Balancing Democratic Politics and Free Market Economy Rahul Vyas* Nidhi Nalwaya** Classical Athenian democracy was based on the ideals of full political participation of all citizens, a strong sense of community and equality of all citizens under law. Modern democracy, on the other hand, relies on elected representatives and tends to draw a distinction between the public and private spheres, thereby somehow unraveling the bonds of community and fostering individualism. Democracy is not so much about electing people as having a process and a system of checks and balances that ensures that basic rights are protected. Samuel Huntington defines the twentieth-century political system as democratic to the extent that its most powerful collective decision makers are selected through fair, honest, and periodic elections in which candidates freely compete for votes and in which virtually all the adult population is eligible to vote. The Authors have endeavored to study the various studies undertaken in the realm of the complex relationship between Democracy and Free market Economy and have presented a qualitative research paper on the same. The basic tenets of democracy can be summarized in the points below: Equality (rights, treatment, respect). Freedom (from oppression, suppression, the arbitrary will of others). Power (having some, delegating it, making it accountable). Universality of citizenship for adults. Participation in public life (community responsibilities). A commitment to open discussion on matters of common concern. Taking decisions by means of votes and abiding by a majority result. Respecting the capacities and rights of the ordinary individual. Another classification is that democracies are countries in which there are institutional mechanisms, usually elections that allow the people to choose their leaders. Secondly prospective leaders must compete for public support and thirdly the power of the government is restrained by its accountability to the people. It is a historical fact that democracies tend to enjoy greater prosperity over long periods of time. As democracy spreads, more individuals are likely to enjoy greater economic benefits. North (1990) has pointed out, a society's institutional framework seems to play an instrumental role in the long-term performance of its economy Democracy does not necessarily usher in prosperity, although some observers claim that "a close correlation with prosperity" is one of the "overwhelming advantages" of democracy. Some functional democracies, including India, have been laggards economically at least until the last few years. Others are among the most affluent societies on earth. However it is a fact that in the long run democratic governance by and large brings prosperity to the population. As Mancur Olson points out: "It is no accident that the countries that have reached the highest level of economic performance across generations are all stable democracies, experience shows that relatively poor countries can grow extraordinarily rapidly when they have a strong dictator who happens to have unusually good economic policies, such growth lasts only for the ruling span of one or two dictators “ Authoritarian regimes often compile impressive short-run economic records. For several decades, the Soviet Union's annual growth in gross national product (GNP) exceeded that of the United States but as has been evident the autocratic countries rarely can sustain these rates of growth for long. The Soviet Union was unable to sustain its rapid growth; its economic failings ultimately caused the country to disintegrate in the throes of political and economic turmoil. Economist Jagdish Bhagwati argues that "no one can maintain these growth rates in the long term. Sooner or later China will have to rejoin the human race." There are two strong reasons for democracies to have an edge over autocratic or any other form of government, Democracies- are more likely to have market economies, and market economies tend to produce economic growth over the long run. Most of the world's leading economies thus tend to be market economies, including Japan, the United States, and the economies of Southeast Asia etc. Freedom House conducted a World Survey of Economic Freedom, which evaluated 80 countries that account for 90% of the world’s population and 99% of the world’s wealth on the basis of criteria such as the right to own property, operate a business, or belong to a trade union. It found that the countries rated free generated 81% of the world's output even though they had only 17% of the world's population. A second recent study confirms the connection between economic freedom and economic growth. The Heritage Foundation has constructed an Index of Economic Freedom that looks at 10 key areas: trade policy, taxation, government intervention, monetary policy, capital flows and foreign investment, banking policy, wage and price controls, property rights, regulation, and black market activity. It has found that countries classified as "free" had real per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) (expressed in terms of purchasing power parities) growth rates of 2.88%. In "mostly free" countries the rate was 0.97%, in "mostly not free" ones -0.32%, and in "repressed" countries -1.44%. Of course, some democracies do not adopt market economies and some autocracies do, but liberal democracies generally are more likely to pursue liberal economic policies. Another reason is that democracies that embrace liberal principles of government are likely to create a stable foundation for long-term economic growth. Individuals will only make long-term investments when they are confident that their investments will not be expropriated. These and other economic decisions require assurances that private property will be respected and that contracts will be enforced. A champion of Free Market system, Ex - Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan has argued that: "The guiding mechanism of a free market economy ... is a bill of rights, enforced by an impartial judiciary Last but not the least democratic governments are more likely to have the political legitimacy necessary to embark on difficult and painful economic reforms. This factor is particularly likely to be important in developing countries like India but it also appears to have played a role in the decisions some formerly communist countries like Russia have taken in recent years to pursue difficult economic reforms. Free market implies that all are free to buy and sell as they will. Even if the starting point were one of equal ownership of resources and income the outcome after a period would be one of inequality of ownership and income and an increasing tendency in this. Democracy on the other hand usually demands a sharing of resources on grounds other than income and the market. A true democracy constantly strives to subvert market choices or limit market operations so that circumstances of need arise less rarely. Friedman’s 1962 theory implies that Economic freedom is a necessary precondition for political freedom. But later statements by Friedman make the relationship more complex. Dawson (1998) notes that “In general, the relationship between economic freedom and political freedom is that initial growth in one tends to promote the other”. Friedman’s statement suggests that the direction of causation between economic freedom and political freedom is either unclear or he variables are interdependent Democratic institutions can foster growth in a variety of ways. Przeworski and Limongi (1993) hypothesise that democracy should positively influence economic growth through better protection of property rights, which promotes savings and investment. Rodrik's (1999) results indicate that participatory and democratic institutions cushion the impact of negative external shocks on economic growth. Svensson (1999) finds that the long-term impact of international aid on growth depends on the political and civil liberties in the host country. More specifically, aid tends to have a positive impact on growth only in countries with democratic governments. But Svensson (2000) and Knack (2001) also provide some evidence that higher aid levels erode institutional quality, as measured by indices of bureaucratic quality, corruption and the rule of law . Supporters of the free market argue that any such sharing is wrong because any interference would only make matters worse, and the less tactful that all have market choices and if people are in a position of need it is their own fault. An obvious democratic counter argument to this first argument is that for those in need it couldn't be worse. A view not usually shared by those not in any great need. Further, it can be argued that not all made any market choices at all, but are rather victims of the market - those without access to income or resources, those deprived of education, etc. Finally, and most shocking to those who worship the market, not all wish to play by the market's rules, that is, there are those who would prefer not to buy or sell themselves. In a democratic society it is possible to choose not to play by the rules of a free market? Robert Barro (1996) expands upon Lipset’s ideas on the relationship between economic growth and democracy. He concludes that economic growth is a critical intermediate step between economic freedom and political freedom. By controlling for all factors except for GDP, Barro demonstrates the weak direct effect of the attributes of free markets on democracy. In contrast,he determines the strong effect of improvements in the standard of living on democracy, particularly per capita GDP, infant mortality rate, and male and female primary school attainment. John Dawson (1996) claims to have conducted the very first empirical test of Friedman’s 1962 hypothesis of the relationship between economic freedom and political freedom. Dawson relies upon Friedman’s later remarks concerning the actual interrelationship of the two variables for his hypothesis, rather than Friedman’s original unidirectional relationship. The results of Dawson’s analysis support Friedman’s theory of the interrelationship between the two types of freedoms and do determine the absence of a single direction of causation. Despite the interrelationship, Dawson does conclude that increases in economic freedom show a greater effect on both economic growth and political freedom than do changes in political freedom on growth and economic freedom. Dawson’s results discount the intermediate role of economic growth for the two freedoms, thereby contradicting the aforementioned work of Barro.Farr, Lord, and Wolfenberger (1998), research similar ground as Dawson, with a stated purpose of distinguishing a direction of causation between economic freedom, economic growth and political freedom. Authors Gordillo and Alvarez Arce explored the causal links between economic growth and political and economic freedoms in a series of countries and concluded that with a model built from a panel with a small time dimension and using a corrected LSDV estimator, that countries primarily concerned with economic growth would apparently benefit from institutional reform in the form of market liberalization . The Europeans seem to have achieved a level of compromise. China has rolled back its previous controls over the market until it too is managing a compromise, though it may need more democracy to enable the market to be contained. Australia has recently survived a concerted effort to greatly extend the market. The U.S. is the most obvious example of where the market has contained democracy with seemingly disastrous consequences. As an argument it has been repeated that just as a pure democracy seems an impossible level of anarchy, so too a truly free market is impossible. This implies that despite the tensions inherent in the relationship, we must continue to try and balance democracy and market freedoms without mistaking the one for the other. Markets can function only within an institutional and legal framework that includes property rights, legal enforcement of contracts and other rules to govern business transactions. In the same vein , rigorously competitive elections are the bedrock of any functional democratic system but a winner-take-all attitude with the victor concentrating power is unsuited for democracy in the long term. Well-functioning democracies are rooted in complex constitutional and laws that separate the executive, legislative and judicial power at the same time protecting freedom of speech, assembly and peaceful dissent by those who lose elections. Regulatory institutions – like the Banking Ombudsman, SEBI, TRAI and bodies that oversee various other industries – play a fundamental role by maintaining a fine balance between the free markets and the actions of elected governments and legislatures. A relevant example is the Reserve Bank of India, perhaps the most important of these institutions, as it is responsibl e for designing and regulating the monetary policy . The policy and regulatory mistakes that contributed to the subprime mortgage crisis – and thus to the Global financial system’s meltdown and the continuing travails of the Eurozone have yet again made the issue of optimal economic regulation and its relation to democracy relevant and sparked a worldwide vociferous debate on the same . Taking a certain view some people believe that markets and private initiative require no significant regulation. The role of politics is to elect majorities that can abolish regulations and regulatory bodies. A segment of the popular discourse similarly opposes regulatory institutions, but for very different reasons. It is argued that politicians can regulate and supervise without intermediate bodies that have some degree of autonomy. To their minds, these bodies merely impede and constrain realization of the people’s will. Globalization and the increasing complexity of financial and other markets make it imperative that the domains of private activity, political decision-making and regulation be clarified. The challenge is even greater because some regulatory agencies must be multilateral, or at least intergovernmental, given the global nature of much economic activity. The difference and the distance between markets and politics must be clear – and, for the sake of both effectiveness and legitimacy, it must be based on rules that are well understood and mooted by popular support . The authors of the present paper have tried to the define the fine balance between continued economic growth being necessary for enhancing the prospects of the working class and the poor. Just pursuing capitalist growth substantially rejects the claim that caring about social justice requires aiming for distributive equality. The impact of political freedom on economic growth is much less clear in the existing literature. Based on the evidence presented in we can safely say that political freedom do not have to be postponed. Furthermore, the dynamic relationships estimated with the Kiviet method indicate that intensified democracy may result in faster growth and greater economic freedom. They also indicate that economic prosperity makes democratisation easier. Chong and Calderón (2000) show that improvements in the institutional framework have a positive influence on economic growth, especially in poor countries. After establishing and solving a full system of equations determining growth and the channel variables, Tavares and Wacziarg (2001) sustain that the overall impact of democracy on growth is moderately negative. In an article with a different approach, Minier (1998) studies the experience of countries in which the level of political freedom changes significantly. Countries that democratise seem to grow faster,while countries becoming less democratic grow more slowly than comparable nations Even if democracy and economic freedom were not mutually reinforcing, there are no economic grounds for postponing democratisation to give priority to market reforms. Capitalism has been a good servant . Yet while this has helped to reduce global poverty and expand education, it has come at a cost namely an alarming rise in the levels of public and private debt, excessive consumerism, and a huge population that has been reduced to Have Nots . Any system that prevents large numbers of people from fully participating or excludes them altogether will ultimately be rejected. Digitization and the Internet have given consumers enormous abilities to connect and aggregate their voices. Power is dispersed, but wealth is concentrated. Further development and population growth will put a lot more pressure on our planet. Capitalism needs to evolve, and that requires different types of Democratic leaders from what has been the case so far, Not necessarily better leaders, but leaders who are able to cope with today’s challenges. Most of the leadership skills—integrity, humility, intelligence, hard work are integral. . Governments with an evolutionary mind-set those regimes that seek to encourage and enhance rather than prescribe and provide handouts will and should use taxes( GST) and standards( Emission Norms for Pollution ) etc to facilitate the population and governance in broad directions without trying to force specific solutions. . The accurate way to do this would be to make those standards self-modifying and dynamic. The link between the free market and democracy has been a savior of many a nation . The delicate interplay between these two pillars of the modern society has created a nations that sprung into relative prosperity, freedom and wealth of opportunity as also put forth remarkably effective leaders who have traversed the worlds of government and finance created a just and compassionate democracy. References : Baumol, W. J., 2002. “The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism”. Princeton University Press. Behrman, J.R., Foster, A.D., Rosenzweig, M.R. and Vashishtha, P., 1999.Women's Schooling, Home Teaching, and Economic Growth. The Journal of Political Economy, 107, 4, pp. 682-714. Bliss, C. and Di Tella, R., 1997. Does Competition Kill Corruption? The Journal of Political Economy, 105, 5, pp. 1001-1023. Burkhart, R. E., and Lewis-Beck, M. S., 1994. Comparative Democracy: The Economic Development Thesis. American Political Science Review, 88, 4, pp. 90310. Carroll, C.D., Neil, D.N., 1994. Saving and growth: A reinterpretation.CarnegieRochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 40, 133-192. Chong A. and Calderón C., 2000. Causality and Feedback Between Institutional Measures and Economic Growth. Economics and Politics, 12, 1, pp. 69-81 de Haan, J. de and Siermann, C. L .J., 1996 . New Evidence on the Relationship Between Democracy and Economic Growth. Public Choice, 86, 1/2, pp. 175-98 de Vanssay, X., Spindler, Z.A., 1994. Freedom and growth: do constitutions matter? Public Choice 78, pp.359-372. Gwartney, James and Robert Lawson with Seth Norton. 2008. Economic Freedom of the World: 2008 Annual Report. Vancouver, BC: The Fraser Institute. Data retrieved from www.freetheworld.com Durham, B. J., 1999. Economic Growth and Political Regimes. Journal of Economic Growth, 4, pp. 81–111. Dutz, M. A. and Hayri, A., 2000. Does more intense competition lead to higher growth? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 2320. Feder, G., 1982. On exports and economic growth. Journal of Development Economics,12, pp.59-73. Fischer, S., 1993. The role of macroeconomic factors in economic growth.Journal of Monetary Economics 32, pp.485-512. Freedom House, 2001. “Freedom in the world: Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties”. Freedom House, Boston. Freeman, R., 2001. Institutional Differences and economic performance among OECD countries. Mimeo. Friedman, M., 1962. “Capitalism and Freedom”. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Gupta, D. K., Madhavan, M.C. and Blee, A., 1998. Democracy, Economic Growth, and Political Instability: An Integrated Perspective. Journal of Socio- Economics, 27, 5, pp. 587-612. Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Park, W., Skipton, C., 2001. “Economic Freedom in the World. Annual Report 2001”. Fraser Institute, Vancouver.