AAEC 2305 Shaikh M Rahman Lecture 1 Text: Principles of Economics, Chapter 1 Learning Objectives 1. Explain and apply the Scarcity Principle 2. Explain and apply the Cost-Benefit Principle 3. Discuss three important pitfalls that occur when applying the Cost-Benefit Principle inconsistently 4. Explain and apply the Incentive Principle The Scarcity Principle Economics: The study of how people make choices under scarcity and the results of these choices for society. The Scarcity Principle: People have unlimited wants and limited resources. Having more of one good means having less of another. Also called No Free-Lunch Principle The Cost-Benefit Principle • Take an action if and only if the extra benefits are at least as great as the extra costs • Costs and benefits are not just money Marginal Benefits Marginal Costs Cost-Benefit Principle - Examples You clip grocery coupons but Bill and Melinda Gates do not You speed on the way to work but not on the way to school At the ball park, you pay extra to buy a soda from the hawkers in the stands You skip your regular dental check-up Should there be 4 separate sections of AAEC 2305, with 50 students each? 6 Or should there be only one section, with 200 students? 7 Cost-Benefit Analysis Benefit: Students learn more effectively in smaller classes. Cost: But smaller classes are also more expensive. 8 Cost-Benefit Analysis Should I do activity x? C(x) = the costs of doing x B(x) = the benefits of doing x If B(x) > C(x), do x; otherwise don't 9 Example 1.1. Should I turn down my stereo? 10 You have settled into a comfortable chair and are listening to your stereo when you realize that the next two tracks on the album are ones you dislike. If you had a programmable disc player, you would have programmed them not to play. But you don't, and so you must decide whether to get up and turn the music down, or to stay put and wait it out. 11 Suppose C(x) = $1.00 = the minimum amount it would take to get you out of your chair. B(x) = the maximum you would be willing to pay someone to turn down the volume. If B(x) > $1, then turn your stereo down. If B(x) < $1, then don't. 12 The Cost-Benefit Principle An individual (or a firm, or a society) should take an action if, and only if, the extra (marginal) benefits from taking the action are at least as great as the extra (marginal) costs. 13 Critics of the cost-benefit approach often object that people don’t really calculate costs and benefits when deciding what to do. But, people often behave as if they were comparing the relevant costs and benefits. And, people often make bad decisions because they fail to compare the relevant costs and benefits. 14 Economic Models • Simplifying assumptions – Which aspects of the decision are absolutely essential? – Which aspects are irrelevant? • Abstract representation of key relationships – The Cost-Benefit Principle is a model • If costs of an action increase, the action is less likely • If benefits of an action increase, the action is more likely 15 Four Decision Pitfalls • Economic analysis predicts likely behavior • Four general cases of mistakes 1. Measuring costs and benefits as proportions instead of absolute amounts 2. Ignoring implicit costs 3. Failure to ignore sunk costs 4. Failure to think at the margin – failure to understand average-marginal distinction 16 Pitfall #1 Measuring costs and benefits as proportions instead of absolute amount • Would you walk to town to save $10 on a $100 item? • Would you walk to town to save $10 on a $1,000 item? Marginal Benefits Marginal Costs Action 17 Can cost-benefit analysis help you make better decisions? Example 1.2 You are about to buy a $20 alarm clock at the campus store when a friend tells you that Walmart has the same alarm clock on sale for $10. Do you drive down to Walmart? 18 Example 1.3. You are about to buy a $1,010 laptop computer from the campus store, when a friend tells you that Walmart has the same computer on sale for $1,000. Do you drive down to Walmart? 19 Should you drive down to Walmart? B(x) = benefit of driving down to Walmart = $10 in both cases C(x) = cost of driving down to Walmart = the same amount in both cases. So your answer should be the same in both cases. 20 Example 1.4. Choosing a public health program. A rare disease will claim 600 lives if we do nothing. We must choose between the following two programs: Program A: save 200 lives with certainty Program B: save 600 lives with probability 1/3, and save zero lives with probability 2/3 Which program would you choose? 21 Example 1.5. Same disease as in Example 1.4 Program C: 400 people will die with certainty Program D: 1/3 chance that no one will die, and 2/3 chance that all 600 will die Which program would you choose? 22 In Example 1.4, most people choose to save 200 lives with certainty (Program A). In Example 1.5, most people choose to save all 600 lives with prob. 1/3 (Program D). Yet the two pairs of programs are identical: A=C and B=D 23 If the list of alternatives among which we choose are the same in two cases, then the particular alternative we choose should also be the same in both cases. Yet people seem to prefer the safe alternative when the alternatives are framed as choices between different numbers of lives saved, and to prefer the risky alternative when the alternatives are framed as choices between different numbers of lives lost. 24 Example 1.6. Losing a $20 bill You have just arrived at the theater to buy your ticket and discover that you have lost a $20 bill from your wallet. Do you buy a ticket and see the play anyway? 25 Example 1.7. A lost theater ticket. You have just arrived at the theater and discover that you have lost the $20 ticket you purchased earlier that day. Do you buy another ticket and see the play anyway? 26 • In both cases, you are $20 poorer than before. • In both cases, the benefit of seeing the play, as measured by what you are willing to pay, may therefore be slightly smaller, but this benefit is the same in both cases. • In both cases, the additional cost you must incur to see the play is exactly $20. • Since the relevant costs and benefits are the same in both cases, your decision should also be the same. 27 Exercise: Cost-Benefit Principle • You have a travel coupon that can be used on either of two upcoming trips: • Save $90 on your $200 round-trip ticket to Chicago or • Save $100 on your $2000 round-trip ticket to Tokyo. • For which trip should you use the coupon? 28 Pitfall #2 Ignoring Implicit Costs • Consider your alternatives – The value of a frequent flyer coupon depends on its next best use • Expiration date • Do you have time for another trip • Cost of the next best trip Explicit Costs Opportunity Cost Implicit Costs 29 Pitfall #2 Ignoring Implicit Costs • Implicit Cost - If doing activity x means not being able to do activity y, then the value to you of doing y is an implicit cost of doing x. • Many people make bad decisions because they tend to ignore the value of such foregone opportunities. • Consider the questions – Should I do x? – Should I do x or y? • In the latter question, y is simply the most highly valued alternative to doing x. 30 Example 1.8. Should I go skiing today? 31 From experience you can confidently say that a day on the slopes is worth $50 to you. The charge for the day is $30 (which includes bus fare, lift ticket, and equipment). But this is not the only cost of going skiing. You must also take into account the value of the most attractive alternative you will forego by heading for the slopes. 32 Suppose that if you don't go skiing, you will work at your new job as a research assistant for one of your professors. The job pays $40 dollars per day, and you like it just well enough to have been willing to do it for free. "Should I go skiing or stay and work as a research assistant?" 33 C(x) = Cost of skiing plus value of forgone earnings = $30 + $40 = $70 B(x) = $50 < C(x) So don't go skiing. 34 Many jobs, of course, are not pleasant. 35 Example 1.9. Suppose instead that your job had been to scrape plates in the dining hall for the same pay, $40/day, and that the job was so unpleasant that you would be unwilling to do it for less than $25/day. Should you go skiing? There are two equivalent ways to look at this decision. 36 I. One of the benefits of going skiing is not having to scrape plates. B(x) = $25 + $50 = $75 C(x) is the same as before, namely the $30 ski charge plus the $40 opportunity cost of the lost earnings, or $70. So now B(x) > C(x), which means you should go skiing. 37 II. Alternatively, we could have viewed the unpleasantness of the plate-scraping job as an offset against its salary. By this approach, the opportunity cost of not working in the dining hall is only $40 - $25 = $15/day. Then C(x) = $30 + $15 = $45 < B(x) = $50, and again the conclusion is that you should go skiing. 38 It makes no difference which of these two ways you handle the valuation of the unpleasantness of scraping plates. It is critically important, however, that you do it either one way or the other. Don't count it twice! 39 Example 1.9 makes clear that there is a reciprocal relationship between costs and benefits. Not incurring a cost is the same as getting a benefit. By the same token, not getting a benefit is the same as incurring a cost. 40 Example 1.10. An African graduate student who recently got his degree was about to return to his home country. The trade regulations of his nation permitted people returning from abroad to bring back a new automobile without having to pay the normal 50 percent tariff. He had been planning to bring back a new $10,000 Chevrolet and sell it. 41 Since new cars normally face a 50 percent import tax, the car would sell at a dealership there for $15,000. The student thought he could easily sell it privately for $14,000, which would net him a $4000 profit. 42 Then the student's father-in-law asked him to bring him back a new $10,000 Chevrolet, and sent him a check for exactly that amount. What was the opportunity cost of agreeing to this request? 43 Example 1.11. Is it fair to charge interest when lending a friend some money? Suppose a friend lends you $10,000, and her primary concern in deciding whether to charge interest is to decide if it would be "fair" to do so. She could have put that same money in the bank, where it would have earned, say, 5 percent interest, or $500 each year. 44 If she charges you $500 interest for each year the loan is out, she is merely recovering the opportunity cost of her money. If she didn't charge you any interest, it would be the same as making you a gift of $500/yr. 45 If someone chooses not to give you a gift, is that unfair? If not, it makes no more sense to say that recovering the opportunity cost of lending someone money is unfair. 46 As simple as the opportunity cost concept is, it is one of the most important in microeconomics. The art in applying the concept correctly lies in being able to recognize the most valuable alternative that is sacrificed by the pursuit of a given activity. 47 Pitfall #3. Failure to ignore sunk costs • An implicit cost will often not seem like a relevant cost when in reality it is. • Another pitfall in decision making is that sometimes an expenditure will seem like a relevant cost when in reality it is not. • Such is often the case with sunk costs, costs that are beyond recovery at the moment a decision is made. • Unlike implicit costs, sunk costs should be ignored. 48 Example 1.12. Should I drive to Boston or take the bus? You are planning a 250 mile trip to Boston. Except for the cost, you are completely indifferent between driving and taking the bus. Bus fare is $100. You don't know how much it would cost to drive your car, so you call Hertz for an estimate. 49 Insurance Interest Fuel & oil Maintenance Total $1000 $2000 $1000 $1000 $5000 50 Suppose you calculate that these costs come to $5000/10,000 miles = $0.50/mile and use this figure to compute that the 250 mile trip will cost you $125 by car. And since this is more than the $100 bus fare, you decide to take the bus. If you decide in this fashion, you commit the error of not ignoring sunk costs. 51 Fuel & oil and maintenance costs come to $2000 for each 10,000 miles you drive, or $.20/mile. At $.20/mile, it costs you only $50 to drive to Boston. Since this is much less than the bus fare, you should drive. 52 Suppose you had been willing to pay $60 to avoid the hassle of driving. Then the real cost of driving would have been $110, not $50, and you should have taken the bus. 53 Example 1.13. How, if at all, would your answer to the question posed in Example 1.12 be different if the hassle of driving is $20 and if you average one $28 traffic ticket for every 200 miles you drive? Someone who gets a $28 traffic ticket every 200 miles driven will pay $35 in fines, on the average, for every 250 miles driven. Adding that figure to the $20 hassle cost of driving, then adding the $50 fuel, oil, and maintenance cost, we have $105. This is more than the $100 bus fare, which means taking the bus is best. 54 Example 1.14. The Pizza Experiment. A local pizza parlor offers an all-you-can-eat lunch for $3. You pay at the door, and then the waiter brings you as many slices of pizza as you like. The "waiter" selects half of the tables at random and gave everyone at those tables a $3 refund before taking orders. 55 The remaining half of his tables got no refund. If all diners were rational, what difference, if any, would you predict in the amounts of pizza eaten by these two groups? 56 "Should I eat another slice of pizza?" 57 For both groups, C(x) is exactly zero. Because the refund group was chosen at random, B(x) should be the same for each group, on the average. People from both groups should keep eating until B(x) falls to zero. 58 So the two groups should eat the same amount of pizza, on the average. The $3 admission fee is a sunk cost, and should have no influence on the amount of pizza one eats. In fact, however, the group that did not get the refund consumed substantially more pizza. 59 Pitfall # 4: Failure to understand the average-marginal distinction • Marginal cost is the increase in total cost from one additional unit of an activity – Average cost is total cost divided by the number of units • Marginal benefit is the increase in total benefit from one additional unit of an activity – Average benefit is total benefit divided by the number of units 60 Marginal Analysis: NASA Space Shuttle # of Launches Total Cost ($Bill.) Marginal Cost ($bill. 0 $0 1 $3 $3 2 $7 $4 3 $12 $5 4 $20 $8 5 $32 $12 If the marginal benefit is $6 billion per launch, how many launches should NASA make? 61 Example 1.15. How much memory should your computer have? Suppose that random access memory can be added to your computer at a cost of $15 per gigabyte. 62 How many megabytes of memory should you purchase? "Should I do X?" "How much X should I buy?" "Should I buy an additional unit of X?" 63 Buy an additional megabyte if the marginal benefit of RAM is at least as great as its marginal cost Marginal benefit = added benefit from having 1 more unit Marginal cost = added cost of having 1 more unit 64 65 66 Example 1.16. Where should you send your boats? 67 Suppose you own a fishing fleet consisting of a given number of boats, and can send your boats in whatever numbers you wish to either of two ends of an extremely wide lake, east or west. Under your current allocation of boats, the ones fishing at the east end return daily with 100 pounds of fish each, while those in the west return daily with 120 pounds each. The fish populations at each end of the lake are completely independent, and your current yields can be sustained indefinitely. Where should you send your boats? 68 Average Catch: West End: 120 lbs./boat East End: 100 lbs./boat True or False: If you shift some of your boats from the east end to the west end, you will catch more fish. 69 Example 1.17. Now suppose that you have 4 boats and the volume of catch decreases as more boats are fishing in the west end of the lake, while the volume of catch remains the same per boat in the east end. How many boats should you send to the east and west ends? No. of Boats East End (lbs. of fish) West End (lbs. of fish) Total Average Marginal Total Average Marginal 1 100 100 100 130 130 130 2 200 100 100 240 120 110 3 300 100 100 330 110 90 4 400 100 100 400 100 70 70 The general rule for allocating a resource efficiently across different production activities is: Allocate each unit of the resource to the production activity where its marginal benefit is highest. 71 For a resource that is perfectly divisible, and for activities for which the marginal product of the resource is not always higher in one than in the others, the rule is: Allocate the resource so that its marginal benefit is the same in every activity. 72 Incentive Principle Incentives are central to people's choices Benefits Actions are more likely to be taken if their benefits rise Costs Actions are less likely to be taken if their costs rise 73 Economics Is Choosing • Focus in this course is on a short list of powerful ideas – Explain many economic issues – Predict decisions made in a variety of circumstances • Core Principles are the foundation for solving economic problems 1-74 74 Microeconomics and Macroeconomics Microeconomics studies choice and its implications for price and quantity in individual markets Sugar Carpets House cleaning services Microeconomics considers topics such as Costs of production Demand for a product Exchange rates Macroeconomics studies the performance of national economies and the policies that governments use to try to improve that performance Inflation Unemployment Growth Macroeconomics considers Monetary policy Deficits Tax policy 1-75 75 Chapter 1 Appendix Working with Equations, Graphs, and Tables 76 Definitions • Equation: A mathematical expression that describes the relationship between two or more variables • Variables: A quantity that is free to take a range of different values. – Dependent variable: a variable in an equation whose value is determined by the value taken by other variables in the equation – Independent variable: a variable in an equation whose value determines the value taken by another variable in the equation • Parameter (constant): A quantity that is fixed in value 77 From Words to an Equation • Identify the variables • Calculate the parameters – Slope: In a straight line, the ratio of the vertical distance the straight line travels between any two points to the corresponding horizontal distance. – Intercept: In a straight line, the value taken by the dependent variable when the independent variable equals to zero. • Write the equation • Example: Phone bill is $5 per month plus 10 cents per minute B = 5 + 0.10 T 78 From Equation to Graph – Equation: B = 5 + 0.10 T – Draw and label axes • Independent variable in the horizontal axis • Dependent variable in the vertical axis – To graph, B 12 • Plot the intercept C • Plot one other 8 A point 6 5 • Connect the points 10 30 D 70 T 79 From Graph to Equation – Identify variables • Independent • Dependent – Identify parameters • Intercept • Slope – Write the equation B = 4 + 0.2 T 80 Changes in the Intercept – An increase in the intercept shifts the curve up • Slope is unchanged • Caused by an increase in the monthly fee – A decrease in the intercept shifts the curve down • Slope is unchanged 81 Changes in the Slope – An increase in the slope makes the curve steeper • Intercept is unchanged • Caused by an increase in the per minute fee – A decrease in the slope makes the curve flatter • Intercept is unchanged 82 From Table to Graph Time (minutes/month) 10 20 30 40 Bill ($/month) $10.50 $11.00 $11.50 $12.00 – Identify variables • Independent • Dependent – Label axes – Plot points • Connect points 83 From Table to Equation Time (minutes/month) 10 20 30 40 Bill ($/month) $10.50 $11.00 $11.50 $12.00 – Identify independent and dependent variables – Calculate slope • Slope = (11.5 – 10.5) / (30 – 10) = 1/20 = 0.05 – Solve for intercept, F, using any point B = F + 0.05 T 12 = F + 0.05 (40) = f + 2 F = 12 – 2 = 10 B = 10 + 0.05 T 84 Simultaneous Equations • Two equations, two unknowns • Solving the equations gives the values of the variables where the two equations intersect – Value of the independent and dependent variables are the same in each equation • Example – Two billing plans for phone service • How many minutes make the two plans cost the same? 85 Simultaneous Equations • Plan 1 B = 10 + 0.04 T • Plan 2 B = 20 + 0.02 T – Plan 1 has higher per minute price while Plan 2 has a higher monthly fee • Find B and T for point A 86 Simultaneous Equations • Plan 1: B = 10 + 0.04 T • Plan 2: B = 20 + 0.02 T – Subtract Plan 2 equation from Plan 1 and solve for T B = 10 + 0.04 T – B = – 20 – 0.02 T 0 = – 10 + 0.02 T T = 500 Find B when T = 500 Use Plan 1 equation B = 10 + 0.04 T B = 10 + 0.04 (500) B = $30 OR Use Plan 2 equation B = 20 + 0.02 T B = 20 + 0.02 (500) B = $30 87