Economics 350 Environmental Economics EPA Water pollution Abatement costs Air pollution Solid municipal waste Hazardous wastes Global warming Endangered species Optimal pollution Cost-benefit analysis Tradable discharge permits Command and control Emission taxes Why do people behave in ways that harm the environment? Moral Approach Economic Approach Appeals to moral behavior Recognizes that people respond to incentives Households: “give a hoot, don’t pollute” Firms: emission standards Households: “pay as you throw” garbage systems Firms: CO2 taxes and tradable SO2 permits Economic Way of Thinking Rationality Scarcity Marginal analysis Equilibrium Positive vs. normative analysis Environmental Policy Objectives Environmental quality Sustainable development Biodiversity Types of Policies Command and Control Market Approaches Effectiveness Cost/Benefit Analysis Environmental Policy Politics Special interests Fairness issues Outlook Pessimists Thomas Malthus Bootleggers & Baptists ? Malthusian Model Population Food production Thomas Malthus time Environmental Policy Politics Special interests Fairness issues Outlook Pessimists Neo-Malthusians “Limits to Growth” Optimists “cornucopians” Technology and markets Julian Simon Economy and Environment Nature resources Natural Resource Economics Economy residuals Environmental Economics Economy and Environment: PPC Production Possibilities Curve Environmental Quality B ΔEQ A PPC PPC shows all combinations of two goods that can be produced from given resources and technology Illustrates tradeoff between the two goods Market Goods ΔG Note: Environmental degradation may shift PPC inward over time. Assume a concave production possibility curve. Suppose that society decides to increase the production of market goods by 10,000 units, and that as a result environmental quality falls by 10 units. If a further increase of 10,000 units of market goods is sought, we can expect that environmental quality will: fall by 10 units. fall by less than 10 units. fall by more than 10 units. increase by less than 10 units. d) a) 0% 1 2 3 4 5 0% 0% 0% d) c) c) b) b) a) Fundamental Balance Recycled: rRp Raw Materials M Residuals: Rp Discharged: dRp Producers Goods: G Consumers Residuals: Rc Discharged: dRc Recycled: rRc M = dRp + dRc M = G + Rp – (rRp + rRc) Fundamental Balance M = G + Rp – (rRp + rRc) 3 Ways of Reducing M Reduce G Reduce “consumerism” Zero population growth? Reduce Rp Reduce residual intensity of production Sectoral shift Increase (rRp + rRc) Mandatory content requirements Types of Pollutants Cumulative Noncumulative Local Regional Global Radioactive waste, plastics, many chemicals Noise Noise, visual SO2 CO2, CFCs Point Source Non-Point Source Smoke stacks, waste treatment plants Agricultural runoff Stationary Source Mobile Source Continuous Emissions Episodic Emissions Factories Cars, planes, boats Power plants, factories, waste treatment plants Oil and chemical spills US Pollution Control Expenditures: 2005 Abatement Expenditures (billions $) Capital Operating Total % of Total Air $3.88 $ 8.63 $12.51 47 Water $1.35 $ 6.73 $8.08 30 Solid Waste $0.68 $ 5.32 $6.00 23 Total $5.91 $20.68 $26.59 U.S. Census Bureau, Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures: 2005, MA200(05), U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, 2008. Online: http://www.census.gov/prod/2008pubs/ma200-05.pdf Review of Microeconomic Theory Rational man model An individual seeks to maximize his or her utility. Taking action until the marginal private cost of further action equals the marginal private benefit of that action. For social optimality the rule is: Taking action until the marginal social cost of further action equals the marginal social benefit of that action Market Model Price Supply P* Demand Q* What Q is produced? What Q should be produced? quantity Positive Normative Market Model: Demand Side Price Buyer’s Marginal Benefit or WTP $50 Market price $25 Consumer Surplus Total Expenditure 1 Demand 5 quantity Consumer Surplus = ∑(WTP – Price) Total Expenditure = P*Q Market Model: Supply Side Price Market price $25 Supply Producer Surplus Seller’s Marginal Cost $10 Total Cost 3 quantity Producer Surplus = ∑(Price – Marginal Cost) Market Model Price Deadweight Loss Supply CS P* PS Demand Q Q* quantity Free Market Outcome: P*, Q* Maximizes social welfare: SW = CS + PS Market Model Problem Set 1, #8 Problem Set 1, #9 __________________ Principle Equimarginal Total Costs of Production Output Plant A 0 20 5 15 1 25 13 22 2 37 30 32 3 50 60 47 4 80 105 77 5 115 155 117 Define: MC = Plant B Plant C ΔTC ΔQ Suppose you wanted to produce Q = 11. How would you allocate output among the three plants if you wanted to minimize the costs of production? Plant A: Q = 4 Plant B: Q = 3 Plant C: Q = 4 MC = $30 in all plants TC = 80 + 60 + 77 = $217 Allocate output such that MCA = MCB = MCC Market Failures Imperfect competition Imperfect information Externalities Public goods/Common Resources Externalities Occur when decision makers do not consider all costs (or benefits) of their actions Two views A. C. Pigou Ronald Coase Cashmere Externalities Externalities: Pigou Social Cost = Private Cost + External Cost Ssocial $ Free Market: P1, Q1 Optimal Outcome: P2, Q2 Sprivate P2 P1 Free market overproduces goods that generate a negative externality Marginal external cost D1 Q2 Q1 cashmere How can society achieve social optimum? Impose tax = marginal external cost Internalize the externality! M&M Experiment Public Goods & Common Resources Excludability: can you be excluded from consuming the good? Rivalry: does my consumption hinder your consumption? Rival in consumption Excludable Non-Excludable Private Goods Common Resources Non-rival in consumption Artificially Scarce Goods Public Goods Tragedy of the Commons Commonly-owned resources tend to be over-exploited Conflict between self-interest and the common good Examples Am I in danger of being overharvested? Garrett Hardin Sample Problems Problem Set 1: #20 (Externality) Problem Set 1: #18 (Public Goods) 140 ΣMB 120 $ 100 $ 80 MBH 60 MBA MB S MC 40 20 0 0 200 400 600 800 3)3 SO2/m SO2 (μg/m 1000 1200 Dirtier air Social Optimum occurs where ΣMB = MC 1400 1600 70 dH dA dS 60 50 40 30 20 D = Σd 10 0 0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500 Orange Juice 3000 3500 4000 4500 There are essentially three ways of reducing M (raw material usage) and, therefore, residuals discharged into the natural environment. These include all of the following except reducing G (output of goods) increasing Rp (production residuals) increasing rRp + rRc (recycled production and consumption residuals) all of the above. d) a) 0% 1 2 3 4 5 0% 0% 0% d) c) c) b) b) a) All of the following are examples of point-source pollutants except one. Which one is not an example of a point-source pollutant? municipal waste treatment plants agricultural chemical runoff electric power plants Eramet Metals manufacturing plant d) a) 0% 1 2 3 4 5 0% 0% 0% d) c) c) b) b) a) Public goods are distinguished by two primary characteristics. These are: market failure; high prices government intervention; high prices nonrivalry; nonexclusivity rivalry; exclusivity d) a) 0% 1 2 3 4 5 0% 0% 0% d) c) c) b) b) a) The efficient output will be less than the free market output when: Marginal social cost and marginal private cost are equal Marginal social cost is greater than marginal private cost Marginal social benefit and marginal private benefit are equal Marginal social benefit is greater than marginal private benefit d) a) 0% 1 2 3 4 5 0% 0% 0% d) c) c) b) b) a) The table below shows the marginal benefit from water quality for the only two citizens of a town. Water quality is a public good. If the marginal cost of water quality is $75 per quality unit, what is the efficient quantity of water quality? Fanting 1 2 3 4 5 6 a) b) c) d) e) f) 1 2 3 4 5 Gary Marginal benefit of water quality Water Quality Marginal benefit of water quality 80 1 100 70 2 85 60 3 60 45 4 35 25 5 15 0 6 0 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6