The Case for Investment in Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy as a Means of Mitigating the Impacts of the Current Economic Recession Report Prepared for Energy Efficiency and Conservation Authority March 2009 "And we understand, roughly speaking, what technologies are needed. Some of them will be very quick—like insulating houses, promoting energy efficiency— and that will put unemployed construction workers back into work now, this year."1 Executive Summary The above quote by Sir Nicholas Stern neatly summarises this paper. We argue that investment in renewable energy and energy efficiency can make a very useful contribution to anti-recession economic policy. This is because the right kinds of investment help to maintain or stimulate aggregate demand in the short term, while still delivering net national economic benefits in the medium to long term. Quick action can also help to lower the high levels of uncertainty around job security and business profitability that permeate the early phase of a recession. With regard to the various initiatives that have already been proposed by EECA the following meet the criteria of good stimulatory policy: Energy Efficiency Clean Heat Commercial Buildings Crown Loans Energy Audits Energy-Wise Home Grants Residential Subsidies Renewable Energy Wood Energy Programme Renewable Electricity Transport Biofuels The employment effect of government funded or subsidised investment programmes during an economic recession is an important factor to weigh alongside the usual costs and benefits. High unemployment, low income, reduced effective demand and spare production capacity are the characteristics of an economy in recession. A key consideration of any programme should be the extent to which it utilises available skilled and unskilled labour. Many of EECA’s energy efficiency and renewable energy programmes meet this consideration. 1 Sir Nicholas Stern: http://www.mckinseyquarterly.com/Energy_Resources_Materials/Environment/Connecting_clim ate_change_and_economic_recovery_2303 1 Infometrics Executive Summary ................................................................................................... 1 1. Preface ................................................................................................................. 3 2. Recession Mitigation Policy Requirements ........................................................... 3 3. Infrastructure ........................................................................................................ 4 3.1 Scope .............................................................................................................. 4 3.2 Measuring Short Term Flow-on Effects............................................................ 5 3.3 Measuring Long Term Effects .......................................................................... 7 4. Energy Efficiency .................................................................................................. 8 4.1 Energy Efficiency and Recession Mitigation .................................................... 8 4.2 The Case for Energy Efficiency in the Longer Term ......................................... 9 4.3 Energy Efficiency and Aggregate Demand .................................................... 11 5. Renewable Energy ............................................................................................. 12 5.1 The Case for Renewable Energy in the Longer Term .................................... 12 5.2 Renewable Energy and Aggregate Demand .................................................. 14 6. Policy Design ...................................................................................................... 17 6.1 Criteria........................................................................................................... 17 6.2 Understanding Decision Making .................................................................... 18 6.3 Information .................................................................................................... 18 6.4 Externalities ................................................................................................... 19 6.4 Type of Intervention (energy efficiency) ......................................................... 20 Appendix A: New Zealand Wind Energy Projects .................................................... 23 Appendix B: Cogeneration in Forestry Processing ................................................... 24 2 Infometrics 1. Preface Indicators point to New Zealand, along with many other economies, being in recession. Like other governments, the New Zealand government is seeking ways in which the duration and impact of the recession can be minimised. There are many international and domestic factors behind the recession, and a range of macroeconomic and microeconomic interventions can relieve pressure on the economy. New Zealand’s response is broadly consistent with overseas developments. 2 Underlying this paper is the premise that the current recession has caused or will cause surplus capacity in various sectors and industries and an increase in the number of jobless people. In the long term the level of employment in an economy is not determined by how much investment occurs in renewable energy or energy efficiency, nor by how much is invested in roads, health or factories, or whether government raises welfare benefits. What is affected is the level of real wages and income per capita. Policies need to focus on improving productivity and increasing the capacity of the economy to produce the goods and services its people desire. In the short term, however, when there are unemployed resources, some policies will be better at increasing resource use and thereby pulling the economy out of recession than others. This paper aims to identify whether energy efficiency and renewable energy can contribute to the government’s recently announced economic stimulation package. 2. Recession Mitigation Policy Requirements What are the requirements for good stimulatory policies in the current economic environment? There are three: 1. Policies should maintain or increase aggregate demand in the short term. The recession can easily turn into a downward spiral. A lack of credit or poor balance sheet reduces demand for goods and services. Firms respond by curtailing production and laying off staff. Demand falls even more and so on. Stimulating aggregate demand is vital to preventing this downward spiral. Interventions need to have the highest possible upstream and downstream jobs and income creation effects. 2. Policies should be economically sensible over longer term, by addressing a market failure and delivering good (social) benefit-cost ratios so that government can repay its borrowing without raising tax rates. If policies also lower costs, including energy costs to businesses and households so much the better. 2 Suggested stimulatory measures include investment in transport infrastructure such as roads and railways, building more state housing, spending on health and education, tax reductions for families and/or businesses, higher welfare benefits, bailing out businesses at risk of collapse or retrenchment, lower interest rates, more guarantees to the financial sector, reduced working hours and raising barriers against imports. We do not evaluate these here. 3 Infometrics 3. Interventions should help to reduce uncertainty. This does not mean just lowering risk. It means reducing the fears of workers about whether or not they will have a job next week or about the prospects of finding a new job, and the fears of businesses about profitability and about whether they can obtain access to credit or uninterrupted input supplies, including energy supplies. Reducing uncertainty is largely about prompt and credible actions that address perceptions in the first phase of a potentially significant downturn. Announced investments in energy efficiency and renewable energy are key policies in this regard, particularly for those industries where energy is a significant share production costs – for example in pulp and paper, iron and steel, etc. Achieving a longer term dividend or economic growth requires the focus of policy to shift from government current spending to government investment, from focusing on spending control to investment optimisation and investment performance. The current situation does not justify a Keynesian spend-up. For instance with regard to state housing, building more state houses will certainly help to maintain aggregate demand and, given the surplus capacity that exists in the construction industry and in some parts of manufacturing, government would not be bidding up prices against itself. The long term benefits of better state housing are also notable; a healthier population, better performance at school, less domestic violence and so on. Arguably though, in the context of the criteria above, a quicker return could be obtained not so much from more state housing as from better housing of all kinds – state and private, regardless of tenure. What is a better house? It is drier and warmer (delivers more social or health benefits) than the typical old New Zealand house, and one that saves residents money without compromising their comfort. The question should be in which parts of the housing system can we have the best stimulatory effect for a given investment? As is no doubt evident this leads us to the foci of this paper – investment in energy efficiency and renewable energy. Energy efficiency and renewable energy can be attractive options for infrastructure investment that complements other fiscal responses to recession if they meet the short term, cost-effective, and risk mitigating criteria outlined above. Before pursuing that area though, we briefly return to topic of infrastructure. 3. Infrastructure 3.1 Scope The definition of infrastructure seems to widen each time it gets mentioned, but in economics it usually encompasses transport, energy, water, and telecommunications systems. Each of these areas, or at least specific subsets of these areas is an a priori candidate for an effective anti-recession measure. In a general sense water is probably the weakest candidate as it is not a desperate nation-wide issue. With telecommunications infrastructure being largely in the hands of the private sector, it is not immediately clear how government spending (or other intervention) in this industry could best be effected in the short term. Embedded privately owned networks are not ideal candidates for short term responses. At best, government can encourage the acceleration of planned upgrades. 4 Infometrics For energy transmission and distributions systems the prognosis is better – these are largely owned by central or local government. Economic upgrade opportunities are largely understood and existing plans for specific capacity upgrades exist. These plans can be accelerated. Roading (and possibly rail) and energy infrastructure are both nation-wide issues, have solid long term paybacks at the margin in terms of economic growth, and are amenable to relatively quick government action that boosts aggregate demand. Government can induce changes in the timing, nature, and scale of investment. Transport and energy are interlinked. The National Energy Efficiency and Conservation Strategy included a number of initiatives around transport such as improvements to traffic management and roading networks, and pricing fuels and networks to reflect all costs and externalities. The type of transport infrastructure that is desired depends partly on the modal mix, which in turn depends partly on relative energy prices and energy efficiencies, but also on demand side attributes. For example, an energy efficient transport system will include the following: Substitution from petrol and diesel towards hybrids and biofuels. Development of low energy intensity modes. Travel demand management. Substitution from petrol and diesel towards electric vehicles. Substitution from private transport to public transport, especially towards non-oil public transport. While the requirements for good stimulatory policies highlight short term results, if given a choice between investment options in alternative modes with similar short term returns and stimulatory benefits, we should prefer options that develop a long term infrastructure that will serve the economy better in terms of lower operating costs, improved service, greater fuel efficiency and so on. For example, insulating houses will reduce both health and energy costs in the future. 3.2 Measuring Short Term Flow-on Effects Table 1 shows the economic flow-on effects of three industries that have a major involvement in infrastructure investment. The effects are presented in the form of multipliers, an economic term used to emphasise the upstream and downstream impacts of an original intervention. For example, a $100m dollars of output from the Construction industry will generate another $174m of gross output. For every person it employs another 1.76 jobs are created elsewhere. How does this work? Conceptually a multiplier is a qualitative tool for providing information about the nature of the impact of an expenditure injection in an economy. The direct impact is enhanced or "multiplied" to the extent that an increase in production in one industry requires or is associated with increased production in other industries, and to the extent that industries supplying consumer goods and services increase their production in response to increased consumer demand. 5 Infometrics Table 1 Economic Activity Multipliers3 Gross output Value added Household income Employment Employment-output ratio (FTE/$m, 2005/06 prices) VA-output ratio Fabricated Metal Products Type I Type II 1.91 2.36 2.11 2.74 1.84 2.25 1.83 2.30 Machinery & Equipment Type I Type II 1.78 2.24 1.85 2.45 1.67 2.04 1.77 2.24 Construction Type I 2.29 2.71 2.65 2.30 5.1 5.2 5.2 0.35 0.38 0.29 Type II 2.74 3.47 3.24 2.76 That is, each dollar spent on the output of one industry leads to output increases in other industries. For example for The Construction industry needs to order materials such as timber and cement from suppliers. The supplying industries such as cement production require inputs themselves – such as energy, pay wages and salaries, and so on. The effect on these supplying industries is known as the upstream or indirect production effect and is commonly measured by a number called a Type I multiplier which is defined as the ratio of the direct plus indirect effects, to the direct effect. The supplying industries also pay wages and salaries, which are used to purchase household consumption goods. This effect is generally known as the downstream or induced consumption effect. Again the effect may be measured by a multiplier. The total or Type II multiplier is defined as the direct, plus indirect production, plus induced consumption effects, all divided by the direct effect. Multipliers are typically calculated for different measures of economic activity such as: gross output value-added household income employment However, multipliers need to be cautiously interpreted and carefully applied. When applied to gross output they can lead to double counting. For example the value of timber supplied to Construction is counted as part of the gross output of the Wood Processing industry and the Construction industry. If one’s aim is to measure overall business activity this double counting may be useful, but from the perspective of economic contribution it is value-added, or contribution to gross domestic product (GDP) which is of interest. There are also a number of implicit assumptions that need to be borne in mind while assessing the short-term flow-on effects of an initial investment or programme: 3 The consumption effect from the distribution of profits to households is ignored. Similarly for consumption financed from social welfare benefits. Average relationships are assumed to hold at the margin. Source: Butcher Partners. 6 Infometrics Prices are assumed fixed. If a factor is in limited supply producers may change inputs, thereby altering their production structure and hence the associated economic multipliers. The last two points are especially important in an economy where labour and capital utilisation is near 100%. In such a situation expansion of one industry stimulated by government policy merely pulls resources out of other productive uses, reducing total economic efficiency and can in fact be inflationary under normal circumstances. This, however, is not the case when the economy is in recession as there exists both involuntary unemployment and overall excess production capacity. Currently of course the New Zealand economy is in recession and is likely to experience relatively slow growth for the next 2-3 years4 - ceteris paribus. Nevertheless, we should not ignore one of the criteria for successful intervention mentioned above; namely that interventions should make good economic sense in the medium term. This criterion cannot be assessed with multipliers alone. Rather a multiindustry general equilibrium model is required, as outlined below. 3.3 Measuring Long Term Effects Long term cost and benefits are usually assessed in a standard partial equilibrium costbenefit analysis. This is fine if the benefits and costs are largely confined to the parties involved, but not if decisions have macroeconomic impacts. For example an individual’s decision not to purchase home insulation might be considered to be a strictly private decision, but if the decision is made in the context of energy prices that do not include a price on carbon, or if the health benefits that accrue from a warmer house are not fully captured by the individual, the national interest might not coincide with private interests. A general equilibrium model incorporates all of the key inter-dependencies in the economy, such as flows of goods from one industry to another, plus the passing on of higher input costs in one industry into prices and thence the costs of other industries. The ESSAM model used by Infometrics has the following key features: 53 industries Substitution between inputs into production - labour, capital, materials, energy. Substitution between 4 energy types: coal, oil, gas and electricity. Substitution between goods and services used by households. Social accounting matrix (SAM) for complete tracking of financial flows between households, government, business and the rest of the world. Further information is given in Infometrics et al (2007).5 The model’ strength is in understanding the effects of changes in allocative efficiency on the economy. Using the above example, this means that it can answer questions NZIER’s Consensus Forecasts March 2009 shows expected GDP growth of -0.9%, -0.6%, and 2.7% for the years ended March 2009 to March 2011. 4 5 Infometrics, EcoSense and Martin Jenkins (2007): Sustainable Homes National Value Case, report prepared for Beacon Pathway Ltd. 7 Infometrics such as: what is the gain to the nation from putting more resources into home insulation so as to lower the resources required in health care? 4. Energy Efficiency In this section we examine energy efficiency in the context of its power to stimulate aggregate demand in the short term, and its ability to provide a longer term economic payback. Multipliers (as described above) and general equilibrium modelling respectively constitute the assessment frameworks. 4.1 Energy Efficiency and Recession Mitigation It is important to have a clear understanding of energy efficiency. The popular definition that it is ‘energy savings’ does not adequately capture the benefits arising from interventions. Neither does the aggregate GDP/Energy intensity index, as structural and activity effects must be assessed and normalised to actually deduce energy efficiency. Energy efficiency investments improve both service benefits from energy using technology and reduce the derived demand for energy. The Energy Efficiency and Conservation Act 2000 recognises this is its definition of energy efficiency: “ ... a change to energy use that results in an increase in net benefits per unit of energy.” Economic recession does not mean the role of energy efficiency will diminish. Faced with rising energy prices, energy users look to more sustainable energy sources, not only to stabilize costs, but also to maintain a dependable supply of energy into the future. Most consumers will look for advice and assistance to help them reduce their energy costs. Sales of insulation materials, for example, have the potential to rise sharply as people try to cut their heating costs and reduce their carbon footprint. The Economist (31 May 2007) noted that house insulation improvements represent the lowest cost way, and can be a “negative cost” way, of achieving lower carbon emissions. An emphasis on energy efficiency notwithstanding, there is a case for re-aligning the EECA programme mix to meeting the recession’s immediate challenges. In general, most EECA programmes are known to have a number of flow-on effects on the economy. These programmes help create new jobs and income and develop technology. We address this below. Investment in energy efficiency is essential for a healthy and vibrant economy, and that investment will inevitably lead to an increase in demand for skilled workers in energy industries. It is one of the most important drivers of economic development in a modern economy. Uninterrupted energy provision services assume an even greater role in an economy caught up in economic recession. The USA will pursue a vigorous energy efficiency infrastructural programmes.6 In the past, due to its public good nature, energy-related services were mostly supplied by the state and the involvement of the private sector was limited. Since the 1990s, the industry has undergone substantial reforms and liberalisation in many countries, 6 President Obama's Speech to Congress, 4 February 2009. 8 Infometrics including New Zealand. As a result, the private sector’s role in the growth and development of this industry has increased. Privatisation has led to the emergence of global players in energy services, which has complicated the way in which the energy industry can help to pull the economy out of the current recession. 4.2 The Case for Energy Efficiency in the Longer Term In 2007/08, Infometrics undertook a major general equilibrium analysis for Beacon Pathway Ltd of various energy saving and water saving initiatives and policies. In the section below we draw heavily on this research in relation to energy efficiency.7 Table 2 summarises the results. Table 2 National Cases for Investment in Energy Efficiency National resource efficiency ratio Retrofit ceiling insulation Heat pumps Pellet burners Compact fluorescent lighting Hot water – heat pump Hot water – instant gas 1.1 1.5 1.2 ∞ 0.1 >10 Private IRR over 20 years 8.0% 20.6% 12.1% ∞ 6.3% 79.8% The ‘national resource use efficiency ratio’ measures the gain in real private consumption in a typical year after the investment has occurred and is delivering results, divided by the loss in private consumption that occurs (again in a typical year) from having more of the nation’s capital stock invested in housing. There is no discounting in this calculation. The general equilibrium modelling picks up direct costs and benefits as well as indirect costs and benefits. For example the effects that investment in energy efficiency might have on industry productivity and international competitiveness are picked up by the model. However, the modelling does not allow for the following: The effect of any improvements in the green image of New Zealand in export markets. The export of new technologies. Possible spillover effects of the creation of new skills and expertise. While these benefits are often claimed they are not easy to substantiate as the counterfactual is difficult to specify. For example if resources are invested in improving the performance of heat pumps, might fewer resources be allocated to biotechnology? We leave these issues on the table as their solution is too ambitious for this paper. Referring back to Table 2, initiatives such as Compact Fluorescent Lighting have a ratio of infinity as CFL bulbs involve no additional capital cost over an incandescent light bulb with the same light output, measured over a given number of light-hours. Effectively this means that CFL presents a “free lunch”. Note, however, that this is not an argument for taking incandescent bulbs off the market. There are situations where 7 Infometrics et al op cit. 9 Infometrics incandescent bulbs are preferable to CFL bulbs for other reasons, so making the former unavailable would reduce consumer utility. With regard to instant gas hot water systems the capital cost premium is low relative to a traditional electric cylinder system, whereas the benefits in terms of total energy savings are high, leading to a very high resource efficiency ratio. An analysis by CRA (2004)8, comes to a less rosy conclusion. The main reasons for this seem to be that that CRA analysis has a higher incremental appliance cost (perhaps because the figures are older), assumes that at the margin electricity is generated by renewables, and has a lower price on carbon. In addition the Infometrics analysis applies only to households who are already connected to and using gas, assumes that appliances are replaced only as they wear out, and does not allow for any increase in water use that might be prompted by instant gas systems. Further, in general equilibrium modelling, changes in producer surplus, which feature in the CRA analysis, are irrelevant to national welfare. Overall, a wide-spread shift to direct gas use may be of questionable national benefit, but this does not preclude many very good opportunities in particular circumstances. Heat pump hot water systems produce about the same level of savings to the consumer as instant gas systems. From the perspective of national resource efficiency, however, there is only a small gain to the replacement of traditional electric systems with heat pump hot water systems as they are much more expensive than standard electric systems. This outweighs their higher performance. More efficient space heating and retrofit insulation produce net long term benefits, though all rely on health benefits to deliver most of the gain rather than on reductions in energy use. To some extent these are mutually exclusive. Obtaining health benefits from better space heating usually means raising the average home temperatures and lowering humidity, particularly in older homes in the colder parts of New Zealand. Thus some ‘take-back’ in energy savings is almost unavoidable. Nevertheless, this does not undermine the case for retrofit insulation as consumers still benefit. It is just that the benefit is manifested in healthier people and more comfortable homes. And this is critical – this work is about increased end user service benefits and flow-on benefits in the economy, not just the direct energy saving. Other researchers who have looked at retrofit insulation estimate benefit-cost ratios of between 1.79 and 4.110, from direct energy cost savings and non-energy co-benefits in terms of health and welfare improvements. Having looked at longer term benefits, we now look at the role of energy efficiency in to recession proofing. 8 Charles River Associates (2004): Increasing the Direct Use of Natural Gas in New Zealand, report prepared for EECA. 9 Energy efficiency and Conservation Authority (2009): Draft: Home Energy Rating Scheme : Cost Benefit Analysis (Scenario 6). Chapman, R., P. Howden-Chapman & D. O’Dea (2005): A cost-benefit evaluation of housing insulation: results from the New Zealand Housing, Insulation and Health study, Wellington School of Medicine and Health Sciences, University of Otago. 10 10 Infometrics 4.3 Energy Efficiency and Aggregate Demand What are the employment and income generating effects of investment in energy efficiency in the long term? We can probably ignore CFL bulbs as the employment generated by manufacturing light bulbs is unlikely to differ substantially by type of bulb. Pursuing this argument, whatever employment is generated by the various measures listed in Table 2, most of it will come from installation of appliances and insulation rather than from manufacture of appliances. Most appliances are manufactured overseas, but a number of New Zealand companies manufacture insulation. In Infometrics et al (2007) it was estimated that retrofitting ceiling and floor insulation would cost about $2500 per dwelling. How large an effort could be mounted in a short time is difficult to say, but assuming 20,000 houses per annum are retrofitted, the value of investment would be $50m. From the data in Table 1 this would directly generate about 260 FTE jobs in Construction and related industries. The Type II multiplier raises the effect to around 630 jobs. The total value added generated would be around $50m. EECA has already investigated a number of initiatives in a standard cost-benefit analysis framework. These are summarised below along with our assessment of the extent of their ability to contribute to good stimulatory policy. To rate as ‘High’ initiatives need to have strong effects on aggregate demand and also a rating of 1.0 or more in Table 2. As is evident, all initiatives relating to insulation and space heating score highly. Table 3 EECA Energy Efficiency Initiatives Name Description Clean Heat Efficient space heating in homes Commercial Buildings Efficient space heating in buildings 3.6 Crown Loans Loans from govt for infrastructure efficiency upgrades Grants targeting high replication innovative technologies for specific energy intensive sectors like tourism and plastics industry? Grants to encourage industry to analyse their own energy saving opportunities 2.1 Energy Wise Home Grants - for insulation and clean heat Incentives to accelerate scrapping of old inefficient fridges Development of voluntary Home Energy Rating Scheme to provide robust info to homeowners /tenants on energy 1.4 EIB –Energy Intensive Business Energy Audits EWHG Fridge Retirement HERS 11 B/C ratio 2.3 3.4 5.7 1.7 2.1 Ranking as good anti-recession policy High; work for heater suppliers and installers. High; work for skilled auditors and technicians upgrading plant –similar to insulation case. High; work for skilled auditors and technicians upgrading plant –similar to insulation case. Medium; creates jobs for auditors and technicians upgrading plant –similar to insulation case. Grants may not be best mechanism. Medium-high; creates jobs for auditors and technicians upgrading plant –similar to insulation case. High for insulation; employs building trades . Medium; some demand for new fridges. Medium; stimulates demand for insulation. Infometrics Products Residential Subsidies VFEL characteristics of house Mandatory and voluntary Standards and labelling inform consumers and improve appliance and equipment efficiency Grants for interest component of insulation & clean heat for middle income households Vehicle Fuel Efficiency Labelling 4.2 Low; aligned standards keep poor quality products from undermining NZ industry. 2.0 High for insulation. 82.1 None. 5. Renewable Energy Renewable energy covers a wide range of energy types, but over the immediate future the emphasis is firmly on wind and geothermal generation for electricity. The single biggest current source of terrestrial renewable energy in the world is biomass, but its role in current energy use is small, albeit growing. In the short term the use of biomass for direct heat and cogeneration is likely to be greater than for liquid bio-fuels Solar power and tidal/wave power are not on the immediate horizon, and are certainly not prime candidates for government stimulatory policy in recession. 5.1 The Case for Renewable Energy in the Longer Term Over the longer term key points favouring renewable energy and particularly wind energy include.11 High levels of availability assist actual energy production and thus energy security, rather than just adding to installed capacity. Lower average electricity spot prices as always dispatched. Free input with no competing uses. No direct CO2 emissions. Short development time frame. More distributed generation. Scalable. The above points make a strong case for wind generation, and indeed are why many projects are in the pipeline. This very strength, however, makes wind energy (and other types of renewable energy) different from the energy efficiency initiatives discussed above, when viewed from the perspective of government action to stimulate the economy in the short term – a point to which we return below. Within the ambit of this project we have not been bale to undertake a thorough general equilibrium analysis of the long term benefits of more renewables-based electricity generation compared to a ‘business as usual’ scenario of more combined cycle gas (CCG) generation or perhaps more coal generation. 11 See New Zealand Wind Energy Association (2009): The Contribution of Wind Energy to Economic Growth and Security of New Zealand’s Electricity Supply. 12 Infometrics However, some general equilibrium modelling in connection with another project12 shows that substituting 70 PJ of CCG generation with renewables generation that is 25% more expensive per unit of energy (allowing for more expensive tidal, wave and solar power etc) over the next 50 years, produces a net gain in real private consumption of about 0.1%, with emissions falling by around 3%, relative to a baseline scenario. The assumed price of carbon was US$100/tonne. A lower carbon price would of course reduce the benefits of renewable energy. In a forthcoming report Scion, with general equilibrium analysis by Infometrics, looks at generating ethanol or biodiesel from purposely grown pine forest.13 The report shows that the long term case for biofuels from pine depends very much on the price of oil and the price of carbon, which are extremely uncertain. The following table summarises the results. Table 4 Change in Private Consumption from 0.8m ha of Forestry to Ethanol 1 2 3 4 Oil Price US$/bbl Carbon Price US$/tonne 200 100 300 200 100 100 100 150 Change in Private Consumption 0.16% 0.09% 0.22% 0.37% Change in CO2e Emissions -3.9% -4.2% -3.6% -4.1% The changes in private consumption are slightly higher than that mentioned above for renewables generation, but of the same order of magnitude. Similarly for the change in CO2 emissions. Solar photovoltaic systems are another type of renewable energy. They are expensive; around $12,000-$15,000 per kW, which is many times the cost of other forms of renewable electricity generation (see below). This means that solar photovoltaic systems also do not meet the second criterion for anti-recession policy, albeit that they may meet the first criterion. This is not to dismiss research in this area as worthless; that is a different issue. Many other biofuel technologies are being investigated in New Zealand, including producing biofuels from algae, whey, tallow, jatropha, canola, and waste oil. Unfortunately we do not know enough about the economics of these possibilities to evaluate them against the criteria of good stimulatory policy. None are currently on EECA’s list. There may also be strategic benefits to renewable energy such as being less reliant on imported energy. However, it is beyond the scope of this paper to compare the value of less exposure to supply disruptions and price volatility against the value of what in most cases will be more expensive energy. Similarly, for the conjecture that renewable energy may have the potential to become a key source for innovation, technology transfer overseas, and growth. 12 Infometrics (2009): Long Term Emission Scenarios for New Zealand, prepared for National Institute of Water and Atmospheric Research, forthcoming. 13 Scion (2009): Bioenergy Options for New Zealand: Analysis of large scale bioenergy from forestry, forthcoming. 13 Infometrics Overall then as a long term initiative, investment in renewable electricity generation is an efficient use of the nation’s resources, albeit that it does not deliver significant long term macroeconomic gains. Pine-based biofuels present a good case under the right conditions. We look now at the first criterion for stimulatory policy – the ability to raise or maintain aggregate demand and utilise idle economic resources in a recession. 5.2 Renewable Energy and Aggregate Demand Renewable energy provides a number of employment, economic, environmental and strategic benefits. Many current renewable energy projects in New Zealand are small scale and capable of producing immediate employment. Internationally, some studies claim that there are greater employment opportunities from renewable energy technologies than from fossil fuel supply options,14 but we cannot assess that here. In any case while this may be true in the short term, it is not necessarily advantageous to the economy in the long term. Maximising employment is not a route to economic prosperity. While unemployment indicates an inefficient use of the economy’s resources, it also inefficient to employ two people when the job can be done by one person. If maximising employment improved economic welfare, we could keep people employed by continually destroying our capital assets and rebuilding them. In the long term we should look to renewable energy that saves labour. In a similar vein the German Government's energy and climate programme sets ambitious goals for the further expansion of renewable energy in all uses – electricity, heat and fuels. Large employment gains are cited. See for example Kratzat et al (2008).15 Again though, while in a labour market with high unemployment net job creation may be possible, it will not happen or happen at high economic cost, if policies such as arbitrary renewable energy targets are not properly evaluated.16 Figure 1 shows the estimated supply curves of various electricity generation sources. The cost curve shows that, in the medium terms, renewable sources of electricity generation are cost competitive with fossil fuel-based sources, suggesting a limited role for government. We revisit this in Section 6. Appendix A lists a number of wind energy projects in New Zealand that are currently at various stages of planning and development. This demonstrates that there are many known viable wind energy projects, construction of which can help to maintain aggregate demand in the current recession. For example the Waitahora valley Wind Farm project in Manawatu promises to deliver a 101 jobs for each of the three years of the construction period. The concomitant increase in household income is $14m. 14 See for example Pollin, R., H. Garrett-Peltier, J. Heintz, & H. Scharber (2008): Green Recovery: A Programme to Create Good Jobs and Start Building a Low-Carbon Economy, Centre for American Progress. 15 Kratzat.M., D. Edler, M. Ottmuller & U. Lehr (2008): Short- and Long-term Impacts of the Expansion of Renewable Energy on the German Labour Market: Gross Employment 2007 – A first estimate. 16 Green interventions may be more economically efficient in developing countries with high unemployment. See for example UNEP/ILO/IOE/ITUC (2008): Green Jobs: Towards Decent Work in a Sustainable, Low-Carbon World. 14 Infometrics Overall, wind generation has strong employment and value-added creation effects. To reiterate though, our interest is primarily in short term effects. For them to materialise in this particular short term (namely 2009-2010) though, planned renewable energy developments need to be accelerated. We look at this in Section 6. None of the above is intended to imply a preference for wind over geothermal generation. The Te Mihi geothermal plant will lower electricity production costs by $60m over 25 years compared with alternative generation. Construction provides 400 jobs and injects $50m into local economy.17 Figure 1:Typical Costs for New Electricity Generation18 Biomass does not feature explicitly in Figure 1, but there are a number of cogeneration facilities in the forestry processing industry. A list is given in Appendix B, which shows that they could, in theory, be better utilised. However, increasing the use of cogeneration plant means that other energy plant would be used less – at least in the short term. Thus there are no immediate aggregate demand creation effects. Solar water heating (SWH) is another example of renewable energy. Between 12-25 FTE staff are required per 1000 installations to cover sales, administration and 17 Source: EECA. 18 MED (2007): New Zealand Energy Strategy to 2050, p38. 15 Infometrics installation of SWH systems.19 However, while there may be some aggregate demand effects from this activity, our research for Beacon Pathway Ltd indicated a low benefitcost ratio for solar water heating. Consequently we do not include it in our list of favoured initiatives for anti-recession policy. With respect to bio-fuels from pine forest, the Forestry and Logging industry has a direct labour requirement of 2.5 FTE per $1m of gross output (2005/06 prices).20 Scion’s lowest scenario envisages 0.8 million ha of forestry with an estimated output value of $2.05 billion (prior to conversion to bio-energy), implying direct employment creation of over 5000 jobs engaged in land clearance, tree planting and on-going silviculture. Even if forest intended for biofuels requires less silviculture than regular forest, the job creation effect is substantial. Analogous to Table 1, the Forestry industry has a Type II employment multiplier of 4.66, implying total job creation exceeding 23,000 FTE. In practice though, planting 0.8 million ha in one year is implausible and there may be regions where labour is scarce in spite of higher national unemployment. Planting 30,000 ha per annum is more plausible, implying job creation of around 900 FTE per annum. Thus even though the longer term case for pine-based biofuels is mildly positive, the short term benefits are clear. Given other benefits associated with forestry such as the prevention of erosion, and the option for at least some of it to be milled for timber and pulp, planting trees should be a key part of the package of stimulatory policies. As with energy efficiency, EECA has already investigated a number of initiatives in a standard cost-benefit analysis framework. Those pertaining to renewable energy are summarised below along with our assessment of the extent of their ability to contribute to good stimulatory policy. Wind, geothermal, and bio-energy (including bio-fuels for transport) rate highly. As noted previously, solar hot water heating does not meet the criteria, while the case for distributed generation has not been assessed in general equilibrium context. Table 5 EECA Renewable Energy Initiatives Name Description Distributed Generation Grants stimulate development of small/med scale local generation options Developing markets and infrastructure for commercial wood fuels industry Supporting wind farms & geothermal industry and proposals at consent poor B-C ratio Policy liaison with Med, MoT and industry Wood Energy Programme Renewable Electricity Solar Hot Water Transport Biofuels B/C ratio 1.4 ? Likely ranking as good anti recession policy Low; market failure unclear. Medium 1.7 High 1.0 ? None. Low; for policy liaison. High for forest establishment 19 McChesney, I. (2005): Solar Water Heating Installation: An Assessment of Current Status and Future Capacity. 20 Source: Butcher Partners 16 Infometrics Renewable energy is driven primarily by medium to long terms drivers. While construction of plant has a short term demand creation effect, this too is limited by the high import content, high capital intensity and requirement for more specialist skills when compared to energy efficiency initiatives like home retrofit insulation. 6. Policy Design The preceding sections demonstrate that certain energy efficiency and renewable energy initiatives satisfy the criteria of good stimulatory policy in an economic recession. A similar view is taken by Barbier (2009)21 who, along with advocating retrofit insulation and renewable energy (wind, solar and ‘next generation’ bio-fuels) also recommends improved mass transit systems for people and freight, and smarter electrical grids. How then should EECA design or prioritise its programmes to meet the challenge of mitigating the impacts of economic recession. How can EECA’s programmes be made more relevant so that they achieve not only their core objectives (over the medium to longer term but also create or sustain employment in the short term? 6.1 Criteria From the general case for stimulatory investment and policy direction presented in Section 2 we can define a set of criteria for assessing the capability of interventions to more effectively stimulate demand, and thereby jobs. Recession mitigation potential is maximised by interventions which: 1. Create quick employment or protect jobs, including the upstream and downstream flow-on effects. A subset of this criterion includes selecting programme areas that fit with available labour market characteristics such as existing skills availability and training options. 2. Quick returns and ready implementation. Whatever type of intervention is pursued for a stimulatory package, it is particularly important that policies can be rolled out quickly. 3. Create new economic and socially useful assets and durable goods and services, or significantly improve existing asset performance. 4. Do not self-offset their direct growth – that is develop new jobs rather than displace existing jobs. 5. Do not inflate wages or costs, by avoiding infrastructure systems that are already at capacity. 6. If possible, incentivise further investment, consumption and economic growth. Many of EECA’s energy efficiency and renewable energy programmes meet these criteria. 21 Barbier, E. (2009): A Global Green New Deal, report prepared for the Economics and Trade Branch, Division of Technology, Industry and economics, United Nations Environmental Programme. 17 Infometrics 6.2 Understanding Decision Making Notwithstanding the contribution that energy and renewable energy can make to antirecession policy, many energy efficiency initiatives (less so for renewable energy) deliver private benefits. Why is it then that they are often not pursued? Within the maxim of ‘free choice’ is there a role for government to assist private decision making in the national interest, and indeed in people’s own direct interests? For policy intervention to be successful it is important that one has a clear understanding of the nature of the problem. In this regard it is useful to consider direct and indirect impacts separately. Direct impacts occur when people’s decisions seem to be at odds with their own best interests (for example they use expensive and inefficient heating options, do not insulate their houses adequately, etc). Indirect impacts occur when the benefits or costs of the actions of individuals accrue to third parties or to society in general (for example the impact of smoke from open fires). When dealing with direct impacts, the key policy question is: what is preventing people from acting in their own best interests? Generally people are not irrational, though they may not seem to be practical. There may be disincentives or factors obstructing individuals from acting in what we think is their own best interests? Alternatively, we might be ignoring other factors that might be influencing their decisions? These could be less tangible factors such as time, convenience and comfort that could offset the adoption of more energy efficient appliances. For example, irrespective of cost, the inconvenience and disruption associated with house alterations will discourage the installation of retrofit insulation. Likewise there might be some unfavourable sideeffects associated with certain products: the noise of certain appliances such as pellet burners and heat pumps. Another major issue is the sunk cost of previous decisions and existing structures. Although there might be little difference in the price between more or less efficient appliances, the gains in efficiency are unlikely to be sufficient to encourage the early replacement of existing functioning appliances. 6.3 Information One key area where there is potential for genuine market failure is with respect to information. A cluttered information market can lead to poor choices that generate a long term cost to the nation. People may also make poor decisions due to a lack of awareness of the benefits of energy efficiency. The critical issue here, from a policy perspective, is what is preventing people accessing the relevant information? One would expect suppliers of genuinely beneficial products to be very willing to advertise the merits of such products. If information is a barrier, it has to be in cases where it is not in the interests of parties to provide full disclosure. An example might be house sales where it is not in the financial interest of the seller to be forthcoming about shortcomings associated with the house. To some extent the responsibilities of due diligence do lie with purchasers, but information about insulation quality, heating costs, etc are not necessarily readily available to purchasers. This is a situation where some form of information disclosure requirement (eg power bills) would improve purchase and renting decisions and provide house owners with the right incentives to invest adequately in maintaining/improving living conditions. With regard to the business sector the issue is not dissimilar. Is information clear and sufficient? Can a business be confident that an energy-saving investment will work in its own particular business circumstances? Credible sources of information from organisations such as EECA would help. 18 Infometrics Even with full information, some people may yet place a lower priority on energy efficiency than others. This might reflect preferences or income inadequacy. With regard to the latter, housing quality is a ‘normal’ good; people will tend to spend more on housing quality as incomes increase. The policy implication here is that measures that improve national wealth will typically, but not always have positive benefits on housing quality. In one sense this implies that housing quality will generally improve over time as national wealth improves. It also suggests that income support can act as a partial substitute for policies to improve home energy efficiency. 6.4 Externalities When individual preferences are at odds with social preferences, policy makers are interested in the externality imposed on society and what might be influencing the sum of individual behaviour to be at odds with social preferences. Retrofit insulation is an interesting example. With a warmer and drier home individuals benefit from feeling healthier, but the significant gains go to the government via lower health costs and to businesses that have lower overheads due to fewer days lost due to sickness. This seems to be a classic case where some policy intervention is warranted. Renewable energy presents a different intervention case to energy efficiency. While the government may own generation companies, it does not (usually) decide on what type of generation capacity is built and when, nor does it actively invest in bio-fuels, electric vehicles, solar power and so on. Many types of interventions have been proposed. Examples include mandatory renewables targets in electricity generation and liquid fuels supply, a ban on new thermal generation, feed-in tariffs, explicit subsidies for biofuels or solar energy, and modal share targets in transport. Such interventions have almost always been proposed without any analysis of the market failure or negative externality that is ostensibly being addressed, let alone what the optimal form of intervention might be. If the market failure is GHG emissions, then the onus should be on advocates of the above to demonstrate why a price on carbon is either inadequate or inefficient. If the issue is energy security, then the cost of volatile supply should be assessed against the cost of assisting particular types of energy that would not otherwise be viable. Nevertheless there is widespread agreement amongst economists that there are two key initiatives that government should implement to support renewable energy: Move quickly to put a price on carbon, including on thermal generation and oil products with no free allocation of emission rights or equivalent assistance. Quickly, because the recession is with us now, and without free allocation to ensure that generators are not in a position to cross-subsidise thermal generation. (As it stands the ETS does not provide free allocation to thermal generators, nor to oil companies, although the New Zealand Refining Company has a Negotiated Greenhouse Agreement relating to its own emissions). Ensure that consent processes are not unreasonably delayed. The latest changes to the RMA may well contribute to this goal. Ensure that local councils attach appropriate weight to the benefits of renewable energy (in particular national benefits) during resource consent proceedings. This issue is not likely to be directly addressed as part of the RMA reforms, but could be assisted through central government guidance. 19 Infometrics In the context of those two initiatives, the renewable energy area that has the greatest potential to boost aggregate demand and curtail rising unemployment is the development of wind generation and the planting of trees for eventual use for bioenergy, encompassing direct heat, cogeneration and transport bio-fuel applications. 6.4 Type of Intervention (energy efficiency) Who should intervene and how? Decisions on who intervenes are usually linked to the nature and level of the externality or spill-over involved. With regard to retrofit insulation for example, the benefit accrues largely at the national level via a reduction in the national health bill. This suggests that the intervention should be organised and funded at the national level, although implementation might be more efficient at the local level. A household suffering unemployment or other forms of reduced income would benefit from adopting low cost energy efficiency and conservation measures to reduce their energy bills, but it would be difficult to push them to invest large sums of money on, say, efficient heating systems to stimulate the economy. It may well be appropriate, however, to subsidise this investment in return for the economic stimulus benefit, national health outcomes, and environmental benefits. In general, government has numerous options for intervention through the exercise of its various policy, regulatory and leadership roles can work to create an environment conducive to more energy efficient homes and buildings. It can: Lead and communicate the case for change, and provide information to inform consumer choices and explain the case for change. Develop and implement appropriate policy frameworks and associated regulations to ensure that consumers face the full environmental and other costs and benefits of their decisions (like a carbon charge). Effect change through its direct ownership of approximately 80,000 household units, commercial and specialist facilities. Regulate to mandate the installation or use of particular cost effective technologies. In practice, successful policy and its implementation usually requires a mix of the above, rather than reliance on a single intervention. We now briefly describe the merits of two of EECA’s programmes with a view to highlighting energy efficiency potential contributions in meeting economic recession challenges. Retrofit Ceiling insulation Homes built before 1979 do not benefit from the same standards of thermal performance as those built today. This is because the Building Code, a regulation made under the Building Act that specifies the performance standards required of building work including for thermal resistance did not exist prior to 1979 and was recently reviewed and strengthened in 2007. Given that the majority of the nations housing stock were built prior to 2007 and 1979, there are significant potential gains from retrofitting ceiling insulation in older homes. 20 Infometrics In understanding the case for public interventions, it is useful to consider why many home owners do not take it upon themselves to retrofit ceiling insulation in older homes, given the amenity and economic advantages of doing so. Each of the following is significant, and a possible reason for further public policy intervention: The economic benefits are longer term and are often outweighed by short term imperatives. Many home owners may be unaware of the potential benefits and the ease retrofitting ceiling insulation. Around 1/3rd of the population live in rented homes, and landlords may not see any economic or amenity benefits to themselves in retrofitting ceiling insulation. Introduction of a carbon charge to cover one of the environmental costs of energy production would increase the price of energy from non-renewable sources and by so doing create a stronger economic incentive for homeowners and occupiers to retrofit ceiling insulation in existing homes. In doing so, there would also be an important role for government to communicate the necessity and rationale for the change, and the actions and choices available to home owners (including the retrofitting of ceiling insulation) that they can make to offset the increased costs of energy. Government could also consider introducing star rating schemes to convey the efficiency of homes (a variant of HERS) so as to build awareness about the benefits of ceiling insulation. The provision of such information might create additional demand for insulated homes, and result in the value of insulation being factored into house prices and rents. There are also more targeted interventions that government can consider to reinforce the necessity for change. If we were to segment the target population into two groups – owner occupiers and landlords, then the following mix of interventions are worth considering: Owner occupiers – suspensory loans or subsidies to create a sharper and short term incentive for home owners to retrofit ceiling insulation – and to enable low and medium income earners to adjust to increased energy costs; amend Section 112 of the Building Act to require retrofitting of ceiling insulation at the time renovations are carried out existing buildings to the performance standard of the current Building Code. This is a practical means of requiring the retrofitting of existing homes at a time when the costs of doing so are likely to be lowest. A similar approach is taken to the installation of disabled access and fire safety features in commercial buildings. Landlords – government owns significant housing stock and so can undertake to retrofit ceiling insulation in all of the homes that it owns. In doing so, there are a number of benefits for government – investment value as it raises the value of its housing stock; reduces costs of living for low income people and this takes pressure off welfare as well as health. For non-government landlords, tax benefits are already present. Another option that could be considered is through introduction of minimum baseline standards through amendments to the Residential Tenancies Act 1986 (RTA). Space Heating Although heat pumps and pellet burners offer economic benefits to home owners over the long term when compared to alternative means of space heating, the up front costs of conversion may outweigh the longer term benefits for some households. It is also possible that some home owners are not aware of the benefits of converting to these more efficient forms of space heating. Exposing energy companies (and their customers) to the full environmental costs of their energy production and consumption, through implementation of a carbon charge would result in increased costs of energy that would provide added incentive for home owners to switch to more efficient means of space heating. 21 Infometrics In doing so, central government would need to communicate the case for change and provide information to homeowners on actions they can take to offset the impacts of change (such as installation of more efficient means of heating). There would also potentially be a role for central government in providing financial or other assistance for home owners, especially low to medium income earners to adjust to more efficient means of heating that might involve additional short term costs. At more specific levels, central government could: Provide suspensory loans or subsidies (possibly on an income targeted basis) specifically for the purposes of helping meet or mange some of the short term costs of switching to more efficient forms of space heating; Install heat pumps and pellet burners in Housing New Zealand Corporation managed residential properties; Regulate minimum efficiency levels for space heaters. 22 Infometrics Appendix A: New Zealand Wind Energy Projects22 Project District / Regional Economic Benefit Construction Operation Scale (MW) 6 Region Central Wind (Moawhango) 130 Manawatu 60 to 150 FTE over 2 year construction period Mt Cass/Doctors (Canterbury) 69 Canterbury $51.6m 149 job-years Waitahora Valley (Puketoi) 177 Manawatu Waverley Wind Farm 135 Taranaki $21 million (including $14 million of household income) over the 3 year construction period which is equivalent to ~1.3% of 2005-06 District economic activity 304 job-years (101 jobs over the 3 year construction period) $105 million 101.25 job-years Weld Cone wind farm 1.5 Marlborough No information in AEE Mill Creek Project aka Ohariu Valley / Makara Coast Kaiwera Downs (Gore) wind farm 71 Wellington No information in AEE 240 Southland $167.1m 186 FTE/year Project Hayes (Lammermoor wind farm) Hauauru ma raki wind Farm (218 turbines) The Waikato Wind Farm Turitea Wind Farm PN 630 Otago 540 Waikato 360 Manawatu Lake Mahinerangi Wind Farm 200 Otago Te Uku Wind Farm Titiokura Saddle Stage 1 - Te Pohue 84 Waikato 100-150 FTE 2 FTE (on site) 48 Hawke's Bay not quantified 2 FTE (on site) Mt Stuart, Milton Otago $4 million 60 to 150 FTE over 2 year construction period 7 FTE $27m/year 18 jobyears/year $3.4 million / year, including $1.6 million / year of household income 32 FTE 3-4 FTE/year No information in AEE $10m/year 7-8 FTE/yr (onsite only) 18 FTE $159 m (including $101m household income) 399 FTE (or 1,1994 job-years) $9m/year 88 FTE/year $150 million and $180 million (direct) (the direct and indirect expenditure is estimated to be $420 million to $504 million) 250 jobs (including approximately 100 jobs on site) 80 jobs $70M / year Indirect economic benefits could potentially create an additional 140 additional jobs and result in an additional $122M per annum spent within the region $4.3 - $5.5 million / year (direct and indirect expenditures) up to 8 FTE (onsite) Source: EECA, from the Applicants’ Assessment of Environment Effects attached to the Resource Consent Applications. 22 23 Infometrics Appendix B: Cogeneration in Forestry Processing23 Pan Pac, Napier – rated at 13 MW but actually generating 5.5 MW on average over last 8 months. This equates to about 48 GWH/year. CHH, Kawerau – have steam turbine capacity for 27 MW but due to lack of steam have been generating 13.5 MW. This equates to 118 GWh/year. CHH, Kinleith – generation capacity is 25MW (it has a total capacity of 28MW or 41 MVA and 275 GWh/year, however about 11% of this is from natural gas so the actual woodbased electricity is 245 GWh/y ear or 25MW). Red Stag, Waipa – the steam turbine capacity is about 3.5 MW but they average closer to 3 MW. This equates to about 26 GWh/year. Blue Mountain, Tapanui – Their steam turbine is rated at 1.6 MW but they average closer to 1.1. MW. The turbine is used only as a means to dump heat and so is operated for about 20% of the time. This equates to a total electricity generation of about 1.9 GWh. 23 Source: EECA 24 Infometrics