Optimal Distribution Rules for Defined Contribution Plans: What Can the United States Learn from Other Countries? Jonathan Barry Forman* I. Introduction The United States and most other industrialized nations have multi-pillar retirement systems that include a public component and a private component. Increasingly, the private component is an employer-provided defined contribution plan or other privately-managed individual retirement savings account. In order to get adequate retirement income from these defined contribution plans, employees need to ensure that significant contributions are made to these plans (the contribution phase), that those contributions are invested well and retained until retirement (the accumulation phase), and that the accumulated retirement savings are used to * Copyright 2012, Jonathan Barry Forman. Alfred P. Murrah Professor of Law, University of Oklahoma; B.A. 1973, Northwestern University; M.A. (Psychology) 1975, University of Iowa; J.D. 1978, University of Michigan; M.A. (Economics) 1983, George Washington University. This paper is based on a presentation for a conference on “Employee Benefits in an Era of Retrenchment” sponsored by Washington University School of Law and the Center for the Interdisciplinary Study of Work and Social Capital, St. Louis, Missouri, March 29, 2012, and a longer version appears as Jonathan Barry Forman, Optimal Distribution Rules for Defined Contribution Plans: What Can the United States and Australia Learn from Other Countries?, 2012 N.Y.U. REV. OF EMP. BENEFITS & EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION 3-1. 1 provide benefits throughout retirement (the distribution phase). This article focuses on the rules governing the distribution phase. Part II of the article discusses the current rules governing benefit distributions from defined contribution plans in the United States and other countries. Part III explains the various types of financial products that can be used to provide defined contribution plan participants with lifetime retirement income. Finally, Part IV of the article considers how distribution rules and regulations can be used to encourage retirees to take their defined contribution plan distributions in the form of annuities or other lifetime income products. II. A Defined Contribution World The United States and most other industrialized nations have multi-pillar retirement systems that can be categorized within the World Bank’s multi-pillar model for retirement savings, consisting of (1) a government pension, (2) an occupational pension, and (3) personal savings.1 Increasingly, the second and third tier components take the form of defined contribution (DC) plans, Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), and similar types of individual 1 WORLD BANK, AVERTING THE OLD AGE CRISIS: POLICIES TO PROTECT THE OLD AND PROMOTE GROWTH xiv (1994); see also ROBERT HOLZMANN & RICHARD HINZ, OLD-AGE INCOME SUPPORT IN THE 21ST CENTURY: AN INTERNATIONAL PERSPECTIVE ON PENSION SYSTEMS AND REFORM 2 (2005) (suggesting an additional pillar for informal intrafamily or intergenerational sources of both financial and nonfinancial support to the elderly, including access to health care and housing). 2 retirement savings accounts. Under a typical defined contribution plan, the employer contributes a specified percentage of the worker’s compensation to an individual investment account for the worker. For example, contributions might be set at 10% of annual compensation. Under such a plan, a worker who earned $30,000 in a given year would have $3,000 contributed to the worker’s individual investment account ($3,000 = 10% × $30,000). The benefit at retirement would be based on all such contributions plus investment earnings. Defined contribution plans are also known as “individual account” plans because each worker has his or her own account, as opposed to the more traditional defined benefit pension plans which pool plan assets for the benefit of all employees.2 Another key difference is that at 2 For a defined benefit plan, an employer promises its employees a definite benefit at retirement. To provide that benefit, the employer typically makes payments into a trust fund, contributed funds grow with investment returns, and eventually the employer withdraws funds from the trust fund to pay the promised benefits. JONATHAN BARRY FORMAN, MAKING AMERICA WORK 215 (2006). For example, a plan may provide that a worker’s annual retirement benefit (B) is equal to 2%, multiplied by the worker’s number of years of service (yos) and the worker’s final average compensation (fac) (B = 2% × yos × fac). Under this final-average-pay formula, a worker with thirty years of service would receive a retirement benefit equal to 60% of his or her preretirement earnings (B = 60% × fac = 2% × 30 yos × fac). Final average compensation is usually computed by averaging the worker’s salary over the last three or five years prior to retirement. 3 retirement, typical defined contribution plans distribute benefits in the form of lump sum cash distributions, while traditional defined benefit pension plans are designed to pay monthly pension benefits from retirement until death.3 A. Defined Contribution Plans in the United States The United States has a “voluntary” pension system.4 That is, employers are not required to provide pensions to employees. However, when employers do provide pensions, those pensions are typically subject to regulation under the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974.5 Most pension plans qualify for favorable tax treatment. Basically, an employer’s contributions to a tax-qualified retirement plan on behalf of an employee are not taxable to the employee.6 Moreover, the pension fund’s earnings on those contributions are tax-exempt.7 3 In the United States for example, defined benefit plans are generally designed to provide annuities that are “definitely determinable benefits . . . over a period of years, usually for life after retirement.” 26 C.F.R. § 1.401-1(b)(1)(i) (2006). 4 FORMAN, supra note 2, at 214; Kathryn L. Moore, An Overview of the U.S. Retirement Income Security System and the Principles and Values It Reflects, 33 COMP. LAB. L. & POL’Y J. 5, 17 (2011). 5 Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974, Pub. L. No. 93-406, 88 Stat. 829. 6 I.R.C. § 402 (2006). 7 I.R.C. § 501(a) (2006). 4 Workers pay tax only when they receive distributions of their pension benefits, and at that point, the usual rules for taxing annuities apply.8 Also, employers typically get to deduct their contributions.9 There are a variety of defined contribution plans, including money purchase pension plans, target benefit plans, profit-sharing plans, stock bonus plans, and employee stock 8 I.R.C. §§ 72, 402 (2006). An individual receiving benefits under an annuity or pension usually excludes a fraction of those benefits from income. That fraction (the “exclusion ratio”) is based on the amount of premiums or other after-tax contributions made by the individual. The exclusion ratio enables the individual to recover his or her own after-tax contributions tax free and to pay tax only on the remaining portion of benefits which represents income. 9 I.R.C. § 404 (2006); Jonathan Barry Forman, The Tax Treatment of Public and Private Pension Plans Around the World, 14 AM. J. OF TAX POL’Y 299 (1997). This exempt-exempt-taxable approach is followed by many of the world’s pensions. See, e.g., ORG. FOR ECON. COOPERATION & DEV., PENSIONS AT A GLANCE 2011: RETIREMENT-INCOME SYSTEMS IN OECD AND G20 COUNTRIES 58, 122–23 (2011); KWANG-YEOL YOO & ALAIN DE SERRES, TAX TREATMENT OF PRIVATE PENSION SAVINGS IN OECD COUNTRIES 76 (Org. for Econ. Cooperation & Dev. ed., 2005). Also of note, since 2002 in the U.S., certain low and moderate income individuals have been able to claim a tax credit of up to $1,000 for certain qualified retirement savings contributions. I.R.C. § 25B (2006); LISA SOUTHWORTH & JOHN GIST, AARP PUB. POLICY INST., THE SAVER’S CREDIT: WHAT DOES IT DO FOR SAVING? (2008). 5 ownership plans (ESOPs).10 Of particular note, profit-sharing and stock bonus plans often include a feature that allows workers to choose between receiving cash currently or deferring taxation by placing the money in a retirement account according to Internal Revenue Code section 401(k). Consequently, these plans are often called “401(k) plans,” and they are the most popular type of retirement plan in the United States.11 The maximum annual amount of such elective deferrals that can be made by an individual in 2013 is $17,500, although workers over the age of fifty can contribute another $5,500, for a total of up to $23,000.12 Favorable tax rules are also available for certain IRAs.13 Almost any worker can set up an IRA with a bank or other financial institution. In 2012, individuals without pension plans can contribute and deduct up to $5,000 to an IRA, although individuals over age fifty can contribute and deduct another $1,000, for a total of up to $6,000, and spouses can contribute and deduct 10 See, e.g., Six Ways to Save for Retirement, 3 BUREAU OF LAB. STAT. PROGRAM PERSP., no. 3, 2011, at 1, 2. 11 See, e.g., BLS Examines Popular 401(k) Retirement Plans, 2 BUREAU OF LAB. STAT. PROGRAM PERSP., no. 6, 2010, at 1. 12 IRS Announces 2013 Pension Plan Limitations: Taxpayers May Contribute up to $17,500 to their 401(k) plans in 2013, INTERNAL REVENUE SERVICE (Oct. 18, 2012), available at http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-news/IR-12-077.pdf. 13 I.R.C. § 219 (2006). 6 similar amounts.14 If a worker is covered by another retirement plan, however, the deduction may be reduced or eliminated if the worker’s income exceeds $58,000 for a single individual or $92,000 for a married couple.15 Like private pensions, IRA earnings are tax-exempt, and distributions are taxable. Also, since 1998, individuals have been permitted to create Roth IRAs.16 Unlike regular IRAs, contributions to Roth IRAs are not deductible. Instead, withdrawals are tax-free. Like regular IRAs, Roth IRA earnings are tax-exempt. And since 2006, employers have been permitted to establish Roth 401(k) plans that operate in a similar fashion.17 B. The Dominance of Defined Contribution Plans In recent years, defined contribution plans have come to dominate the pension landscape. For example, 50% of full-time private industry workers in the United States participated in defined contribution plans in 2011, up from 40% in 1989–90; meanwhile, participation in 14 Retirement Topics—IRA Contribution Limits, INTERNAL REVENUE SERVICE (Aug. 3, 2012), available at http://www.irs.gov/retirement/participant/article/0,,id=211358,00.html. 15 Internal Revenue Service, supra note 12. 16 I.R.C. § 408A (2006). 17 I.R.C. § 402A (2006). 7 defined benefit plans fell from 42% in 1989–90 to just 22% in 2011.18 In the aggregate, defined contribution plans held 57% of pension assets in the United States in 2011, up from 52% in 2001.19 Similarly, 81% of pension assets in Australia were held by defined contribution plans (the same percentage as in 2001), 60% in Switzerland (up from 49% in 2001), and 39% in the United Kingdom (up from just 8% in 2001). All in all, the era of the traditional defined benefit pension plan is largely behind us,20 but the relatively low savings rates in our new “defined contribution world” have led many analysts to wonder if future retirees will have adequate retirement incomes.21 C. 18 The Decline of Annuitization William J. Wiatrowski, Changing Landscape of Employment-Based Retirement Benefits, BUREAU OF LAB. STAT. (Sept. 29, 2011), available at http://www.bls.gov/opub/cwc/cm20110927ar01p1.htm. 19 TOWERS WATSON, GLOBAL PENSION ASSET STUDY 2012 8, 34-36 (Jan. 2012), available at http://www.towerswatson.com/assets/pdf/6267/Global-Pensions-Asset-Study-2012.pdf. 20 EDWARD A. ZELINSKY, THE ORIGINS OF THE OWNERSHIP SOCIETY: HOW THE DEFINED CONTRIBUTION PARADIGM CHANGED AMERICA (2004); Edward A. Zelinsky, The Defined Contribution Paradigm, 114 YALE L. J. 451 (2004). 21 See, e.g., Jack VanDerhei, The Importance of Defined Benefit Plans for Retirement Income Adequacy, EMP. BENEFIT RES. INST. NOTES, Aug. 2011, at 7; Steven Greenhouse, After the Storm, the Little Nest Eggs that Couldn’t, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 7, 2012, at F1. 8 The United States has a well-developed annuity market.22 Nevertheless, over the years, there has been a significant decline in annuitization of retirement savings by American workers. The shift to defined contribution plans is a large part of the story, because defined contribution plans typically distribute benefits in the form of lump sum distributions rather than as annuities.23 Indeed, relatively few defined contribution plans even offer annuity options, and relatively few participants elect annuity options.24 All in all, people rarely choose to buy annuities voluntarily, even though purchasing annuities could rationally help maximize their expected retirement 22 Anthony Webb, The United States Longevity Insurance Market, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME: GLOBAL ANNUITY MARKETS AND POLICY 63 (Olivia S. Mitchell, John Piggott & Noriyuki Takayama eds., 2011). 23 TOWERS WATSON, INTERNATIONAL PENSION PLAN SURVEY: REPORT 2011 1–5 (2011), available at http://www.towerswatson.com/assets/pdf/6036/TW-EU-2011-22755-IPP-survey.pdf. An annuity is a financial instrument (e.g., an insurance contract) that converts a lump sum of money into a stream of income payable over a period of years, typically for life. The person holding an annuity is called an annuitant. 24 See BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS, U.S. DEP’T OF LABOR, NATIONAL COMPENSATION SURVEY: HEALTH AND RETIREMENT PLAN PROVISIONS IN PRIVATE INDUSTRY IN THE UNITED STATES, 2010 (2011); BEVERLY J. ORTH, APPROACHES FOR PROMOTING VOLUNTARY ANNUITIZATION (2008) (presented at the 2008 Retirement 20/20 Conference, Society of Actuaries in Washington, D.C., November 17-18, 2008). 9 incomes.25 Of note, the Internal Revenue Service and the U.S. Department of Labor recently mounted a joint effort to improve lifetime income options for retirement plans.26 The U.S. Treasury and the Internal Revenue Service also recently released a package of proposed regulations and rulings intended to make it easier for plans to offer partial annuities and longevity insurance to retirees.27 D. Defined Contribution Plans in Other Countries As in the United States, the level of voluntary annuitization is generally low around the world.28 In Australia, for example, just seventeen life annuity policies were sold in 2009.29 In 25 See Shlomo Benartzi, Alessandro Previtero & Richard H. Thaler, Annuitization Puzzles, 25 J. ECON. PERSP. 143 (2011). 26 Joint Hearing on Lifetime Income Options Before the U.S. Dep’t of Labor & U.S. Dep’t of the Treasury (Sept. 14-15, 2010). 27 U.S. DEP’T OF THE TREASURY, TREASURY FACT SHEET: HELPING AMERICAN FAMILIES ACHIEVE RETIREMENT SECURITY BY EXPANDING LIFETIME INCOME CHOICES (2012), available at http://www.treasury.gov/press-center/pressreleases/Documents/020212%20Retirement%20Security%20Factsheet.pdf. 28 Olivia S. Mitchell & John Piggott, Turning Wealth into Lifetime Income: The Challenge Ahead, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 1, 3. 10 Sweden, the development of the annuity markets has been held back by public pensions and by traditional occupational pensions.30 In Germany, annuity markets are well-developed but underutilized.31 For tax reasons, annuities are unattractive in Japan,32 and in India, government policy on life annuities is underdeveloped.33 However, there are a few countries that have significantly higher levels of annuitization. For example, approximately two-thirds of all participants in Chile’s national defined contribution 29 Hazel Bateman & John Piggott, Too Much Risk to Insure? The Australian (non-) Market for Annuities, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 96 tbl. 6.5; see also Jack Jie Ding, Annuitization with Phased Consumption Requirements: Who, When and How Much (Macquarie Univ. Dep’t. of Econ., Working Paper, Dec. 3, 2011), available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2014453. 30 Edward Palmer & Bo Larsson, The Swedish Annuity Market: Where it is and Where it’s Headed, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 13, 15, 27. 31 Barbara Kaschützke & Raimond Maurer, The Private Life Annuity Market in Germany: Products and Money’s Worth Ratios, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 131. 32 Junichi Sakamoto, Annuity Markets in Japan, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 159. 33 Mukul G. Asher & Deepa Vasudevan, Market Structure and Challenges for Annuities in India, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 32. 11 system purchase annuities.34 Chile has achieved this high rate of annuitization largely by restricting the options for retirement distributions. The main options are a phased withdrawal benefit or a life annuity. Under the phased withdrawal approach, the retiree retains ownership of the account balance, and the fund administrator makes monthly distributions based on a government formula that takes into account the retiree’s age, sex, and marital status. Alternatively, retirees can purchase life annuities from insurance companies. Because of government regulation and the relatively large and competitive market for annuities in Chile, commissions to purchase life annuities are quite low—under 2%—and money’s worth values are relatively high.35 Switzerland also has markedly higher annuitization rates compared to most other countries—approximately 80%.36 Switzerland has a mandatory occupational pension system for 34 Jose Ruiz & Olivia S. Mitchell, Pension Payouts in Chile: Past, Present, and Future Prospects, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 107, 111, 126. 35 Id. at 111, 122–26. The “money’s worth ratio” is, “the discounted expected present value of the lifetime payment stream relative to the premium, conditional on survival.” Id. at 124. 36 Monika Bütler & Stefan Staubli, Payouts in Switzerland: Explaining Developments in Annuitization, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 195, 203; B. Avanzi, What is it that Makes the Swiss Annuitise? A Description of the Swiss Retirement System, 16 AUSTL. ACTUARIAL J. 135 (2010); Monika Bütler & Martin Ruesch, Annuities in Switzerland 89 (World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS4438, 2007). 12 most employees. Payout choices are also strongly influenced by the fact that in most pension plans, the default option is an annuity, and peer effects are also important. The United Kingdom has the largest annuity market in the world, primarily because individuals who have saved in tax-favored pension plans are required to annuitize at least 75% of their pension wealth.37 Singapore recently announced that its citizens must annuitize a minimum amount of their retirement assets in the country’s Central Provident Fund, although the rest can be taken as a lump sum.38 Pension income from approved annuity providers is exempt from tax. The government will also enter the insurance market as an annuity provider. Poland’s new pension system will also pay out benefits in the form of life annuities.39 37 Edmund Cannon & Ian Tonks, Compulsory and Voluntary Annuity Markets in the United Kingdom, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 171. To be sure, retirees have considerable leeway over how much to annuitize and when. 38 Joelle H.Y. Fong, Olivia S. Mitchell & Benedict S. K. Koh, Longevity Risk Management in Singapore’s National Pension System 1 (Pension Research Council, Working Paper No. WP2010-10, 2010). 39 Marek Szczepański, The Design of Supplementary Pension Schemes in Poland and Longevity Risk: Current Situation and Proposed Changes 4 (Pensions Inst., Discussion Paper No. PI-1202, 2012). As for third-tier, supplementary pension schemes, the annuity market in Poland is fairly thin. Id. at 8. 13 III. Lifetime Retirement Income Products A. Managing Longevity Risk Retirees face numerous risks in managing their assets through retirement.40 Longevity risk—the risk of outliving one’s retirement savings—is probably the greatest risk facing current and future retirees with defined contribution plans. As life expectancy increases, accumulated retirement savings in individual accounts will need to finance an ever-greater portion of retirees’ ever-longer retirements. At present, a sixty-five-year-old woman has a 50% chance of living past age eighty-six, while a sixty-five-year-old man has a 50% chance of living past age eighty-four.41 The joint life expectancy of a sixty-five-year-old couple is even more remarkable. There is a 50% chance that at least one sixty-five-year-old spouse will live to age ninety-one, and there 40 The top risks for today’s retirees include: longevity, inflation, market volatility, withdrawal rate, health care expenses, and unexpected events. AMERIPRISE FIN., MAKING YOUR RETIREMENT INCOME LAST A LIFETIME (Nov. 2010), available at http://cdn.ameriprisecontent.com/cds/alwp/advisor/david.p.weidman/cdocuments-andsettingsandrewdesktopwebsite-downloadsmaking-your-retirement-income-last-alifetiime634532517160486099.pdf. 41 H.R. DOC. NO. 112-102, at 91 tbl. V.A4 (2012). 14 is a 25% chance that at least one will live to ninety-five.42 That means married couples can easily have twenty-five or thirty years in retirement. Pertinent here, one study estimated that three out of five new middle class retirees will outlive their financial assets if they attempt to maintain their pre-retirement standard of living.43 As more fully described below, retirees can use a variety of approaches to help manage their longevity risk, including systematic withdrawals, traditional lifetime annuities, longevity insurance, and variable annuities with guaranteed lifetime withdrawal benefits.44 Depending on each retiree’s specific circumstances, the best strategy may involve a combination of these products. B. 42 Systematic Withdrawals Fred Reish, Just out of Reish: Living “Room”? The Problem with Living Too Long, PLAN SPONSOR (Aug. 2011), available at http://www.plansponsor.com/MagazineArticle.aspx?id=6442481375. 43 ERNST & YOUNG LLP, RETIREMENT VULNERABILITY OF NEW RETIREES: THE LIKELIHOOD OF OUTLIVING THEIR FINANCIAL ASSETS i (2008). 44 See, e.g., SOC’Y OF ACTUARIES, MANAGING RETIREMENT DECISIONS SERIES: DESIGNING A MONTHLY PAYCHECK FOR RETIREMENT (2012); Steve Vernon, The Retirement Income Menu: An Idea Whose Time Has Come, 2 INST. RETIREMENT COUNCIL UPDATE, no. 9, 2011, at 1, 5; Anthony Webb, Making Your Nest Egg Last a Lifetime, B.C. CTR. FOR RETIREMENT RES., Sept. 2009, at 1-4. 15 One of the simplest and most common strategies to manage retirement savings is to invest all of the funds in a diversified portfolio, and then use a conservative withdrawal rate and a systematic withdrawal plan designed to have a high probability that the retirement savings will last for twenty or thirty years. To be sure, many people start out by simply trying to live off of their interest and dividends, with an eye towards leaving their principal to heirs. More typically, however, individuals invest their retirement savings and try to draw down their principal and investment income carefully through managed withdrawals. In that regard, financial planners often suggest following the 4% rule.45 The basic idea is to invest retirement savings in a 50% stock, 50% bond portfolio, and initially to set spending at 4% of retirement savings. Each year thereafter, spending is increased to keep up with inflation. For example, assuming that our hypothetical investor has a $1,000,000 nest egg, in the first year the retiree would withdraw 4% ($40,000), and each year thereafter that dollar amount would increase to keep up with inflation.46 Assuming a 3% inflation rate, annual withdrawals would increase to $41,200 in the second year, $42,436 in the third year, and so on. While there is some possibility of running out of money, most financial planners believe this strategy will work for thirty years 45 William P. Bengen, Determining Withdrawal Rates Using Historical Data, 7 J. FIN. PLAN. 171 (1994). 46 See Eleanor Laise, A Strategy for a Lifetime of Income, KIPLINGER, Aug. 17, 2011 (applying the 4% rule), available at http://www.kiplinger.com/features/archives/ krr-a-strategy-for-a-lifetime-of-income.html. 16 of retirement. C. Lifetime Annuities Traditional lifetime annuities offer another approach for managing longevity risk. Depending on the retiree’s age, immediate annuities can provide cash flows of 7% of funds invested or more, and immediate annuities provide a powerful hedge against longevity risk. For example, for a sixty-five-year-old man who purchased a $100,000 immediate, level-payment annuity without inflation protection in 2011, the annual payout would be around $6,732 or 6.73% of the annuity’s purchase price.47 Alternatively, he could buy an inflation-adjusted annuity. For example, if he instead purchased an annuity with a 3% escalator, he would receive $4,944 in the first year and ever-increasing amounts in later years. However, annuities do have several disadvantages. In particular, annuitants lose control of the underlying funds, and unless a guarantee feature is selected, nothing will remain for the annuitants’ heirs in the event of early death. Also, because of adverse selection (meaning that those who voluntarily purchase annuities tend to live longer than those who do not), annuities are not priced very well. In that regard, many analysts believe that most retirees will get the most value for their investment if they defer the decision to annuitize until the age of seventy-five or 47 Immediate Annuities Update, ANNUITY SHOPPER, Jan. 2012, at 28 tbl. 5. Women tend to live longer than men, therefore the annual payout for a sixty-five-year-old woman who elected an immediate, level-payment annuity in 2011 would be just $6,264 or 6.26% of the annuity’s purchase price. Id. 17 eighty.48 Finally, it is important to note that Social Security and Supplemental Security Income already provide inflation-adjusted monthly benefits that may crowd out private annuities.49 D. Longevity Insurance Alternatively, retirees can protect against longevity risk by purchasing longevity insurance.50 The typical approach is to buy a deferred annuity at age sixty-five that starts making annual payments only if the annuitant lives past age eighty or eighty-five. For example, in February of 2012, a sixty-five-year-old man could invest $100,000 in a MetLife deferred annuity, and beginning at age eighty-five, he would receive a level lifetime income of $25,451.04 a year.51 Alternatively, that $100,000 could buy a deferred annuity that would pay $17,069.40 a year starting at age eighty, $11,649.84 a year starting at age seventy-five, or $8,133.60 a year starting 48 See Moshe Arye Milevsky, Optimal Annuitization Policies: Analysis of the Options, 5 N. AM. ACTUARIAL J., no. 1, 2001, at 57, 66. 49 See, e.g., Monika Bütler, Kim Peijnenburg & Stefan Staubli, How Much Do Means-Tested Benefits Reduce the Demand for Annuities? (Network for Studies on Pensions, Aging and Retirement, Discussion Paper No. DP 06/2011-52, 2011). 50 See Jason S. Scott, The Longevity Annuity: An Annuity for Everyone?, FIN. ANALYSTS J., Jan.- Feb. 2008, at 40; Anthony Webb, Guan Gong & Wei Sun, An Annuity that People Might Actually Buy, B.C. CTR. FOR RETIREMENT RESEARCH, July 2007, at 1. 51 E-mail from Hersh Stern, WebAnnuities Insurance Agency, Inc., to Jonathan Barry Forman (Feb. 07, 2012, 9:46 AM) (on file with author). 18 at age seventy. Companies do not offer inflation-adjusted deferred annuities, but some companies do offer fixed step-ups.52 To be sure, there is some risk of running out of money before the year that the deferred annuity starts, but that is certainly less of a risk than trying to manage one’s retirement savings from the start of retirement over the indefinite future. Pertinent here, the current U.S. minimum distribution rules, which generally requires participants to begin taking distributions soon after they reach age seventy-and-a-half, can make it difficult to purchase deferred annuities that commence after that age with funds that are held inside defined contribution plans.53 In that regard, however, the Internal Revenue Service recently released proposed regulations that would ease the minimum distribution requirements to permit up to $100,000, or, if less, 25% of the participant’s account balance, to be used to purchase a “Qualifying Longevity Annuity Contract.”54 Of particular note, workers could be encouraged to buy deferred annuities in installments, starting at a young age. For example, a worker could use a portion of the worker’s retirement 52 Joseph A. Tomlinson, Income Choices, FINANCIAL PLANNING, May 1, 2011, available at http://www.financial-planning.com/fp_issues/2011_5/income-choices-2672801-1.html. 53 See I.R.C. § 401(a)(9) (2006); Natalie Choate, New! Longevity Insurance for IRAs, MORNINGSTAR ADVISOR (Mar. 9, 2012), available at http://www.morningstar.com/advisor/t/52769065/new-longevity-insurance-for-iras.htm. 54 Longevity Annuity Contracts, 77 Fed. Reg. 5443 (proposed Feb. 3, 2012) (to be codified at 26 C.F.R. pt. 1); U.S. DEP’T OF TREASURY, supra note 27. 19 contributions each year to purchase a deferred life annuity that started at age sixty-five or a later age.55 Deferred annuities like these could provide retirement benefits that mimic the lifetime pensions provided by traditional defined benefit plans. E. Guaranteed Lifetime Withdrawal Benefits Finally, retirees can use variable annuities with Guaranteed Lifetime Withdrawal Benefits (GLWB) funds to manage their longevity risk.56 A GLWB annuity is based on a variable annuity, but it allows investors to lock in a minimum guarantee for life. Mechanically, the investor or retiree deposits, or rolls over, a sum of money into a variable annuity with subaccounts that are invested in stocks, bonds, and other generic investments. Depending on market performance, that investment portfolio grows—or shrinks. In any event, at retirement, the annuitant starts taking guaranteed withdrawals from the account. Payouts come from the invested funds, but if those funds are ever depleted due to long life or poor investment returns, the guaranteed minimum kicks in. The guaranteed withdrawal rate is determined at the time of the sale, and it might be set at 55 Moshe A. Milevsky, Real Longevity Insurance with a Deductible: Introduction to Advanced- Life Delayed Annuities (ALDA), 9 N. AM. ACTUARIAL J., no. 9, 2005, at 109. 56 Moshe A. Milevsky & Ling-wu Shao, Annuities and their Derivatives: The Recent Canadian Experience, in SECURING LIFELONG RETIREMENT INCOME, supra note 22, at 50, 56. 20 between 4% and 6% depending upon the age when withdrawals are to begin.57 The guaranteed amount is determined by multiplying the guaranteed rate by the guaranteed base, which is determined when withdrawals begin. Depending on the contract, if the investment portfolio performs well, the guaranteed base might reset to a higher level and generate even greater withdrawals. On the downside, GLWB annuities can be very complicated, they can have annual costs that exceed 3% of asset value, they can have heavy surrender charges, and they typically do not have an inflation adjustment.58 All in all, GLWB annuities are similar to systematic withdrawal in that the investor maintains control over the assets, but the investor trades a lower rate of return (meaning gross return less fees) for the guarantee of not outliving assets.59 IV. Optimal Distribution Rules Clearly, there are a number of approaches and products that can help retirees manage their longevity risk. While lump sum distributions tend to dissipate quickly, annuities and similar 57 See generally Benny Goodman & Seth Tanenbaum, TIAA-CREF Inst., The 5% Guaranteed Minimum Withdrawal Benefit: Paying Something for Nothing?, RESEARCH DIALOGUE, Apr. 2008. 58 SOC’Y OF ACTUARIES, supra note 44, at 6; see also Tomlinson, supra note 52. 59 “Stand-alone living benefits” are similar to GLWBs, except that instead of using a variable annuity chassis, stand-alone living benefits use mutual funds or managed accounts as the base. Tomlinson, supra note 52. 21 products can last a lifetime. Government policy should be designed to mandate, or at least encourage, retirees to purchase such lifetime income products.60 A. Mandate or Encourage Annuitization One approach for promoting lifetime retirement income would be for the government to require retirees to purchase annuities or similar lifetime income guarantees. As mentioned, that is what Singapore, Sweden, and Poland are doing, and the United Kingdom and Chile have been promoting annuitization for years. President George W. Bush’s Commission to Strengthen Social Security also recommended that at least a portion of the balances in its proposed individual accounts should be annuitized.61 More specifically, the Commission recommended 60 See, e.g., FORMAN, supra note 2, at 238–39; U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-11- 400, RETIREMENT INCOME: ENSURING INCOME THROUGHOUT RETIREMENT REQUIRES DIFFICULT CHOICES (2011); PAMELA PERUN, THE ASPEN INST., RETIREMENT SAVINGS: CONFRONTING THE CHALLENGE OF LONGEVITY (2010); Roberto Rocha & Dimitri Vittas, Designing the Payout Phase of Pension Systems: Policy Issues, Constraints and Options (World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper No. 5289, 2010). 61 COMM’N TO STRENGTHEN SOC. SEC., EXEC. OFFICE OF THE PRESIDENT, STRENGTHENING SOCIAL SECURITY AND CREATING PERSONAL WEALTH FOR ALL AMERICANS 41–42 (2001); John F. Cogan & Olivia S. Mitchell, Perspectives from the President’s Commission on Social Security Reform, in LESSONS FROM PENSION REFORM IN THE AMERICAS 216, 229–30 (Stephen J. Kay & Tapen Sinha eds., 2008). 22 that each retiree be required to annuitize enough to keep the retiree’s annual income above the poverty level throughout retirement.62 Alternatively, the government might want only to encourage annuitization. For example, the government could require defined contribution plans to make annuity options available to plan participants.63 The government might even require plans to default participants into annuities or trial annuities, unless plan participants affirmatively elect otherwise.64 62 COMM’N TO STRENGTHEN SOC. SEC., supra note 61, at 41. On the plus side, if everyone had to buy an annuity with all or part of their defined contribution plan savings, annuity prices would fall, both because the larger annuity market would be more efficient and because adverse selection would decline as virtually every retiree would buy an annuity, not just those who expected to live a long time. Estelle James, Truman Packard & Robert Holzmann, Reflections on Pension Reform in the Americas: From ‘Averting the Old-Age Crisis’ to ‘Keeping the Promise of Old-Age Security’ and Beyond, in LESSONS FROM PENSION REFORM IN THE AMERICAS, supra note 61, at 164, 169–70. 63 See, e.g., U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 60, at 38–39. 64 U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 60, at 39–40; GORDON A. (SANDY) MACKENZIE, THE DECLINE OF THE TRADITIONAL PENSION 200–03 (2010). See generally Jeffrey R. Brown, Understanding the Role of Annuities in Retirement Planning, in OVERCOMING THE SAVINGS SLUMP 178, 199–200 (Annamaria Lusardi ed., 2008); William G. Gale, J. Mark Iwry, David C. John & Lina Walker, Increasing Annuitization in 401(k) Plans with Automatic Trial 23 It could even make sense to encourage or require individuals to allocate a portion of their contributions to annuities or annuity-like products.65 Such “in-service” annuities would enable workers to obtain streams of lifetime income each year that they work, just as workers with traditional defined benefit plan pensions currently do.66 For that matter, the government could actually get into the market of selling annuities and other lifetime income products or, alternatively, guaranteeing products sold by private companies.67 The U.S. Department of the Treasury already sells inflation-adjusted bonds that Income (The Retirement Sec. Project, Paper No. 2008-2, 2008); J. Mark Iwry & John A. Turner, Automatic Annuitization: New Behavioral Strategies for Expanding Lifetime Income in 401(k)s (The Retirement Sec. Project, Paper No. 2009-2, 2009); JEFFREY R. BROWN, AM. COUNCIL OF LIFE INSURERS, AUTOMATIC LIFETIME INCOME AS A PATH TO RETIREMENT INCOME SECURITY (2009). 65 See, e.g., BROWN, supra note 64, at 4; Paul Yakoboski, TIAA-CREF INST., Retirees, Annuitization and Defined Contribution Plans, TRENDS AND ISSUES, Apr. 2010, at 3, 5. 66 Moreover, by annuitizing savings in multiple installments over many years rather than just at retirement, in-service annuities would reduce investment risk and income risk to individuals. MACKENZIE, supra note 64, at 195–96. 67 See, e.g., ORTH, supra note 24, at 3; Henry T.C. Hu & Terrance Odean, Paying for Old Age, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 25, 2011, at A19; Lawrence A. Frolik, Protecting Our Aging Retirees: 24 can be useful in developing inflation-adjusted financial products.68 Some analysts have also suggested using the tax system to encourage people to take their distributions as annuities. For example, the government could exempt annuity payouts from income taxation or favor them with a reduced tax rate.69 B. More Financial Education about Lifetime Income Products The government also has a role in promoting financial education about annuities and other lifetime income products. For example, in addition to showing the total balance in a defined contribution account, benefit statements could be required to include an estimate of the “annuity equivalent” lifetime income stream of payments.70 More specifically, individual benefit Converting 401(k) Accounts into Federally Guaranteed Lifetime Annuities, 47 SAN DIEGO L. REV. 277 (2010). 68 See, e.g., Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (TIPS), TREASURYDIRECT (Apr. 22, 2011), available at http://www.treasurydirect.gov/indiv/products/prod_tips_glance.htm. 69 See, e.g., Retirement Security Needs Lifetime Pay Act of 2009, H.R. 2748, 111th Cong. (2009); Szczepański, supra note 39, at 8. 70 See, e.g., Lifetime Income Disclosure Act, S. 267, 112th Cong. (2011); H.R. 677, 112th Cong. (2011); U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, supra note 60, at 48–49; ADVISORY COUNCIL ON EMP. WELFARE & PENSION BENEFIT PLANS, REPORT ON THE SPEND DOWN OF DEFINED CONTRIBUTION ASSETS AT RETIREMENT (2008) (“Recommendation 4: Encourage and allow 25 statements could be required to show the monthly annuity payment that would be made if the employee’s total account balance were used to buy a single life annuity that commenced when the employee reaches age sixty-five. For married employees, these individualized statements would also show the monthly annuity payments under a qualified joint and survivor annuity. C. Asset Tests The government should also better coordinate treatment of pensions and the asset tests used in means-tested public programs like Medicaid, food stamps, and Supplemental Security Income. The stringent asset tests under those programs often require low-income workers to withdraw the balances in their defined contribution plans and “spend down” those assets before they can qualify for benefits.71 Consequently, these asset tests can encourage individuals to dissipate their retirement savings and may even discourage individuals from saving for retirement in the first place. While distributions from retirement accounts should probably count as “income” in determining eligibility for means-tested benefits, modest amounts held in defined contribution plans and annuities should probably be excluded from the asset tests. D. Other Things Government Can Do In addition to promoting annuities and other lifetime retirement income options, the government should also encourage people to save more while they are working. Ideally, the additional participant disclosure, specifically the conversion of account balances into annual retirement income.”), available at www.dol.gov/ebsa/publications/2008ACreport3.html. 71 See, e.g., Bütler et al., supra note 49. 26 United States should adopt a mandatory universal pension system like Australia, Singapore, and Chile.72 At the very least, we should adopt policies that make 401(k) plans or payroll-deduction IRAs available to all workers.73 The government could also help defined contribution plan participants do a better job managing their retirement savings.74 Pertinent here, the Pension Protection Act of 2006 encourages employers to replace their low-yield, stable-value bond funds with “qualified default investment alternatives” like balanced funds, life-cycle funds, and variable annuity contracts.75 The U.S. Department of Labor also recently finalized regulations that will make it easier for plan 72 TERESA GHILARDUCCI, WHEN I’M SIXTY FOUR: THE PLOT AGAINST PENSIONS AND THE PLAN TO SAVE THEM 263–93 (2008); Jonathan Barry Forman, Should We Replace the Current Pension System with a Universal Pension System?, 16 J. OF PENSION BENEFITS, no. 2, 2009, at 51; U.S. GOV’T ACCOUNTABILITY OFFICE, GAO-09-642, PRIVATE PENSIONS: ALTERNATIVE APPROACHES COULD ADDRESS RETIREMENT RISKS FACED BY WORKERS BUT POSE TRADE-OFFS 52 (2009). 73 FORMAN, supra note 2, at 233–35. See, e.g., Automatic IRA Act of 2012, H.R. 4049, 112th Cong. (2012); J. Mark Iwry & David C. John, Pursuing Universal Retirement Security Through Automatic IRAs (The Retirement Sec. Project, Paper No. 2007-2, 2007). 74 Stephen Blakely, Is There a Future for Retirement?, EMP. BENEFIT RES. INST. NOTES, Sept. 2011, at 16. 75 29 C.F.R. § 2550.404c-5 (2011). 27 sponsors to give investment advice to plan participants,76 and another set of regulations that will improve disclosures about fees, expenses, and investments.77 The government could also do more to encourage people to work longer.78 For example, the government could raise the age for the Internal Revenue Code section 72(t) penalty on premature withdrawals from age fifty-nine-and-a-half to age sixty-two, the current early retirement age for Social Security. Similarly, the government could raise the normal retirement age for pensions to match Social Security’s full retirement age—currently age sixty-six, but headed to age sixty-seven.79 76 See Investment Advice—Participants and Beneficiaries, 76 Fed. Reg. 66136 (Oct. 25, 2011) (to be codified at 29 C.F.R. pt. 2550). 77 Press Release, Emp. Benefits Sec. Admin., U.S. Dep’t of Labor, U.S. Department of Labor Extends and Aligns Applicability Dates for Retirement Plan Fee Disclosure Rules (July 13, 2011), available at http://www.dol.gov/ebsa/newsroom/2011/11-1063-NAT.html. 78 See, e.g., Jonathan Barry Forman & Yung-Ping (Bing) Chen, Optimal Retirement Age, 2008 N.Y.U. REV. OF EMP. BENEFITS & EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION 14-1; Jack VanDerhei & Craig Copeland, The Impact of Deferring Retirement Age on Retirement Income Adequacy, 358 EMP. BENEFIT RES. INST. ISSUE BRIEF, Jun. 2011. 79 Also, as the Social Security system offers actuarially fair increases in benefits to those who delay taking their benefits, the government should encourage people to delay taking their benefits at least until they reach their full retirement age. See, e.g., Kenn Beam Tacchino, David A. 28 The government could also do more to make workers preserve their retirement savings until retirement. In particular, it would make sense to prohibit premature distributions and loans from defined contribution plans and IRAs.80 V. Conclusion Workers today are building up most of their retirement savings in defined contribution plans and other individual retirement savings accounts. Many of those workers will need to use their savings to provide retirement income over retirements that can last twenty years or more. Retirees can best manage that longevity risk by taking their distributions in the form of annuities and other lifetime retirement income products, and government policies should be designed to encourage the use of those financial products. Littell & Bruce D. Schobel, A Decision Framework for Optimizing the Social Security Claiming Age, 28 BENEFITS QUARTERLY, no. 2, 2012, at 40. 80 See, e.g., FORMAN, supra note 2, at 233; LORI LUCAS, PLUG THE DRAIN: 401(K) LEAKAGE AND THE IMPACT ON RETIREMENT 9 (2011). 29