Short Selling and Earnings Management: A Controlled Experiment Vivian Fang, University of Minnesota Allen Huang, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology Jonathan Karpoff, University of Washington SEC, Division of Economic and Risk Analysis & U of Maryland, Center for Financial Policy May 1st, 2015 1 Motivation Does short selling (SS), or its prospect, constrain firms’ opportunistic reporting behavior? Short sellers can identify earnings manipulation and fraud • Dechow, Sloan, and Sweeney (1996), Christophe, Ferri, and Angel (2004), Efendi, Kinney, and Swanson (2005), Desai, Krishnamurthy, and Venkataraman (2006), and Karpoff and Lou (2010) Anecdotal evidence David Einhorn (Founder and president of Greenlight Capital) • “Fooling some of the people all of the time”: • Six-year fight with Allied Capital between 2002 and 2008 • In June 2007, the SEC found that Allied broke several securities laws relating to the accounting and valuation of illiquid securities. 2 Motivation (Cont’d) There exist various incentives for earnings management (EM) Compensation, insider trading, job security, operational flexibility, or control SS imposes one constraint on EM • By reducing benefits: SS increases price efficiency (e.g., Boehmer, Jones, and Zhang, 2013; Boehmer and Wu, 2013) • By increasing costs: SS tracks a firm’s discretionary accruals and detects EM (e.g., Cao et al., 2006; Karpoff and Lou, 2010; Hirshleifer, Teoh, and Yu, 2011) 3 MC2 MC1 MB1 MB2 L2 L1 EM Empirical Approach We exploit Regulation SHO’s 202 T pilot program Every third stock in the Russell 3000 index ranked by trading volume within each exchange was drawn and designated as a pilot stock. From May 2, 2005 - August 6, 2007 (as scheduled), pilot stocks were exempted from short-sale price tests. Tick test (for exchange-listed stocks): a short-sale can only occur at a price above the most recently traded price (plus tick) or at the most recently traded price if that price is an uptick from the last different price (zero-plus tick). Bid test (for Nasdaq NM stocks): a short sale can only occur at a price at least one penny above the bid price if the bid price is a downtick from the previous bid. 4 Empirical Approach (Cont’d) The pilot program facilitates a diff-in-diff (DiD) analysis Relevance: an economically meaningful decrease in pilot stocks’ SS costs (increase in SS prospect) relative to non-pilot stocks’ SEC (OEA, 2007): increase in short-sale trades and short sales-to-shares ratio for pilot stocks / Diether et al. (2009): more order-splitting for NYSE pilot stocks Strong public reaction: Repeal of price tests in July 2007 led to backlash from practitioners and politicians & Reversal of the policy in Feb 2010 drew sharp criticism from HFs and short sellers Exogeneity: the decrease in pilot stocks’ SS costs is exogenous Controlled experiment with random assignment of treatment and control group No evidence that the firms themselves lobbied for the pilot program The goal was to evaluate the impact of short-sale price tests on market quality 5 Data • Data Sources 2004 Russell 3000 index Pilot stocks are from SEC’s first pilot order Excluded are stocks that were not previously subject to price tests and stocks that went public or had spin-offs after April 30, 2004 Sorted by stock’s average daily dollar volume from June 2003 through May 2004 Every third stock (starting with the 2nd one) within each listing market are then picked Compustat Industrial Annual Files for EM and controls Excluded are financial and utilities firms • Sample 388 pilot and 709 non-pilot firms (balanced sample) over 2001-2003, 2005-2010 The results are similar using an unbalanced sample. 6 Balanced Sample Variable ASSET MB ASSETGR CAPEX R&D ROA CFO LEV CASH N 388 388 388 388 388 388 388 388 388 DIVIDENDS 388 7 Treatment Group Control Group (Pilot Firms) (Non-pilot Firms) Mean Median N Mean None is Significant. Median tWilcoxon statistic z-statistic 3,748.61 2.75 13.42 5.55 4.19 14.37 11.36 29.36 0.21 817.69 1.95 7.88 3.76 0.00 14.51 11.33 26.46 0.12 709 709 709 709 709 709 709 709 709 3,746.25 2.60 13.22 5.50 4.04 14.15 10.56 29.80 0.22 817.42 1.98 7.66 3.65 0.32 14.29 10.46 27.56 0.11 0.00 0.68 0.10 0.14 0.27 0.25 1.10 -0.25 -0.44 0.51 0.03 -0.30 0.91 -0.94 0.22 1.10 -0.24 -0.32 0.83 0.00 709 0.73 0.00 1.14 1.07 Pilot-related Variables • PILOT: dummy variable to indicate pilot firms • PRE: dummy variable to indicate whether FYE falls between January 1, 2001 and December 31, 2003 • DURING: dummy variable to indicate whether FYE falls between January 1, 2005 and December 31, 2007 • POST: dummy variable to indicate whether FYE falls between January 1, 2008 and December 31, 2010 8 EM Variables • Discretionary Accruals (Kothari, Leone, and Wasley, 2005) Discretionary accruals = Total accruals (Earnings – Cash Flows) – Fitted normal accruals (Performance matched benchmark within industry-year) • Likelihood of beating earnings targets (e.g., Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal, 2005; Bhojraj et al., 2009) BEAT_ALY = 1 if the reported EPS falls between the analyst consensus forecast and that plus 1ct in a quarter and 0 otherwise; BEAT_EPS = 1 if the reported EPS falls between prior year same quarter’s EPS and that plus 1ct in a quarter and 0 otherwise. 9 First Finding Univariate Plot First Finding: Pilot firms’ discretionary accruals (and likelihood of marginally beating earnings targets) decrease during the pilot program, and revert to preexperiment levels when the program ends. 0.002 0.000 -0.002 Pre-pilot During-pilot Post-Pilot -0.004 -0.006 -0.008 -0.010 -0.012 -0.014 -0.016 Discretionary Accruals of Pilot Firms Discretionary Accruals of Non-pilot Firms 10 First Finding Multivariate DiD Dependent Variables PILOT×DURING Discretionary accruals BEAT_ALY BEAT_EPS -0.010** -0.079** -0.074* (0.004) (0.040) (0.044) PILOT×POST 0.003 0.017 -0.003 (0.004) (0.043) (0.033) PILOT 0.000 0.022 0.045* (0.003) (0.029) (0.024) DURING -0.001 -0.219*** 0.089** (0.002) (0.050) (0.039) POST -0.001 -0.437*** -0.062* (0.005) (0.056) (0.032) Controls Yes Yes Yes # of obs. 9,873 28,341 59,589 Adjusted R2 0.40% 2.21% 0.64% Discretionary accruals is 1 percentage point lower for the treatment group than for the control group during the 3-year pilot period compared to the 3-year period pre-pilot. The likelihood of marginally beating analyst consensus (prior year same quarter’s EPS) is 1.8 (0.8) percentage points lower for the treatment group, 11.1% (14.2%) of the unconditional %. 11 First Finding Robustness Checks Results are robust to using alternative measures of EM Fraud-score of Dechow et al. (2011) Results are not explained by Growth / Investment We consider several ways to control for growth/investment Pilot firms’ investment levels do not follow the same pattern as discretionary accruals Equity Issuance We show similar results for firms not seeking to issue equity as for the overall sample Market attention We control for various proxies of market attention/investor awareness Reverting pattern is not consistent with a market attention story (Chen et al. 2004) 12 Second Finding Second Finding: For financial misconduct that occurred before the announcement of the pilot program, pilot firms are more likely to be caught after the pilot program starts than non-pilot firms. As we sequentially include frauds initiated after the pilot program begins, the unconditional likelihood of pilot firms getting caught converges monotonically toward that of non-pilot firms. Pr(Caught(t + n), Fraud(t)) = Pr(Fraud(t)) × Pr(Caught(t + n)|Fraud(t)) Pr(Caught(>May 2005), Fraud(<July 2004)) = Pr(Caught(>May 2005), Fraud(>July 2004)) Dependent Variables PILOT Controls Industry FE # of obs. Pseudo R2 13 (1) Pre-2004 fraud caught 0.202*** (0.061) Yes Yes 2,694 5.90% (2) Pre-2005 fraud caught 0.193*** (0.062) Yes Yes 2,697 5.92% (3) Pre-2006 fraud caught 0.185*** (0.070) Yes Yes 2,700 5.18% (4) Pre-2007 fraud caught 0.142* (0.076) Yes Yes 2,704 4.44% Third Finding Current return-future earnings test Third Finding: Pilot firms’ price efficiency increase during the pilot program. Annual buy-andDependent Variable Rt Aggregated earnings hold return X3t 0.270*** for the next 3 years; (0.027) Coefficient of current X3t×PILOT×DURING 0.158*** return on future (0.060) earnings (Lundholm X3t×PILOT -0.014 and Myers, 2002) X3t×DURING Xt-1 Xt R3t 14 INTERCEPT # of obs. Adjusted R2 (0.036) 0.037 (0.030) -0.676*** (0.054) 0.576*** (0.044) -0.125*** (0.007) 0.347*** (0.010) 13,844 10.90% Third Finding PEAD test Third Finding: Pilot firms’ price efficiency increase during the pilot program. Boehmer and Wu (2013) Post-earnings announcement drift, CAR (+2, +11) Treatment Control t-Statistics Group Group Control – Treatment Earnings surprise D1 (Most negative) -0.38% -1.26%*** 2.47** D2 -0.41%** -0.41%*** 0.01 D3 -0.38%** -0.57%*** 0.88 D4 0.00% -0.07% 0.35 D5 -0.22% -0.24%** 0.12 D6 -0.13% -0.16% 0.13 D7 0.10% -0.10% 0.95 D8 -0.02% -0.06% 0.16 D9 0.23% 0.36%** 0.45 D10 (Most positive) 0.97%*** 0.83%*** 0.43 • When investors fail to fully capitalize on earnings information, returns will drift in the same 15 direction as the earnings surprise (Ball and Brown, 1968; Bernard and Thomas, 1989, 1990). • Short selling facilitates the incorporation of negative information into stock prices. Conclusion and Contribution • Takeaway: An exogenous reduction in short selling costs leads to less EM, higher conditional probability of detection, and enhanced price efficiency. • Contribution: Literature on the real effects of trading in financial markets Bond, Edmans, and Goldstein (2012) for a survey Literature on the determinants of earnings management Dechow, Ge, and Schrand (2010) for a review Literature on short selling and price discovery Add to the policy debate on the costs and benefits of short selling Short selling, or its prospect, improves financial reporting quality even among firms that are not charged with financial reporting violations. 16