CHAPTER 20 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Prepared by: Fernando Quijano and Yvonn Quijano © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair • All economies, regardless of their size, depend to some extent on other economies and are affected by events outside their borders. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism International Trade © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 2 of 47 • The “internationalization” or “globalization” of the U.S. economy has occurred in the private and public sectors, in input and output markets, and in business firms and households. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism International Trade © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 3 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Trade Surpluses and Deficits • When a country exports more than it imports, it runs a trade surplus. • A trade deficit is the situation when a country imports more than it exports. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 4 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Trade Surpluses and Deficits U.S. Balance of Trade (Exports Minus Imports), 1929–2002 (Billions of Dollars) EXPORTS MINUS IMPORTS 1929 1933 1945 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 EXPORTS MINUS IMPORTS 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 + 0.4 + 0.1 – 0.9 + 0.4 + 2.4 + 3.9 + 1.2 + 13.6 – 2.3 – 23.7 – 26.1 – 24.0 – 14.9 – 15.0 – 20.5 – 51.7 – 102.0 – 114.2 – 131.9 – 142.3 – 106.3 – 80.7 – 71.4 – 20.7 – 27.9 – 60.5 – 87.1 – 84.3 – 89.0 – 89.3 – 151.7 – 249.9 – 365.5 – 348.9 – 423.6 Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 5 of 47 • Corn Laws were the tariffs, subsidies, and restrictions enacted by the British Parliament in the early nineteenth century to discourage imports and encourage exports of grain. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Economic Basis for Trade: Comparative Advantage © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 6 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: The Economic Basis for Trade: Comparative Advantage • David Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage, which he used to argue against the corn laws, states that specialization and free trade will benefit all trading partners (real wages will rise), even those that may be absolutely less efficient producers. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 7 of 47 • A country enjoys an absolute advantage over another country in the production of a product when it uses fewer resources to produce that product than the other country does. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Absolute Advantage versus Comparative Advantage © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 8 of 47 • A country enjoys a comparative advantage in the production of a good when that good can be produced at a lower cost in terms of other goods. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Absolute Advantage versus Comparative Advantage © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 9 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Mutual Absolute Advantage Yield Per Acre Of Wheat And Cotton Wheat Cotton NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA 6 bushels 2 bales 2 bushels 6 bales • New Zealand can produce three times the wheat that Australia can on one acre of land, and Australia can produce three times the cotton. • We say that the two countries have mutual absolute advantage. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 10 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Mutual Absolute Advantage • Suppose that each country divides its land to obtain equal units of cotton and wheat production as shown below: Total Production Of Wheat And Cotton Assuming No Trade, Mutual Absolute Advantage, And 100 Available Acres NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA Wheat 25 acres x 6 bushels/acre 150 bushels 75 acres x 2 bushels/acre 150 bushels Cotton 75 acres x 2 bales/acre 150 bales 25 acres x 6 bales/acre 150 bales © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 11 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Production Possibility Frontiers for Australia and New Zealand Before Trade © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 12 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Mutual Absolute Advantage • An agreement to trade 300 bushels of wheat for 300 bales of cotton would double both wheat and cotton consumption in both countries. Production and Consumption of Wheat and Cotton after Specialization PRODUCTION New Zealand Wheat Cotton Australia 100 acres x 6 bu/acre 600 bushels 0 acres 0 © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing 0 acres 0 100 acres x 6 bales/acre 600 bales Principles of Economics, 7/e CONSUMPTION New Zealand Australia 300 bushels 300 bushels 300 bales 300 bales Karl Case, Ray Fair 13 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Expanded Possibilities after Trade • Because both countries have an absolute advantage in the production of one product, specialization and trade will benefit both. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 14 of 47 • Even if a country had a considerable absolute advantage in the production of both goods, Ricardo would argue that specialization and trade are still mutually beneficial. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Comparative Advantage © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 15 of 47 • When countries specialize in producing the goods in which they have a comparative advantage, they maximize their combined output and allocate their resources more efficiently. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Comparative Advantage © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 16 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Comparative Advantage • Assume that people in each country want to consume equal amounts of cotton and wheat, and that each country is constrained by its domestic production possibilities curve, as follows: Yield Per Acre of Wheat and Cotton Wheat Cotton © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA 6 bushels 6 bales 1 bushel 3 bales Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 17 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Comparative Advantage Total Production of Wheat and Cotton Assuming No Trade and 100 Available Acres NEW ZEALAND AUSTRALIA Wheat 50 acres x 6 bushels/acre 300 bushels 75 acres x 1 bushels/acre 75 bushels Cotton 50 acres x 6 bales/acre 300 bales 25 acres x 3 bales/acre 75 bales • The gains from trade in this example can be demonstrated in three stages. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 18 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Realizing a Gain from Trade When One Country Has a Double Absolute Advantage Stage 1: Countries specialize STAGE 1 New Zealand Australia Wheat 50 acres x 6 bushels/acre 300 bushels 0 acres 0 Cotton 50 acres x 6 bales/acre 300 bales 100 acres x 3 bales/acre 300 bales • Australia transfers all its land into cotton production. New Zealand cannot completely specialize in wheat production because it needs 300 bales of cotton and will not be able to get enough cotton from Australia (if countries are to consume equal amounts of cotton and wheat). © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 19 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Realizing a Gain from Trade When One Country Has a Double Absolute Advantage Stage 2: STAGE 2 New Zealand Australia Wheat 75 acres x 6 bushels/acre 450 bushels 0 acres 0 Cotton 25 acres x 6 bales/acre 150 bales 100 acres x 3 bales/acre 300 bales • New Zealand transfers 25 acres out of cotton and into wheat. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 20 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Realizing a Gain from Trade When One Country Has a Double Absolute Advantage Stage 3: Countries trade STAGE 3 New Zealand Australia 100 bushels (trade) Wheat 350 bushels 100 bushels (after trade) 200 bales (trade) Cotton © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing 350 bales 100 bales (after trade) Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 21 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Gains from Comparative Advantage • The real cost of producing cotton is the wheat that must be sacrificed to produce it. • A country has a comparative advantage in cotton production if its opportunity cost, in terms of wheat, is lower than the other country. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 22 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Comparative Advantage Means Lower Opportunity Cost • Both Australia and New Zealand will gain when the terms of trade are set between 1:1 and 3:1, cotton to wheat. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 23 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Terms of Trade • The ratio at which a country can trade domestic products for imported products is the terms of trade. • The terms of trade determine how the gains from trade are distributed among trading partners. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 24 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Exchange Rates • When trade is free—unimpeded by government-instituted barriers— patterns of trade and trade flows result from the independent decisions of thousands of importers and exporters and millions of private households and firms. • To understand these patterns we must learn about exchange rates. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 25 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Exchange Rates • An exchange rate is the ratio at which two currencies are traded, or the price of one currency in terms of another. • For any pair of countries, there is a range of exchange rates that can lead automatically to both countries realizing the gains from specialization and comparative advantage. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 26 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Trade and Exchange Rates in a Two-Country/Two-Good World • Exchange rates determine the terms of trade. Domestic Prices of Timber (Per Foot) and Rolled Steel (Per Meter) in the United States and Brazil Timber Rolled steel UNITED STATES BRAZIL $1 $2 3 Reals 4 Reals • The option of buying at home or importing will depend on the exchange rate. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 27 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Trade and Exchange Rates in a Two-Country/Two-Good World Trade Flows Determined by Exchange Rates EXCHANGE RATE PRICE OF REAL $1 = 1 R $1 = 2 R $1 = 2.1 R $1.00 .50 .48 $1 = 2.9 R .34 Brazil imports timber; United States imports steel $1 = 3 R $1 = 4 R .33 .25 United States imports steel © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing RESULT Brazil imports timber and steel Brazil imports timber Brazil imports timber; United States imports steel United States imports timber and steel Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 28 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Exchange Rates and Comparative Advantage • If exchange rates end up in the right ranges, the free market will drive each country to shift resources into those sectors in which it enjoys a comparative advantage. • Only those products in which a country has a comparative advantage will be competitive in world markets. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 29 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: The Sources of Comparative Advantage • Factor endowments refer to the quantity and quality of labor, land, and natural resources of a country. • Factor endowments seem to explain a significant portion of actual world trade patterns. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 30 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem • The Heckscher-Ohlin theorem is a theory that explains the existence of a country’s comparative advantage by its factor endowments. • According to the theorem, a country has a comparative advantage in the production of a product if that country is relatively well endowed with inputs used intensively in the production of that product. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 31 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Other Explanations for Observed Trade Flows • Product differentiation is a natural response to diverse preferences within an economy, and across economies. • Some economists also distinguish between gains from acquired comparative advantage and gains from natural comparative advantages. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 32 of 47 • Economies of scale may be available when producing for a world market that would not be available when producing for a limited domestic market. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Other Explanations for Observed Trade Flows © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 33 of 47 • Protection is the practice of shielding a sector of the economy from foreign competition. • A tariff is a tax on imports. • A quota is a limit on the quantity of imports. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Trade Barriers: Tariffs, Export Subsidies, and Quotas © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 34 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: Trade Barriers: Tariffs, Export Subsidies, and Quotas • Export subsidies are government payments made to domestic firms to encourage exports. • Dumping refers to a firm or industry that sells products on the world market at prices below the cost of production. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 35 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism U.S. Trade Policies and GATT • The Smoot-Hawley tariff was the U.S. tariff law of the 1930s, which set the highest tariff in U.S. history (60 percent). It set off an international trade war and caused the decline in trade that is often considered a cause of the worldwide depression of the 1930s. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 36 of 47 • The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) is an international agreement singed by the United States and 22 other countries in 1947 to promote the liberalization of foreign trade. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism U.S. Trade Policies and GATT © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 37 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Economic Integration • Economic integration occurs when two or more nations join to form a free-trade zone. • The European Union (EU) and the North American Free-Trade Agreement NAFTA are examples of economic integration. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 38 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Economic Integration • The European Union (EU) is the European trading bloc composed of Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 39 of 47 • The U.S.-Canadian Free-Trade Agreement is an agreement in which the United States and Canada agreed to eliminate all barriers to trade between the two countries by 1988. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Economic Integration © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 40 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Economic Integration • The North American Free-Trade Agreement (NAFTA) is an agreement signed by the United States, Mexico, and Canada in which the three countries agreed to establish all of North America as a free-trade zone. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 41 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Case for Free Trade • The case for free trade is based on the theory of comparative advantage. When countries specialize and trade based on comparative advantage, consumers pay less and consume more, and resources are used more efficiently. • When tariffs and quotas are imposed, some of the gains from trade are lost. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 42 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Gains from Trade © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • When world price is $2, domestic quantity demanded rises, and quantity supplied falls. U.S. supply drops and resources are transferred to other sectors. Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 43 of 47 International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism C H A P T E R 20: The Losses from the Imposition of a Tariff • The loss of efficiency from a $1 tariff: 1. Consumers must pay a higher price for goods that could be produced at a lower cost. 2. Marginal producers are • Government revenue equals the shaded area. © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing drawn into textiles and away from other goods, resulting in inefficient domestic production. Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 44 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Case for Protection • Protection saves jobs • Some countries engage in unfair trade practices • Cheap foreign labor makes competition unfair • Protection safeguards national security • Protection discourages dependency • Protection safeguards infant industries © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 45 of 47 • An infant industry is a young industry that may need temporary protection from competition from the established industries of other countries to develop an acquired comparative advantage. C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism The Case for Protection © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Karl Case, Ray Fair 46 of 47 C H A P T E R 20: International Trade, Comparative Advantage, and Protectionism Review Terms and Concepts absolute advantage General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade comparative advantage (GATT) Corn Laws Heckscher-Ohlin dumping theorem economic integration infant industry European Union (EU) North American FreeTrade Agreement (NAFTA) exchange rate export subsidies protection factor endowments quota © 2004 Prentice Hall Business Publishing Principles of Economics, 7/e Smoot-Hawley tariff tariff terms of trade theory of comparative advantage trade deficit trade surplus U.S.-Canadian FreeTrade Agreement Karl Case, Ray Fair 47 of 47