitive answers. So here is how it works. When considering an investment, instead of asking whether it has a positive NPV, you instead ask “Can I sell enough to break even?” If you can sell more than the break even amount, then it’s a profitable investment. And if you can’t, it’s not. It’s that simple. How do we determine the break-even quantity? Well, first we have to distinguish between marginal costs which vary with quantity, and fixed costs, which don’t. The break even quantiy is the fixed cost divided by the contribution margin (price minus marginal cost). (Show Q = FC/(P-MC) in video.) If you sell the break-even quantity, your profit is exactly zero. But if you sell more, your earn money. <<GRAPHIC FOR THIS EXAMPLE?>> To see how this works, consider Nissan’s 2008 redesign of its Titan pickup truck. The Titan had only two years left on its eight-year product life cycle and Nissan had to decide whether to redesign it. Nissan managers used a rough break-even calculation to evaluate their investment alternatives. It would cost $400 million to design and build a new truck from the bottom up. At a 12% cost of capital, the investment would cost Nissan about $48 million per year. Since they earned only $1,500 per truck, they would have to sell at least 32,000 trucks each year to break even. However, with only a 3% share of a shrinking U.S. market, Nissan predicted they would sell only 12,000 Titan trucks each year, not enough to break even. Instead they decided to explore other options, like outsourcing a new truck from Chrysler. <<INSERT GRAPHIC OF SHILLER’e P/E ratio, below>> 50.00 Price/Earnings Ratio of U.S. Stocks, 1881-2010 (Using 10-Year, Inflation-Adjusted Earnings) 45.00 40.00 35.00 30.00 25.00 P/E 20.00 15.00 Average: 10.00 5.00 0.00 Year Data and concept: Prof. Robert J. Shiller, Yale University, http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/data.htm Graph: Shayne & Co., LLC. The graph shows the monthly value of the general U.S. stock market, as measured by the S&P 500 (and comparable You can also think of stock market valuations in break-even terms. If you purchase a stock for, say $30, and the stock earns, on average, $1.50/share, then it takes 20 years to pay back the initial investment. In the graph above, we see that the aggregate P/E ratio for the stock market was about 20 in June, 2010. This is above its historical average of about 16, so some “value investors” would currently consider the stock market over-valued. Note that smaller, private companies typically trade at much lower P/E ratio’s, around 6, for example. VI. Shutdown decisions and break-even prices When looking at shutdown decisions, we work with break-even prices rather than quantities. Let’s think about what happens when you shut down. You lose your revenue, but you get back your avoidable costs. If revenue is less than avoidable cost, or equivalently, if price is less than average avoidable cost, then shut down. The break-even price is the average avoidable cost <<graphic to illustrate shut down decision>>. The challenge of break-even analysis is deciding which costs are avoidable, and for that we use the Cost Taxonomy (show chart 5-1 from page 57 in video). You can see that in the short run, only marginal cost is avoidable. In the long run, fixed costs become avoidable. So let’s say fixed costs are $100, marginal costs are $5, and you’re producing 100 units per year. In the short run, the shutdown price is equal to the marginal cost, <<INSERT GRAPHIC SHOWING MC IS SHUT DOWN PRICE AT $5>>. In the long run, the shutdown includes average fixed cost and rises to $6. When does the transition between short run and long run occur? Think of the fixed costs as a one-year renewable lease. When the lease comes up for renewal, it is relevant to the shutdown decision because it is avoidable. But until the lease comes up for renewal—during the short run—it is unavoidable and should not be considered when deciding whether to shut down. VII. Sunk costs and post-investment hold-up Sunk costs are relevant only before you incur them. But after you incur them, they become irrelevant, and this can make you vulnerable to what economists call “postinvestment hold-up.” Consider the case of a magazine, National Geographic, trying to negotiate with a regional commercial printer to print its magazine. Using a network of regional printers saves the magazine shipping costs, but they must convince each printer to buy a $10 million printing press in order to produce a high-quality magazine. If the marginal cost of printing a single copy is $1 and the printer expects to print one million copies per year over a two-year period, the average cost of printing the magazine over two years is $6, computed as the average fixed cost of the investment, (graphic of $6= $10 million divided by 2 million copies, plus the marginal cost, which is $1 per copy). This is the break-even price for the printer and represents her bottom line in negotiations with the magazine. Before they are incurred, sunk costs are relevant to the negotiation. Once the printer purchases the press, however, the profit calculus changes—if the cost of the press is sunk. In this case, the magazine can hold up the printer by renegotiating terms of the deal. Since the cost of the press is unavoidable, the printer’s break-even price does not include it, and therefore it falls to the marginal cost of printing the magazine, which is $1. If the commercial printer anticipates hold-up, he will be reluctant to buy the printer without some assurance. Hold-up then becomes a problem not just for the printer, but for the magazine as well. There are several things the printer and magazine can do to consummate the transaction. One option is a long-term contract, but contracts are often difficult and costly to enforce. A better solution is to make the magazine purchase the press and lease it back to the printer. This circumvents the post-investment hold-up problem because the printer has incurred no sunk costs. This leads to another maxim: <<GRAPHIC OF MAXIM contracts should encourage both investment and trade>>. VIII. Solutions to the hold-up problem Anytime that one person makes a relationship-specific investment, meaning one that is sunk or lacks value outside a trading relationship, he can be held up by his trading partner. This gives parties incentives to take actions to reduce the risk of hold-up, like signing long term contracts, or merging together, sometimes called vertical integration. We are going to close the chapter by taking a contractual view of marriage. Marriages are vulnerable to hold up in much the same way that commercial relationships are. The stereotypical story is that a woman accuses a man of taking “the best years of her life,” and then trading her in for a younger model. If a woman anticipates hold up, then she will be reluctant to make long term investments, like children. And like any commerical contract, the marriage contract is designed to restore the incentives of parties to make relationship specific investments. When an economist and his fiancée were receiving pre-marital counseling from a priest, the priest asked the economist why he wanted to get married. The economist answered “Long-term contracts induce higher levels of relationshipspecific investment.” The priest looked as if he didn’t understand, so he added “you know, the kind of investments that differentiate a marriage from a series of meaningless spot-market transactions.” On their first anniversary, the economist’s wife gave him a card declaring that her “relationship-specific investment was covering her cost of capital.”